Skip to main content
Log in

Condorcet's paradox and the likelihood of its occurrence: different perspectives on balanced preferences*

  • Published:
Theory and Decision Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Many studies have considered the probability that a pairwise majority rule (PMR) winner exists for three candidate elections. The absence of a PMR winner indicates an occurrence of Condorcet's Paradox for three candidate elections. This paper summarizes work that has been done in this area with the assumptions of: Impartial Culture, Impartial Anonymous Culture, Maximal Culture, Dual Culture and Uniform Culture. Results are included for the likelihood that there is a strong winner by PMR, a weak winner by PMR, and the probability that a specific candidate is among the winners by PMR. Closed form representations are developed for some of these probabilities for Impartial Anonymous Culture and for Maximal Culture. Consistent results are obtained for all cultures. In particular, very different behaviors are observed for odd and even numbers of voters. The limiting probabilities as the number of voters increases are reached very quickly for odd numbers of voters, and quite slowly for even numbers of voters. The greatest likelihood of observing Condorcet's Paradox typically occurs for small numbers of voters. Results suggest that while examples of Condorcet's Paradox are observed, one should not expect to observe them with great frequency in three candidate elections.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

References

  • Arrow, K.J. (1963). Social Choice and Individual Values (2 ndedn.), Wiley, New York.

    Google Scholar 

  • Arrow, K.J. and H. Raynaud (1986). Social Choice and Multicriterion Decision Making, MIT Press, Cambridge, MA.

    Google Scholar 

  • Berg, S. (1985). Paradox of voting under an urn model: The effect of homogeneity, Public Choice 47:377–387.

    Google Scholar 

  • Berg, S. and B. Bjurulf (1983). A note on the paradox of voting: Anonymous preference profiles and May's formula, Public Choice 40:307–316.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bjurulf, B.H. and R.G. Niemi (1978). Strategic voting in Scandinavian parlia-ments, Scandinavian Political Studies 1: 5–22.

    Google Scholar 

  • Borda, J. de (1784). A paper on elections by ballot. In Sommerlad and McLean (1989),122–129.

  • Buckley, J.J. (1975). A note on unconditional probabilities and the voter's 1paradox, Public Choice 24:111–114.

    Google Scholar 

  • Buckley, J.J. and T.E. Westen (1979). The probability of the voter's paradox for an even number of voters, Journal of Interdisciplinary Modeling and Simulation 2: 185–210.

    Google Scholar 

  • Condorcet, Marquis de (1785a). An essay on the application of probability the-ory to plurality decision making: An election between three candidates. In Sommerlad and McLean (1989), 69–80.

  • Condorcet, Marquis de (1785b). An essay on the application of probability theory to plurality decision making: Part five. In Sommerlad and McLean (1989),109–118.

  • Condorcet, Marquis de (1788). On the form of decisions made by plurality vote. In Sommerlad and McLean (1989),152–166.

  • Dahl, R. (1956). A Preface to Democratic Theory, Chicago University Press, Chicago.

    Google Scholar 

  • Feix, M.R. and J.L. Rouet (1999). Un espace des phases électoral et les stat-istiques quantiques, Ecole des Mines de Nantes, mimeograph.

  • Feller, W. (1957). An Introduction to Probability Theory and Its Applications, (2nd ed.) John Wiley, New York.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fishburn, P. C., W. V. Gehrlein and E. Maskin (1979a). A progress report on Kelly's majority conjectures, Economic Letters 2:313–314.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fishburn, P. C., W. V. Gehrlein and E. Maskin (1979b). Condorcet proportions and Kelly's conjectures, Discrete Applied Mathematics 1:229–252.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gehrlein, W. V. (1978). Condorcet winners in dual cultures. Presented at National Meeting of Public Choice Society, New Orleans, LA.

  • Gehrlein, W. V. (1981). The expected probability of Condorcet's paradox, Eco-nomics Letters 7: 33–37.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gehrlein, W. V. (1982). The frequency of Condorcet's paradox in large groups, Proceedings of the Northeast American Institute for Decision Sciences,Wash-ington, DC,121–123.

  • Gehrlein, W. V. (1984). A variant interpretation of the impartial anonymous culture condition, Unpublished Manuscript.

  • Gehrlein, W. V. (2001a). Obtaining Representations for Probabilities of Vot-ing Outcomes with Effectively Unlimited Precision Integer Arithmetic, Social Choice and Welfare, forthcoming.

  • Gehrlein, W. V. (2001b). Condorcet winners on four candidates with anonymous voters, Economics Letters 71:335–3400.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gehrlein, W. V. and P. C. Fishburn (1976a). Condorcet's paradox and anonymous preference profiles, Public Choice 26: 1–18.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gehrlein, W. V. and P. C. Fishburn (1976b). The probability of the paradox of voting: A computable solution, Journal of Economic Theory 13: 14–25.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gehrlein, W. V. and P. C. Fishburn (1979). Proportions of profiles with a majority candidate, Computers and Mathematics with Applications 5:117–124.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gehrlein, W. V. and D. Lepelley (1997). Condorcet's paradox under the maximal culture condition, Economics Letters 55: 85–89.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gillett, R. (1979). Borda indecision, unpublished manuscript.

  • Gillett, R. (1980). The asymptotic likelihood of agreement between plurality and Condorcet outcomes, Behavioral Science 25: 23–32.

    Google Scholar 

  • Guilbaud, G. T. (1952). Les théories de l'intérê t général et le problè me logique de l'agrégation, Economie Appliquée 5:501–584.

    Google Scholar 

  • Johnson, N. L. and S. Kotz (1977). Urn Models and Their Application. Wiley, New York, NY.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kelly, J. S. (1974). Voting anomalies, the number of voters, and the number of alternatives, Econometrica 42:239–2511.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kuga, K. and H. Nagatani (1974). Voter antagonism and the paradox of voting, Econometrica 42:1045–1067.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kurrild-Klitgaard, P. (2001). An empirical example of the Condorcet paradox of voting in a large electorate, Public Choice 107:135–145.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lepelley, D. (1989) Contribution à l'analyse des procédures de décision collect-ive, Unpublished doctoral dissertation, Université de Caen.

  • May, R. M. (1971). Some mathematical remarks on the paradox of voting, Behavioral Science 16:143–151.

    Google Scholar 

  • Meyer, D. A. and T. A. Brown (1998). Statistical mechanics of voting, Physical Review Letters 81:1718–1721.

    Google Scholar 

  • Miller, N.R. (1983). Pluralism and Social Choice, American Political Science Review 77:734–747.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rae, D.W. (1980). An altimeter for Mr. Escher's stairway: A comment on William H. Riker's ‘Implications from the disequilibrium of majority rule for the study of institutions,’ American Political Science Review 74:451–455.

    Google Scholar 

  • Riker, W. H. (1958). The paradox of voting and congressional rules for voting on amendments, American Political Science Review 52:349–366.

    Google Scholar 

  • Riker, W.H. (1961). Voting and the summation of preferences: an interpretive bib-liographical review of selected developments during the last decade, American Political Science Review 55:900–911.

    Google Scholar 

  • Riker, W.H. (1980). Implications from the disequilibrium of majority rule for the study of institutions, American Political Science Review 74:432–446.

    Google Scholar 

  • Saari, D. G. (1994). Geometry of Voting, Studies in Economics 3, Springer, Heidelberg.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sen, A.K. (1970). Collective Choice and Social Welfare, Holden-Day, San Francisco, CA.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sommerlad, F. and I. McLean (1989). The Political Theory of Condorcet, University of Oxford Working Paper.

  • Stensholt, E. (1999a) Voteringens kvaler: flyplassaken i Stortinget 8. oktober 1992, Sosialø konomen 4: 28–40.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stensholt, E. (1999b). Beta distributions in a simplex and impartial anonymous cultures, Mathematical Social Sciences 37: 45–57.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tideman, T.N. (1992). Collective decision and voting: Cycles. Presented at Public Choice Society Meeting, New Orleans, LA.

  • Truchon, M. (1998). Rating skating and the theory of social choice, Université Laval, unpublished manuscript.

  • Tsetlin, I., M. Reggenwetter and B. Grofman (2001). The impartial culture maximizes the probability of majority cycles. Social Choice and Welfare, forthcoming.

  • Van Deemen, A. and N. Vergunst (1998). Empirical evidence of paradoxes of voting in Dutch elections, Public Choice 97:475–490.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Gehrlein, W.V. Condorcet's paradox and the likelihood of its occurrence: different perspectives on balanced preferences* . Theory and Decision 52, 171–199 (2002). https://doi.org/10.1023/A:1015551010381

Download citation

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1023/A:1015551010381

Keywords

Navigation