Skip to main content
Log in

Networks, Law, and the Paradox of Cooperation

  • Published:
The Review of Austrian Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

There is a tension between libertarians' optimism about private supply of public goods and skepticism of the viability of voluntary collusion (Cowen 1992, Cowen and Sutter 1999). Playing off this asymmetry, Cowen (1992) advances the novel argument that the “free market in defense services” favored by anarcho-capitalists is a network industry where collusion is especially feasible. The current article dissolves Cowen's asymmetry, showing that he fails to distinguish between self-enforcing and non-self-enforcing interaction. Case study evidence on network behavior before and after antitrust supports our analysis. Furthermore, libertarians' joint beliefs on public goods and collusion are, contrary to Cowen and Sutter (1999), theoretically defensible.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

References

  • Allen, P. (2000) “Prepared Testimony of Mr. Paul Allen.” Senate Banking Committee, Subcommittee on Financial Institutions, Hearing on Competition and Innovation in the Credit Card Industry at the Consumer and Network Level, May 25, 2000.

  • Banner, S. (1998) “The Origin of the New York Stock Exchange, 1791-1860.” Journal of Legal Studies, 27: 113–140.

    Google Scholar 

  • Benson, B. (1990) The Enterprise of Law. San Francisco: Pacific Research Institute for Public Policy.

    Google Scholar 

  • Benson, B. (1993) “The Impetus for Recognizing Private Property and Adopting Ethical Behavior in a Market Economy: Natural Law, Government Law, or Evolving Self-Interest.” Review of Austrian Economics, 6: 43–80.

    Google Scholar 

  • Benson, B. (1998) To Serve and Protect: Privatization and Community in Criminal Justice. New York: New York University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bernheim, D. and Whinston, M. (1985) “Common Marketing Agencies as a Device for Facilitating Collusion.” Rand Journal of Economics, 16: 269–281.

    Google Scholar 

  • Boal,W. and Ransom, M. (1997) “Monopsony in the Labor Market.” Journal of Economic Literature, 35: 86–112.

    Google Scholar 

  • Calomiris, C. and Kahn, C. (1991) “The Role of Demandable Debt in Structuring Optimal Banking Arrangements.” American Economic Review, 81: 497–513.

    Google Scholar 

  • Calomiris, C. (1990) “Is Deposit Insurance Necessary? A Historical Perspective.” Journal of Economic History, 50: 283–295.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cannon, J. G. (1910) Clearing Houses. Washington, Govt. Print. Off.

    Google Scholar 

  • Carlton, D. and Frankel, A. (1995a) “The Antitrust Economics of Payment Card Networks.” Antitrust Law Journal, 63: 643–668.

    Google Scholar 

  • Carlton, D. and Frankel, A. (1995b) “The Antitrust Economics of Payment Card Networks: Reply to Evans and Schmalensee Comment.” Antitrust Law Journal, 63: 903–915.

    Google Scholar 

  • Coate, S. and Loury, G. (1993) “Will Affirmative-Action Policies Eliminate Negative Stereotypes?” American Economic Review, 83: 1220–1240.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cowen, T. (1992) “Law as a Public Good: The Economics of Anarchy.” Economics and Philosophy, 8: 249–267.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cowen, T. (1994) “Rejoinder to David Friedman on the Economics of Anarchy.” Economics and Philosophy, 10: 329–332.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cowen, T. and Sutter, D. (1999) “The Costs of Cooperation.” The Review of Austrian Economics, 12: 161–173.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dewing, A. (1914) Corporate Promotions and Reorganizations. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dowd, K. (1994) “Competitive Banking, Bankers' Clubs, and Bank Regulation.” Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 26: 289–308.

    Google Scholar 

  • Economides, N. (1995) “Commentary on 'Antitrust Economics of Credit Card Networks'.” Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Review, Nov.-Dec. 1995: 60–63.

  • Evans, D. and Schmalensee, R. (1995) “Economic Aspects of Payment Card Systems and Antitrust Policy Toward Joint Ventures.” Antitrust Law Journal, 63: 861–901.

    Google Scholar 

  • Evans, D. and Schmalensee, R. (1999) Paying with Plastic: The Digital Revolution in Buying and Borrowing. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fort, R. and Quirk, J. (1995) “Cross-Subsidization, Incentives, and Outcomes in Professional Sports Leagues.” Journal of Economic Literature, 33: 1265–1299.

    Google Scholar 

  • Friedman, D. (1989) The Machinery of Freedom, Guide to Radical Capitalism, 2nd ed. La Salle, IL: Open Court.

    Google Scholar 

  • Friedman, D. (1994) “Law as a Private Good: A Response to Tyler Cowen on the Economics of Anarchy.” Economics and Philosophy, 10: 319–327.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gabel, D. (1994) “Competition in a Network Industry: The Telephone Industry, 1894-1910.” Journal of Economic History, 54: 543–572.

    Google Scholar 

  • Geddes, R. (2000) “Public Utilities.” In: Encyclopedia of Law and Economics,Vol. III. The Regulation of Contracts.

  • Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar, pp. 1162-1205.

  • Goodhart, C. (1988) The Evolution of Central Banks. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gorton, G. (1985) “Clearinghouses and the Origin of Central Banking in the United States.” Journal of Economic History, 45: 277–283.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gorton, G. and Mullineaux, D. (1987) “The Joint Production of Confidence: Endogenous Regulation and Nineteenth Century Commercial-Bank Clearinghouses.” Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 19: 457–468.

    Google Scholar 

  • Greif, A. (1993) “Contract Enforceability and Economic Institutions in Early Trade: The Maghribi Traders' Coalition.” American Economic Review, 83: 525–548.

    Google Scholar 

  • Greif, A., Milgrom, P., and Weingast, B. R. (1994) “Coordination, Commitment, and Enforcement: The Case of the Merchant Guild.” Journal of Political Economy, 102: 745–776.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hanft, N. (2000) “PreparedTestimony ofMr. Noah Hanft.” Senate Banking Committee, Subcommittee on Financial Institutions, Hearing on Competition and Innovation in the Credit Card Industry at the Consumer and Network Level, May 25, 2000.

  • Hausman, J., Leonard, G., and Tirole, J. (1999) “The Impact of Duality on Productive Efficiency and Innovation.” Working paper, MIT.

  • Hock, D. (1999) Birth of the Chaordic Age. San Francisco: Berrett-Koehler Pub.

    Google Scholar 

  • Katz, M. and Shapiro, C. (1985) “Network Externalities, Competition, and Compatibility.” American Economic Review, 75: 424–440.

    Google Scholar 

  • Katz, M. and Shapiro, C. (1994) “Systems Competition and Network Effects.” Journal of Economic Perspectives, 8: 93–115.

    Google Scholar 

  • Klein, D. (1990) “The Voluntary Provision of Public Goods? The Turnpike Companies of Early America.” Economic Inquiry, 28: 788–812.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lal, D. (1997) “From Planning to Regulation: Toward a New Dirigisme?” The Cato Journal, 17: 211–227.

    Google Scholar 

  • Libecap, G. and Wiggins, S. (1984) “Contractual Responses to the Common Pool: Prorationing of Crude Oil Production.” American Economic Review, 74: 87–98.

    Google Scholar 

  • Liebowitz, S. J. and Margolis, S. (1994) “Network Externality: An Uncommon Tragedy.” Journal of Economic Perspectives, 8: 133–150.

    Google Scholar 

  • Liebowitz, S. J. and Margolis, S. (1995) “Are Network Externalities a New Source of Market Failure?” Research in Law and Economics, 17: 1–22.

    Google Scholar 

  • Liebowitz, S. J. and Margolis, S. (1998) “Network Effects and Externalities.” In: The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics and the Law, pp. 671–675. London: MacMillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mahoney, P. (1997) “The Exchange as Regulator.” Virginia Law Review, 83: 1453–1500.

    Google Scholar 

  • McChesney, F. and Shughart, W. (1995) The Causes and Consequences of Antitrust: The Public-Choice Perspective. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • National Collegiate Athletic Association (2000) NCAA Division I Manual 2000-2001. Overland Park, KS: NCAA.

    Google Scholar 

  • National Collegiate Athletic Association v. Board of Regents of the University of Oklahoma et al. (1984) 468 U.S. 85.

  • Neale, W. (1964) “The Peculiar Economics of Professional Sports.” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 78: 1–14.

    Google Scholar 

  • Noll, R. (Ed.) (1974) Government and the Sports Business. Washington, DC: The Brookings Institution.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rochet, J. C. and Tirole, J. (2000) “Cooperation among Competitors: The Economics of Payment Card Associations.” Working paper, IDEI, Toulouse.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rosen, S. (1981) “The Economics of Superstars.” American Economic Review, 71: 845–858.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rothbard, M. N. (1978) For a New Liberty: The Libertarian Manifesto. NY: Libertarian Review Foundation.

    Google Scholar 

  • Salop, S. and White, L. J. (1991) “Policy Watch: Antitrust Goes to College.” Journal of Economic Perspectives, 5: 193–202.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schmidtz, D. (1991) The Limits of Government: An Essay on the Public Goods Argument. Boulder: Westview Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Smith, V. L. (1980) “Experiments with a Decentralized Mechanism for Public Good Decisions.” American Economic Review, 70: 584–599.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sowell, T. (1994) Race and Culture. NY: Basic Books.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sprague, O. M. W. (1910/1977) History of Crisis Under the National Banking System. Fairfield, NJ: Augustus M Kelly Publishers.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stringham, E. (1999) “Market Chosen Law.” Journal of Libertarian Studies, 14: 53–77.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stringham, E. (2002) “The Emergence of the London Stock Exchange as a Self-Policing Club.” Journal of Private Enterprise, 17: 1–19.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stringham, E. (2003) “The Extralegal Development of Securities Trading in Seventeenth Century Amsterdam.” Quarterly Review of Economics and Finance, 43: 321–344.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sutter, D. (1995) “Asymmetric Power Relations and Cooperation in Anarchy.” Southern Economic Journal, 61: 602–613.

    Google Scholar 

  • Telser, L. (1980) “A Theory of Self-Enforcing Agreements.” Journal of Business, 53: 27–44.

    Google Scholar 

  • Timberlake, R. (1984) “The Central Banking Role of Clearinghouse Associations.” Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 16: 1–15.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tullock, G. (1974) The Social Dilemma: The Economics of War and Revolution. Blacksburg, VA: University Publications.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tullock, G. (1981) “The Rhetoric and Reality of Redistribution.” Southern Economic Journal, 47: 895–907.

    Google Scholar 

  • Veitch, J. (1986) “Repudiations and Confiscations by the Medieval State.” Journal of Economic History, 46: 31–36.

    Google Scholar 

  • Zywicki, T. (2000) “The Economics of Credit Cards.” Chapman Law Review, 3: 79–172.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Caplan, B., Stringham, E. Networks, Law, and the Paradox of Cooperation. The Review of Austrian Economics 16, 309–326 (2003). https://doi.org/10.1023/A:1027393021392

Download citation

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1023/A:1027393021392

Navigation