Skip to main content
Log in

Listing Specialization and Pricing Precision

  • Published:
The Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper investigates the relationship between property pricing precision (deviation from an expected property value) and specialization in the listing process by agents. It is hypothesized that financially constrained, risk-averse sellers prefer finer gradations of pricing precision, i.e., less deviation from expected property value, and that a set of agents will rise to meet this preference. The findings in this work indicate that agents specializing in listing properties increase pricing precision. The contributions of this work are twofold: (a) it provides a unique and heretofore uninvestigated metric as its dependent variable, thus allowing for further investigation into the brokerage intermediation process beyond the scope of price and marketing time, and (b) it provides an identifiable agent trait that can allow for a better matching of sellers’ preferences with agents’ abilities.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. The terms “broker” and “agent” are used interchangeably in the literature to describe individuals who take part in the broker intermediation process. We use the term “broker” to represent the qualifying broker, while the term “agent” refers to salespersons. The terms “brokerage,” “broker intermediation,” etc., refer to the actions of brokers and agents in real estate markets.

  2. It is clear that, while not all risk-averse sellers are financially constrained, all rational, financially-constrained sellers should be risk-averse; it is precisely this subset of risk-averse sellers that would be most interested in pricing precision and the group of brokers that can better deliver pricing precision.

  3. To those omitted authors, we extend our apologies. The interested reader may reference Sirmans et al. (2005) for an exhaustive review of hedonic studies in real estate, many of which are brokerage studies.

  4. Colwell and Marshall (1986), p. 597.

  5. This setting significantly mimics the present market.

  6. Other simplifying assumptions here are that sellers of property have forgone the For Sale By Owner (FSBO) market and that buyers are exogenous to the present problem.

  7. Generally speaking, all equities trade with frequency. Since equity securities are homogeneous for a given firm (and a given class for that firm), market liquidity is high. The same is not true for residential property. Here, we additionally assume that prices and marketing times are positively related as in Anglin et al. (2003). That is to say, higher prices are attained with longer marketing periods, while lower prices can easily be garnered in shorter marketing periods.

  8. Time subscripts are omitted for convenience.

  9. Jackson and Lindley (1989) illustrates the predicament we face in this instance, demonstrating that the interpretation of main effects in the presence of an interaction term may be problematic. Jackson and Lindley’s work is based on Gujarati (1970), which provides the theoretical basis for their empirical test. In light of these issues, we include separate estimations for each of the main effects in (7) and (8) as well as the combined model with interaction (9) to allow the reader the most complete and correct analysis.

  10. Again, we recognize that the signs and statistical significance of our main effects, TList and %List, changed in the presence of the interaction term. This is not unusual, as the interaction term “steals” some of its statistical significance from the main effects. In model (9), we cannot interpret the main effects.

References

  • Anglin, P. M., Rutherford, R. C., & Springer, T. M. (2003). The trade-off between the selling price of residential properties and time on the market: the impact of price setting. Real Estate Economics, 26(1), 95–111. doi:10.1023/A:1021526332732.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ball, C. A., Torous, W. N., & Tschoegl, A. E. (1985). The degree of price resolution: the case of the cold market. Journal of Futures Markets, 5, 29–43. doi:10.1002/fut.3990050105.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Belkin, J., Hempel, D. J., & McLeavey, D. W. (1976). An empirical study of time on market using a multidimensional segmentation of housing markets. AREUEA Journal, 4(1), 57–75.

    Google Scholar 

  • Colwell, P. F., & Marshall, D. W. (1986). Market share in the real estate brokerage industry. AREUEA Journal, 14(4), 583–599.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gardiner, J., Heisler, J., Kallberg, J. G., & Liu, C. H. (2007). The impact of dual agency. Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics, 35(1), 39–55. doi:10.1007/s11146-007-9028-8.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Geltner, D., Kluger, B. D., & Miller, N. G. (1991). Optimal price and selling effort from the perspectives of the broker and the seller. AREUEA Journal, 19(1), 1–24.

    Google Scholar 

  • Grossman, S. J., & Stiglitz, J. E. (1980). On the impossibility of informationally efficient markets. American Economic Review, 70, 393–408.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gujarati, D. (1970). Use of dummy variables in testing for equality between sets of coefficients in linear regression: a generalization. American Statistician, 24(5), 18–22. doi:10.2307/2682446.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Huang, J., & Rutherford, R. C. (2007). Who you going to call? Performance of realtors and non-realtors in a MLS setting. Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics, 35(1), 77–93. doi:10.1007/s11146-007-9029-7.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jackson, J. D., & Lindley, J. T. (1989). Measuring the extent of wage discrimination: a statistical test and a caveat. Applied Economics, 21(4), 515–540. doi:10.1080/758519717.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jud, G. D. (1983). Real estate brokers and the market for residential housing. AREUEA Journal, 11(1), 69–82.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jud, G. D., & Frew, J. (1986). Real estate brokers, housing prices, and the demand for housing. Urban Studies, 23, 21–31. doi:10.1080/00420988620080031.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jud, G. D., Seaks, T. G., & Winkler, D. T. (1996). Time on market: the impact of residential brokerage. Journal of Real Estate Research, 12(3), 447–458.

    Google Scholar 

  • Levitt, S., & Syverson, C. (2005). Market distortions when agents are better informed: the value of information in real estate transactions. National Bureau of Economic Research, NBER Working Paper 11053.

  • Miller, N. G. (1978). Time on the market and selling price. AREUEA Journal, 6(2), 164–174.

    Google Scholar 

  • Munneke, H. J., & Yavas, A. (2001). Incentives and performance in real estate brokerage. Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics, 22(1), 5–21. doi:10.1023/A:1007879109026.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Palmon, O., Smith, B. A., & Sopranzetti, B. J. (2004). Clustering in real estate prices: determinants and consequences. Journal of Real Estate Research, 26, 115–136.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rutherford, R. C., Springer, T. M., & Yavas, A. (2005). Conflicts between principals and agents: evidence from residential brokerage. Journal of Financial Economics, 76, 627–665. doi:10.1016/j.jfineco.2004.06.006.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rutherford, R. C., Springer, T. M., & Yavas, A. (2007). Evidence of information asymmetries in the market for residential condominiums. Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics, 35(1), 23–38. doi:10.1007/s11146-007-9027-9.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Salant, S. W. (1991). For sale by owner: when to use a broker and how to price the house. Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics, 4(2), 157–174. doi:10.1007/BF00173122.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sirmans, G. S., Macpherson, D. A., & Zietz, E. N. (2005). The composition of hedonic pricing models. Journal of Real Estate Literature, 13(1), 1–44.

    Google Scholar 

  • Turnbull, G. K., & Dombrow, J. (2007). Individual agents, firms, and the real estate brokerage process. Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics, 35(1), 57–76. doi:10.1007/s11146-007-9025-y.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Yavas, A. (1992). A simple search and bargaining model of real estate markets. AREUEA Journal, 20(4), 533–548.

    Google Scholar 

  • Yavas, A., & Colwell, P. F. (1995). A comparison of real estate marketing systems: theory and evidence. Journal of Real Estate Research, 10(5), 583–599.

    Google Scholar 

  • Yinger, J. (1981). A search model of real estate broker behavior. American Economic Review, 71(4), 591–605.

    Google Scholar 

  • Zumpano, L. V., & Elder, H. W. (1994). Economies of scope and density in the market for real estate brokerage services. AREUEA Journal, 22(3), 497–513.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

We wish to thank C.F. Sirmans (Editor), an anonymous referee of the journal, Tom Springer, Bill Hardin, Tom Lindley, Frank Mixon, and session participants at the 2007 Southern Finance Association Meeting in Charleston, South Carolina, for their comments, suggestions, and assistance. Remaining errors are our own.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Sean P. Salter.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Salter, S.P., Johnson, K.H. & King, E.W. Listing Specialization and Pricing Precision. J Real Estate Finan Econ 40, 245–259 (2010). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11146-008-9146-y

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11146-008-9146-y

Keywords

Navigation