1 Introduction

Recent years, the exhaustion of fossil energy and the environmental concerns of pollutants emission have made the energy conservation and emission reduction necessary. The power industry, which has been relying on fossil fuel as main primary energy for a long time, is emission intensive. In order to reduce the dependence on fuel energy and greenhouse gas emission, various regulation measures have been proposed and implemented, which can be roughly categorized into two kinds of greenhouse gas emission regulation and renewable energy promotion. Emission regulation and renewable energy promotion are regulation measures in two aspects, yet aiming at the same goal of achieving energy conservation and emission reduction targets. Therefore, in addition to the physical restrictions intrinsic to itself, power systems are nowadays facing more constraints from external domains, such as primary energy and emissions.

In [1], a novel concept, called the “generalized congestions” was proposed to describe those factors affecting both the competition level and the efficiency of power markets. Market power is defined as the market participant’s capability to influence the market efficiency with the aid of generalized congestions, and generalized market power reflects its capability to influence the social welfare. Regulation measures, like other generalized congestions, could influence the energy and capital flows in power systems. Thus, the regulation power is a special market power, which can also reduce market efficiency if it is not well designed.

In most countries, emission regulation and renewable energy promotion coexist, in which complex interactions are likely to happen. In [2], interactions between emission regulation and renewable energy (RES) promotion were categorized into direct interaction, indirect interaction, and trading interaction. The detailed interaction model is elaborated in this paper (shown in Fig. 1). If the interactive modes or key parameters of these regulation measures are adopted by ex-ante simulation evaluation, the unnecessary policy risk and social cost losses may be avoided.

Fig. 1
figure 1

Interactions between renewable energy promotion and emission regulation

2 Existing regulation policies for greenhouse gas emission and renewable energy promotion

2.1 Regulation of greenhouse gas emission

Typical regulation methods are carbon tax and emission trading (ET). Carbon tax is a Pigovian tax levied on the carbon content of fuels [3]. The Australia government introduced the carbon tax law in December 2011, which forced about 300 of the worst-polluting firms to pay an AUD $23 levy for every ton of greenhouse gases they produced. The problem with carbon tax is to determine a proper tax rate. The target of carbon tax is to internalize the externality of emission, however the marginal externality cost is difficult to be discovered. Emission trading is a market-based approach to control the pollution by providing economic incentives for achieving pollutant emission reductions. The basic methodology of emission trading is Coase theorem, which solves the externality problem by defining property rights and market-based mechanisms. The emission trading is a discovering process for marginal external cost. Theoretically, it could achieve the emission reduction target in the most efficient way when the transaction cost is near zero. Emission Trading Scheme (ETS) has already been implemented in many countries and districts, such as the Danish CO2 trading program (from 2001 to 2003), UK ETS (from 2002 to 2006), and EU ETS (2005). In [4], a detailed survey of EU ETS is given, including the origins and history, the allocation of allowances, the implications of competitiveness and the distribution of costs and benefits, etc.

2.2 Renewable energy promotion

Regulation of greenhouse gas emissions will introduce extra emission cost to fuel-based generation, which, to some extent, will make renewable energy generation relatively more competitive. However, researches show that only if the carbon tax or the emission price is much higher than the present value, can the renewable energy be truly competitive. So, in many countries, various policies for renewable energy promotion are applied to increase the competitiveness of renewable energy directly. The existing policies for renewable energy promotion can be categorized into two kinds of “price driven” and “quantity driven” based on their different regulation targets, and “investment incentive” and “generation incentive” based on their different incentive targets (shown in Table 1).

Table 1 Different mechanisms for renewable energy promotion

2.3 Existing research methods

In electricity market research, the major modelling methods include optimization model based, game equilibrium model based and simulation model based. In [5], a state-of-the-art review on modeling methods for decision making optimization in the electricity spot market was given. When studying the emission reduction related decision making problems, similar modelling methods are adopted. In [6], optimization model was used to investigate the effects of emission constraints and emission trading scheme on the generation scheduling outcome. In [7], Cournot equilibrium model was used to analyze the potential profit impacts and possible compensation of potential emission trading scheme on generation companies. As for power system energy policy studies, optimization and game equilibrium models are not applicable since the target problem is too complicated and comprises different market participants. Popular modelling methods of the power system energy policies include the computable general equilibrium (CGE) model and agent-based computational economics (ACE) model. CGE models are popular for policy analysis, which compromise of economic models using actual economic data to estimate how an economy might react to changes of policy, technology or other external factors. CGE models have been widely used in environmental policy researches to analyze the impact of different emission allowance allocation methods on emission reduction effects [8] and the impact of EU-wide emission trading on the reduction cost [9]. The ACE model-based method is to study the economics and emissions by evolving systems of autonomous interacting agents [10]. ACE models have been adopted to study the long-term impact of emission trading on generation emissions [11, 12] and the design of emission trading scheme [13], and the impact of the policies of renewable energy promotion on renewable energy investment [14].

3 Simulation tool and models

The dynamic simulation platform for power economy and power system (DSPES) was first proposed in [15], which is a novel simulation platform supporting multi-criteria, multi-participant dynamic simulation. Based on the dynamic model of power systems and power economy, DSPES supports the experimental study of power industry, providing quantitative risk analysis function and decision support for different participants. In this paper, DSPES is used for case studies. Mid-term simulation will be run to obtain the simulation results in 1 year.

3.1 Generation model

  1. 1)

    Marginal cost of fossil fuel-based generator. The marginal cost cf (€/MWh) for fossil fuel-based generator consists of marginal generation cost cfg and marginal emission cost cfe (€/MWh)

    $$ c_{\text{f}} = c_{\text{fg}} + c_{\text{fe}} = {{p_{\text{f}} } \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{p_{\text{f}} } e}} \right. \kern-0pt} e} + p_{\text{e}} \times r_{\text{fe}} ,$$
    (1)

    where \( c_{\text{fg}} = {{p_{\text{f}} } \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{p_{\text{f}} } {\text{e}}}} \right. \kern-0pt} {\text{e}}} \), pf (€/ton) is the fuel price and e (MWh/ton) is the efficiency; \( c_{\text{fe}} = p_{\text{e}} \times r_{\text{e}}, \)pe (€/ton) is the emission price and rfe (ton/MWh) is the emission rate.

  2. 2)

    Emission trading strategy. The emission trading quantity \( q_{{{\text{f}},\,i,\,t}}^{\text{e}} \) of fossil fuel-based generator i at day t is

    $$ q_{{{\text{f}},\;i,\;t}}^{\text{e}} = e_{{i,\;t}} - b_{i}^{\text{e}} \times r_{t}^{\text{l}} ,$$
    (2)

    where ei,t is the emission quantity of generator i at day t, \( b_{i}^{\text{e}} \) is the emission allowance budget of generator i at day t, and \( r_{t}^{\text{l}} \) is ratio of load level at day t with respect to annual total load.

  3. 3)

    Marginal cost of renewable energy. The marginal cost cr (€/MWh) for renewable energy is the marginal generation cost crg (€/MWh) minus feed-in-tariff subsidy pr (€/MWh) as follows

    $$ c_{\text{r}} = c_{\text{rg}} - p_{\text{r}} . $$
    (3)

3.2 Electricity market model

Generation Companies (GENCOs) will trade in the spot electricity market on daily basis. Suppose that the demand is inelastic and every unit reports their marginal cost. Uniform clearing pricing method is adopted to clear the market.

3.3 Emission market model

In this model, emission trading is carried out on daily basis, and GENCOs are considered as price takers, who report their everyday emission allowance demand to the emission market. Daily emission price pe will then be generated based on a “demand–price” model.

In this “demand–price” model, pet (emission price at day t) is calculated based on an inference from the accumulated emission allowance demand before day t to the annual overall emission demand. Its basic principle is illustrated in Fig. 2.

$$ p_{{\text{e}}t} = \bar{p}_{\text{e}} + \lambda \frac{{(\tilde{e}_{\text{T}} - e_{t - 1} ) - (\bar{e} - e_{t - 1} )}}{{\bar{e} - e_{t - 1} }}, $$
(4)
$$ e_{t - 1} = \sum\limits_{k = 1}^{t - 1} {\sum\limits_{n = 1}^{N} {q_{{{\text{f}},\;{n},\;{k}}}^{\text{e}} } } , $$
(5)
$$ \tilde{e}_{\text{T}} = {{\sum\limits_{k = 1}^{t - 1} {\sum\limits_{n = 1}^{N} {q_{{{\text{f}},\;{n},\;{k}}}^{\text{e}} } } } \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{\sum\limits_{k = 1}^{t - 1} {\sum\limits_{n = 1}^{N} {q_{{{\text{f}},\;{\text{n}},\;{\text{k}}}}^{\text{e}} } } } {\sum\limits_{k = 1}^{t - 1} {r_{\text{k}}^{\text{l}} } }}} \right. \kern-0pt} {\sum\limits_{k = 1}^{t - 1} {r_{k}^{\text{l}} } }}, $$
(6)

where \( \bar{p}_{\text{e}} \) is the average price in emission market,λ is the emission price factor, et−1 is the accumulated emission allowance demand before day t; \( \tilde{e}_{\text{T}} \) is the inference value of annual overall emission allowance demand based on et−1, \( \bar{e} \) is the preset annual overall emission cap and \( r_{k}^{\text{l}} \) is the daily load proportion (in day k) with respect to annual overall load.

Fig. 2
figure 2

Basic principle of the “demand–price” model

This emission market “demand–price” model tries to simulate the annual emission price dynamics. Parameters in this model has been tuned based on actual EU ETS emission market price statistics, \( \bar{p}_{\text{e}} \) is set to 20 €/ton,λ is set to 1,000, and price cap and floor are set to 40 and 0 €/ton, respectively.

The following case studies show that the model can reasonably reflect the emission price dynamics.

3.4 Evaluation index

  1. 1)

    Social cost (SC). The social cost must be comprehensively evaluated, covering each kind of cost incurred and possible social benefits. In this sense, at least electricity purchasing cost (PC), subsidy (S), and social benefits (B) should be considered. In this paper: SC = PC + S − B. It should be mentioned that, usually the fiscal revenue of selling emission allowance or the carbon tax will be used to encourage clean energy development, which is the social benefits in this paper.

  2. 2)

    Overall emission (OE). The overall emission of the whole system is used to evaluate the effectiveness of policies, rather than the emission per MWh or per GDP.

  3. 3)

    Cost efficiency (CE). Cost efficiency is needed to compare the efficiency of one policy with another one. CE = ΔOE/ΔSC, where ΔOE and ΔSC are the increments of OE and SC, respectively.

Dynamic efficiency can be evaluated by the profit accumulation of each kind of GENCO.

4 Case studies

IEEE 39-bus system is chosen for case studies, Fig. 3 shows the annual load curve, and three kinds of GENCO are set in the system: high emission GENCO (HIGH) which owns fossil fuel-based generators (mainly coal-based) with high emission rate, low emission GENCO (LOW) which owns fossil fuel-based generators (mainly gas-based) with low emission rate, and renewable GENCO (RENEWABLE) which owns renewable energy generators.

Fig. 3
figure 3

Annual load curve

And in this paper, feed-in-tariff subsidy and emission trading are selected as the typical renewable energy promotion and emission regulation measures, respectively, as shown in Fig. 4.

Fig. 4
figure 4

Interaction model

Six types of generator are considered in the case study (shown in Table 2), among them there are three types of coal-based generator, two types of gas-based generator, one type of bio power plant, and one type of wind turbine. And their distributions in a power system are shown in Table 3.

Table 2 Unit parameters
Table 3 Unit distribution

4.1 First case study: influences of emission regulation strength

In the first case study, the policy of renewable energy promotion is fixed, and the impact of different emission regulation strengths will be evaluated by scenario simulations.

In all scenarios, feed-in-tariff subsidy is set for renewable energy generators. Here, 50 % means that the subsidy will cover 50 % of the renewable energy generator cost (shown in Table 4).

Table 4 Simulation scenarios (first case study)

Scenario 1 is set as the Business as Usual scenario. In Scenarios 2–4, emission trading is implemented and the percentage in Table 4 implicates its target of emission reduction percentage compared with the emission level in Scenario 1.

Then simulations are conducted on the simulation platform DSPES, simulation results are shown in Table 5. It can be found in Table 5 that in the aspect of all emissions social cost, the simulation results of Scenario 1 are inferior to that of Scenario 2, which is due to the absence of emission regulation.

Table 5 Simulation results (first case study)

In Scenarios 2–4, as the regulation strength increases, the total emissions decrease, while the social cost increases. Among them, Scenario 2 achieves the lowest social cost, and the cost efficiency of Scenarios 3–4 is calculated compared with Scenario 2. Scenario 3 obtains the best cost efficiency (0.2513 ton/€), which means the reduction of one more ton emission cost only €3.98.

So in this case study, considering the total emission reduction and cost efficiency, Scenarios 2 and 3 are better choices.

Figure 5 shows the profit accumulation for different kinds of GENCO under each scenario.

Fig. 5
figure 5

Profit accumulation of different GENCOs under different scenarios

As the emission regulation strengthens from Scenarios 1–4, more and more profit can be obtained for “RENEWABLE” due to its relatively increased competitiveness, which will stimulate more and more renewable generation investments in the long run; profit accumulation for “HIGH” decreases due to the increase of extra emission cost, its generators will at last act as the peak load units.

Profit accumulation for “LOW” will decrease at the beginning (Scenarios 1–3), because the emission cost is not high enough to compete with “HIGH”, while the “RENEWABLE” get more market share. Then, the profit accumulation increases from Scenarios 3–4, because now the emission cost is high enough to compete with “HIGH”.

Figures 6, 7, and 8 show the emission price dynamics (in 1 year) at different levels of emission regulation strength. The tougher the regulation, the higher the average emission price is.

Fig. 6
figure 6

Emission price dynamics (Scenario 2)

Fig. 7
figure 7

Emission price dynamics (Scenario 3)

Fig. 8
figure 8

Emission price dynamics (Scenario 4)

4.2 Second case study: influences of renewable energy promotion strength

In the second case study, emission regulation policy is fixed, and the impact of different renewable energy promotion strengths is evaluated by simulation scenarios.

Scenario 2 in the first case study is chosen as a benchmark scenario in this case study. The change of renewable energy promotion strength is reflected by different subsidy percentages (shown in Table 6).

Table 6 Simulation scenarios (second case study)

Compared with that of Scenario 2, the social cost increases with the growth of subsidy percentage, but the quantity of emission reduction is negligible (shown in Table 7). Considering the cost efficiency, Scenarios 5–7 are inefficient.

Table 7 Simulation results (second case study)

In Scenario 5, due to insufficient renewable energy promotion, renewable energy generators cannot compete with fossil fuel-based generators. The latter will account for large market share, and the demand for emission allowance rises, leading to relatively high emission price (shown in Fig. 9).

Fig. 9
figure 9

Emission price dynamics (Scenario 5)

As the efforts to promote renewable energy generation are enhanced in Scenarios 6 and 7, the excessive feed-in-tariff will greatly enhance the competitiveness of renewable energy generators, which will cut the market share of fossil fuel-based generators. Therefore, the demand for emission allowance is lowered, and the emission price goes down, which is zero during the majority time (Figs. 10, 11).

Fig. 10
figure 10

Emission price dynamics (Scenario 6)

Fig. 11
figure 11

Emission price dynamics (Scenario 7)

In this case study, the excessive renewable energy promotion will twist the emission price signal, which leads to the ineffectiveness of the emission regulation. This is the negative effect of the interaction between renewable energy promotion and emission regulation.

5 Conclusion

In this paper, based on the simulation platform DSPES, interactions between greenhouse gas emission regulation and renewable energy promotion in electric power industry are studied. The policy effect is evaluated by the social cost, overall emission, cost efficiency, and the economic incentive to different GENCOs. Case studies show that neither emission regulation nor renewable energy promotion can achieve the most efficient emission reduction outcome alone. The two measures will coexist for a long period of time. If not well designed, they will impose negative effects on each other. In the case study, excessive renewable energy promotion may twist the emission price, thus leading to inefficient emission reduction. The DSPES turns out to be a very useful tool for policy analysis, which can be used as a “wind tunnel” before the implementation of energy policies.