Skip to main content
Log in

Relative performance evaluation and peer-performance summarization errors

  • Published:
Review of Accounting Studies Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

In tests of the relative performance evaluation (RPE) hypothesis, empiricists rarely aggregate peer performance in the same way as a firm’s board of directors. Framed as a standard errors-in-variables problem, a commonly held view is that such aggregation errors attenuate the regression coefficient on systematic firm performance towards zero, which creates a bias in favor of the strong-form RPE hypothesis. In contrast, we analytically demonstrate that aggregation differences generate more complicated summarization errors, which create a bias against finding support for strong-form RPE (potentially inducing a Type-II error). Using simulation methods, we demonstrate the sensitivity of empirical inferences to the bias by showing how an empiricist can conclude erroneously that boards, on average, do not apply RPE, simply by selecting more, fewer, or different peers than the board does. We also show that when the board does not apply RPE, empiricists will not find support for RPE (that is, precluding a Type-I error).

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. In theory, firms use RPE to filter out performance measurement error that commonly affects all firms in an industry or the economy more generally (e.g., see Lambert 2001). Since firms within an economy face common risk, a natural empirical prediction is that RPE should be systematically widespread in practice.

  2. Uncertainty regarding the board’s choice of peers and peer-group aggregation weights (plus missing or unavailable data) most likely yields differences in the empiricist’s and board’s peer-group performance. While SEC-regulated disclosures of the names of peers have recently reduced uncertainty about peer-group choice, empiricists remain uncertain about the weights assigned to each of the peers in the peer group.

  3. Demski and Sappington (1999) study more generally how key summarization errors inherently arise when empiricists investigate agency relationships. For example, when an empiricist cannot observe the multidimensional nature of firms’ performance evaluation systems, it is difficult to interpret accurately an empiricist’s estimation of the relation between pay and performance.

  4. The classic RPE hypothesis has two major empirical implications (Antle and Smith 1986). First, a “strong” implication of the RPE hypothesis suggests that the systematic or peer-related component of the firm’s performance is eliminated from the agent’s compensation. Second, a “weak” implication of the RPE hypothesis is that a board places a different weight on the unsystematic component of firm performance relative to the weight on the systematic component of firm performance.

  5. Jenter and Kanaan (2010) present a similar argument.

  6. Framing summarization errors as an errors-in-variables problem implies an additive uncorrelated measurement error in the independent variable (i.e., the board’s peer-group performance), while holding the dependent variable fixed (i.e., the manager’s compensation). As a result, the errors-in-variables problem biases the corresponding regression coefficient towards zero. Thus, if the summarization errors are framed as an errors-in-variables problem, then finding support in favor of strong-form RPE is more likely (Janakiraman et al. 1992, p. 60).

  7. The two-step approach suggested by Antle and Smith (1986) allows us to study both the strong and weak implications of the RPE hypothesis. However, our result of a summarization error also holds when the regression’s independent variables include both peer-group performance and other variables (e.g., empirical studies using the Holmström and Milgrom 1987 approach) or only changes in peer-group performance (as suggested by Janakiraman et al. 1992).

  8. Assuming a cost to acquire peer information, we can formally show that it is indeed optimal to exclude potential peers from the peer group. This analysis is available from the authors upon request.

  9. A further example that yields a deviation from the risk-minimizing aggregation rule follows when a powerful manager may influence the choice of weights on poor-performing peers, to improve the manager’s performance relative to peers and thereby increase compensation (Dye 1992).

  10. Demski and Feltham (1976) assume a decision maker may ultimately consider a simplified problem instead of a complete analysis. Applying this view, we label an alternative aggregation rule as “simplified.”

  11. Throughout the paper we use linear incentive contracts to improve the model’s tractability and to facilitate the connection of the model to linear regression assumptions underlying the empirical investigation of RPE. While the assumption of linear contracts limits the generalizability of the results, further analysis (available from the authors upon request) shows that our aggregation rule holds in an optimal contracting setting with a single firm.

  12. In particular, our result complements Holmström (1982) by deriving a risk-minimized aggregation of peer performance in a LEN-setting with two new assumptions where (1) firms respond differentially to market-wide shocks and (2) contract design depends in part on employment contracts specified by peers in the labor market.

  13. More specifically, a divergence in the empiricist’s aggregation introduces a partial correlation between the firm’s performance and an empiricist’s peer-group performance (after controlling for the board’s peer-group performance). Since the regression coefficient on systematic firm performance is proportional to this partial correlation, an incorrect rejection of the RPE hypothesis (that is, a Type-II error) can be made in interpreting statistical tests of the strong-form RPE hypothesis.

  14. See Table 1 for an overview of the various studies.

  15. Throughout the paper, we use the terms “idiosyncratic” risk and “firm-specific” risk as well as “market” risk and “common” risk, interchangeably.

  16. For notational brevity, we set δ ii  = 0 to not exclude δ ii from \( \varvec{\delta}_{i} \).

  17. Consistent with prior studies, we analyze the case where RPE is based on gross performance. An analysis of the case of where RPE is based on a firm’s net performance, i.e., firm performance less compensation costs, is available from the authors upon request.

  18. Principal i and agent i conjecture that principal j offers agent j a contract z j that induces a j , j ≠ i. For expositional brevity, we do not explicitly highlight these conjectures. In equilibrium, the conjectures are correct.

  19. For each firm j, the expected net payoff is zero if agent j exerts no effort and his reservation certainty equivalent is zero. Even for the sub-optimal case where principal j does not use RPE, \( \kappa_{j}^{\prime } \left( 0 \right) = 0 \) ensures \( a_{j} > 0 \) and thus a strictly positive expected net payoff. Hence, we can take the set of firms as given in our analysis.

  20. Superscript “†” denotes optimality.

  21. Banker and Datar (1989) and Milgrom and Roberts (1990) also present the standard results, (9a) and (9b). For the special case μ i  = 0, market risk does not affect the performance of firm i. Then, the performance of peer firms is not used to reduce the agent’s incentive risk. Hence, (9a) and (9b) simplify to the well-known result, \(v_{ii}^{\dag } \) = (1 + r i κ ′′ i (a i )Var[y i ])−1 and \(v_{ip}^{\dag } \) = 0.

  22. Relatedly, Gong et al. (2011) find that, for RPE purposes, firms exhibiting a higher ability to remove common risks are more likely to be chosen as peer firms.

  23. To simplify notation, subscript “†” denotes the risk-minimized peer-group performance, \( y_{ip} (\varvec{\delta}_{i}^{\dag } ) \).

  24. Notably, the Corollary 1 proof does not require an assumption of a single-factor model as in (1). Consequently, Corollary 1 holds for any correlation between firm performance y i and peer performance y j .

  25. While the approach in Janakiraman et al. (1992) allows for a more direct test of strong-form RPE, the decomposition approach used by Antle and Smith (1986) provides a framework that can also be used to test for weak-form RPE.

  26. To distinguish between focal firm and peer-group performance, we use an index f for the performance of the focal firm and retain an index p for the performance of the peer group. We also denote the empiricist’s choice of peers by superscript e and the board’s choice of peers by superscript b. For notational brevity, we omit the index f indicating that aggregation rules are firm-specific and, subsequently, the time index t when characterizing the regressions.

  27. The parameter m is a normalization that equals zero for the knife-edge case that the board’s and the empiricist’s peer-group performance are perfectly correlated, ρ be  = ±1. Our assumptions imply that the board cannot completely eliminate incentive risk from the manager’s compensation, ρ fb  ≠ ±1.

  28. Framing the empiricist’s measurement error as a classical errors-in-variables problem implies that the performance of the board’s and the empiricist’s peer group is equivalent up to an additive error term, i.e., \( y_{p} (\varvec{\delta}^{e} ) = y_{p} (\varvec{\delta}^{b} ) + u \), where E[u] = 0 and \( {\text{Cov}}[y_{p} (\varvec{\delta}^{b} ),u] = 0 \).

  29. We later show that when the board uses a simplified aggregation rule that is different to that used by the empiricist, a bias does in fact exist against finding support for strong-form RPE.

  30. In separate analyses, we specify assumptions and highlight the characteristics of commonly used aggregation rules in prior empirical studies (e.g., correlation-based aggregation, Antle and Smith 1986). These characteristics have limited practicality. In further analyses, we derive the principal’s preferences over exogenous aggregation rules under different economic conditions. Both analyses are available from the authors upon request.

  31. Our result must be interpreted carefully in an applied empirical setting. Depending on the sample size and the measurement error in the independent variables, in a statistical sense, the estimated regression coefficient \( \hat{\beta }_{s} (\varvec{\delta}^{b} ,\varvec{\delta}^{e} ) \) might not differ significantly from zero, despite the presence of an aggregation-induced bias. Section 4 provides further evidence.

  32. Recall that we rule out trivial cases where firm performance is unaffected by market risk.

  33. The choice of the retail industry is without loss of generality. Calibrating the data using, for example, the manufacturing industry (SIC codes 20–39) yields similar inferences.

  34. The μ f -value represents the 2004 median firm-specific coefficient from regressing firm-specific returns on market returns for the previous 60 months and the idiosyncratic risk, σ 2 f , represents the variance of the residuals of this regression.

  35. Applying a board’s aggregation rule and normalized incentive parameters to the left side of (14), the manager’s compensation is characterized by \( w({\varvec{\delta}}^{b} ) = \varepsilon_{f} + \mu_{f} /(\mu_{b}^{2} \sigma_{m}^{2} + \sigma_{b}^{2} )(\sigma_{b}^{2} \varepsilon_{m} - \mu_{b} \sigma_{m}^{2} \sum\nolimits_{{j \in I_{b} }} {\delta_{j}^{b} \varepsilon_{j} } ) \).

  36. We report simulated regressions identical to those described in Antle and Smith (1986). In untabulated regressions we also perform both a parametric and nonparametric test, following Janakiraman et al. (1992). In reduced-form regressions as specified in Janakiraman et al. (1992), expression (10), we obtain identical inferences as those reported in this section. In nonparametric tests, given that RPE exists, we expect the percentage of positive coefficients on the systematic component of firm performance in 1,000 regressions to approximate 50 %, which is matched by the percentage of negative coefficients (Janakiraman et al. 1992). If no RPE exists, the percentage of positive coefficients would be significantly larger than the percentage of negative coefficients. Our inferences from the nonparametric tests are consistent with those from the parametric tests.

  37. Despite the measurement error introduced by the use of a small sample (that is, 15 firm-years for each of the 1,000 firm-specific regressions), all \( \hat{\beta }_{s} \) coefficients in Table 2 converge to the coefficient values predicted by application of our Proposition 5.

  38. In untabulated simulations, we find a similar incorrect rejection of strong-form RPE for alternative peer selections by the board.

  39. If equally weighted peer performance selected by an industry-size sort better reflects a board’s aggregation rule, then our theory suggests that the likelihood of a Type-II error is reduced. This provides a potential theoretical rationale for why support is documented for strong-form RPE in Albuquerque (2009). In other words, in the context of Table 2, Panel B, equally weighting peer performances selected by an industry-size sort may move the empiricist closer to the diagonal where the regression coefficient generally converges to zero.

References

  • Aggarwal, R., & Samwick, A. (1999a). Executive compensation, strategic competition, and relative performance evaluation: Theory and evidence. Journal of Finance, 54(6), 1999–2043.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Aggarwal, R. K., & Samwick, A. A. (1999b). The other side of the trade-off: The impact of risk on executive compensation. Journal of Political Economy, 107(1), 65–105.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Albuquerque, A. (2009). Peer firms in relative performance evaluation. Journal of Accounting & Economics, 48(1), 69–89.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Antle, R., & Smith, A. (1986). An empirical investigation of the relative performance evaluation of corporate executives. Journal of Accounting Research, 24(1), 1–39.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Banker, R. D., & Datar, S. M. (1989). Sensitivity, precision, and linear aggregation of signals for performance evaluation. Journal of Accounting Research, 27(1), 21–39.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bannister, J. W., & Newman, H. A. (2003). Analysis of corporate disclosures on relative performance evaluation. Accounting Horizons, 17(3), 235–246.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bannister, J., Newman, H., & Weintrop, J. (2011). Tests for relative performance evaluation based on assumptions derived from proxy statement disclosures. Review of Quantitative Finance and Accounting, 37(2), 127–148.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barro, J. R., & Barro, R. J. (1990). Pay, performance, and turnover of bank CEOs. Journal of Labor Economics, 8(4), 448–481.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bertrand, M., & Mullainathan, S. (2001). Are CEOs rewarded for luck? The ones without principals are. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 116(3), 901–932.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bizjak, J., Lemmon, M., & Naveen, L. (2008). Does the use of peer groups contribute to higher pay and less efficient compensation? Journal of Financial Economics, 90(2), 152–168.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brickley, J. A. (2003). Empirical research on CEO turnover and firm-performance: A discussion. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 36(1–3), 227–233.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cadman, B., & Carter, M. (2010). Compensation peer groups and their relation with CEO compensation. Working paper.

  • Crawford, A. J. (1999). Relative performance evaluation in CEO pay contracts: Evidence from the commercial banking industry. Managerial Finance, 25(9), 34–54.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • DeFond, M. L., & Park, C. W. (1999). The effect of competition on CEO turnover. Journal of Accounting & Economics, 27(1), 35–56.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Demski, J. S., & Feltham, G. A. (1976). Cost determination: A conceptual approach. Ames, IA: Iowa State University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Demski, J., & Sappington, D. (1999). Summarization with errors: A perspective on empirical investigations of agency relationships. Management Accounting Research, 10(1), 21–37.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dye, R. A. (1992). Relative performance evaluation and project selection. Journal of Accounting Research, 30(1), 27–52.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Farrell, K. A., & Whidbee, D. A. (2003). Impact of firm performance expectations on CEO turnover and replacement decisions. Journal of Accounting & Economics, 36(1–3), 165–196.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Faulkender, M., & Yang, J. (2010). Inside the black box: The role and composition of compensation peer groups. Journal of Financial Economics, 96(2), 257–270.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Garvey, G., & Milbourn, T. (2003). Incentive compensation when executives can hedge the market: Evidence of relative performance evaluation in the cross section. Journal of Finance, 58(4), 1557–1582.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Garvey, G. T., & Milbourn, T. T. (2006). Asymmetric benchmarking in compensation: Executives are rewarded for good luck but not penalized for bad. Journal of Financial Economics, 82(1), 197–225.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gibbons, R., & Murphy, K. J. (1990). Relative performance evaluation for chief executive officers. Industrial and Labor Relations Review, 43(3), 30–51.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gong, G., Li, L. Y., & Shin, J. Y. (2011). Relative performance evaluation and related peer groups in executive compensation contracts. The Accounting Review 86(3), 1007–1043.

    Google Scholar 

  • Greene, W. H., & Zhang, C. (2003). Econometric analysis (Vol. 5). Upper Saddle River, NJ: Prentice Hall.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hall, B. J., & Liebman, J. B. (1998). Are CEOs really paid like bureaucrats? Quarterly Journal of Economics, 113(3), 653–691.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Himmelberg, C. P., & Hubbard, R. G. (2000). Incentive pay and the market for CEOs: An analysis of pay-for-performance sensitivity. Working Paper, Columbia University.

  • Holmström, B. (1982). Moral hazard in teams. The Bell Journal of Economics, 13(2), 324–340.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Holmström, B., & Milgrom, P. (1987). Aggregation and linearity in the provision of inter-temporal incentives. Econometrica, 55(2), 303–328.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Holmström, B., & Milgrom, P. (1991). Regulating trade among agents. Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics, 146, 85–105.

    Google Scholar 

  • Indjejikian, R. J. (1999). Performance evaluation and compensation research: An agency perspective. Accounting Horizons, 13(2), 147–157.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Janakiraman, S., Lambert, R. A., & Larcker, D. F. (1992). An empirical investigation of the relative performance evaluation hypothesis. Journal of Accounting Research, 30(Spring), 53–69.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jenter, D., & Kanaan, F. (2010). CEO turnover and relative performance evaluation. Working paper, Stanford University and NBER.

  • Joh, S. W. (1999). Strategic managerial incentive compensation in Japan: Relative performance evaluation and product market collusion. Review of Economics and Statistics, 81(2), 303–313.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kendall, M. (1991). Kendall’s advanced theory of statistics. London: Edward Arnold.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lambert, R. A. (2001). Contracting theory and accounting. Journal of Accounting & Economics, 32(1–3, December), 3–87.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lambert, R. A., & Larcker, D. F. (1987). An analysis of the use of accounting and market measures of performance in executive compensation contracts. Journal of Accounting Research, 25, 85–129.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Matsumura, E. M., & Shin, J. Y. (2006). An empirical analysis of an incentive plan with relative performance measures: Evidence from a postal service. The Accounting Review, 81, 533–566.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Milgrom, P., & Roberts, J. (1990). The economics of modern manufacturing: Technology, strategy, and organization. The American Economic Review, 80(3), 511–528.

    Google Scholar 

  • Murphy, K. J. (1999). Executive compensation. In O. Ashenfelter & D. Card (Eds.), Handbook of labor economics (pp. 2485–2563). Amsterdam: North-Holland.

    Google Scholar 

  • Prendergast, C. (1999). The provision of incentives in firms. Journal of Economic Literature, XXVII(March), 7–63.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rajgopal, S., Shevlin, T., & Zamora, V. (2006). CEOs’ outside employment opportunities and the lack of relative performance evaluation in compensation contracts. The Journal of Finance, 61(4), 1813–1844.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

For their helpful comments, we thank two anonymous referees, Ana Albuquerque, Larry Brown, Jörg Budde, Hui Chen, Jonathan Glover, Robert Göx, Thomas Hemmer, Stephan Hollander, Michael Krapp, David Larcker, Mark Penno, Jens-Robert Schöndube, Stefan Reichelstein, Alfred Wagenhofer, Rick Young, and workshop participants at Duke University, University of Bern, University of Fribourg, University of Graz, the American Accounting Association annual meeting, the Managerial Accounting Section mid-year meeting, the Colorado Summer Accounting Research Conference, the Southeast Summer Accounting Research Conference (SESARC), and the Tournaments, Contests, and Relative Performance Evaluation conference at North Carolina State University.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Shane S. Dikolli.

Appendix: Proofs

Appendix: Proofs

Proof of Proposition 1

As outlined, we relax the individual rationality constraint, CE i  = 0, and solve for each firm i the relaxed problem (8). Note that the relaxed problem is well behaved. Using the Lagrange-parameter λ i for the incentive compatibility constraint, (4), the Lagrangian for firm i is given by

$$ L_{i} = a_{i} - \kappa_{i} (a_{i} ) - \frac{{r_{i} }}{2}(v_{ii}^{2} {\text{Var}}[y_{i} ] + 2v_{ii} v_{ip} {\text{Cov}}[y_{i} ,y_{ip} (\varvec{\delta}_{i} )] + v_{ip}^{2} {\text{Var}}[y_{ip} (\varvec{\delta}_{i} )] - \lambda_{i} (\kappa_{i}^{\prime } (a_{i} ) - v_{ii} ) $$
(18)

where Var[y i ] = σ 2 i  + μ 2 i σ 2 m , \( {\text{Cov}}[y_{i} ,y_{ip} (\varvec{\delta}_{i} )] = \mu_{i} \sum\nolimits_{j = 1}^{n} {\delta_{ij} \mu_{j} \sigma_{m}^{2} } \), and \( {\text{Var}}[y_{ip} (\varvec{\delta}_{i} )] = \sum\nolimits_{j = 1}^{n} {\delta_{ij}^{2} (\sigma_{j}^{2} + \mu_{j}^{2} \sigma_{m}^{2} )} \).

From (18), the Karush–Kuhn–Tucker conditions are given by

$$ \partial L_{i} /\partial a_{i} = 1 - \kappa_{i}^{\prime } (a_{i} ) - \lambda_{i} \kappa_{i}^{\prime \prime } (a_{i} ) = 0, $$
(19)
$$ \partial L_{i} /\partial v_{ii} = - r_{i} (v_{ii} {\text{Var}}[y_{i} ] + v_{ip} {\text{Cov}}[y_{i} ,y_{ip} (\varvec{\delta}_{i} )]) + \lambda_{i} = 0, $$
(20)
$$ \partial L_{i} /\partial v_{ip} = - r_{i} (v_{ii} {\text{Cov}}[y_{i} ,y_{ip} (\varvec{\delta}_{i} )] + v_{ip} {\text{Var}}[y_{ip} (\varvec{\delta}_{i} )]) = 0, $$
(21)
$$ \partial L_{i} /\partial \lambda_{i} = \kappa_{i}^{\prime } (a_{i} ) - v_{ii} = 0, $$
(22)

and for k = 1,…,n, k ≠ i,

$$ \begin{aligned} \frac{{\partial L_{i} }}{{\partial \delta_{ik} }} = & - \frac{{r_{i} }}{2}\left( {2v_{ii} v_{ip} \frac{{\partial {\text{Cov}}[y_{i} ,y_{ip} ({\varvec{\delta}}_{i} )]}}{{\partial \delta_{ik} }} + v_{ip}^{2} \frac{{\partial {\text{Var}}[y_{ip} ({\varvec{\delta}}_{i} )]}}{{\partial \delta_{ik} }}} \right) \\ = & - r_{i} v_{ip} (v_{ii} \mu_{i} \mu_{k} \sigma_{m}^{2} + v_{ip} \delta_{ik} (\sigma_{k}^{2} + \mu_{k}^{2} \sigma_{m}^{2} )) = 0. \\ \end{aligned} $$
(23)

Normalizing, \( \sum\nolimits_{k = 1}^{n} {\varvec{\delta}_{ik} = 1} \), and solving (19)–(23) yields (9a), (9b), and (9c). The rest of the proof follows as outlined in the text. □

Proof of Corollary 1

The partial correlation, \( \rho_{ij{\cdot}\dag } \), is defined by (Kendall 1991)

$$ \rho_{ij{\cdot}\dag } = \frac{{\rho_{ij} - \rho_{i\dag }\rho_{j\dag } }}{{\sqrt {(1 - \rho_{i\dag }^{2} )(1 - \rho_{j\dag}^{2} )} }}, $$

with \( \rho_{ij} = {\text{Corr}}\left[ {y_{i} ,y_{j} } \right] \); \( \rho_{i\dag } = {\text{Corr}}[y_{i} ,y_{ip} (\varvec{\delta}_{i}^{\dag } )]; \) and \( \rho_{j\dag } = {\text{Corr}}[y_{j} ,y_{jp} (\varvec{\delta}_{i}^{\dag } )] \) denoting the associated correlation coefficients. From (22) and (9b), we get for the risk-minimized aggregation, \( \varvec{\delta}_{i}^{\dag } \):

$$ 2\frac{{\partial {\text{Cov}}[y_{i} ,y_{ip}(\varvec{\delta}_{i}^{\dag } )]}}{{\partial {{\updelta}}_{ij} }} =- \frac{{v_{ip}^{\dag } }}{{v_{ii}^{\dag } }}\frac{{\partial{\text{Var}}[y_{ip} (\varvec{\delta}_{i}^{\dag } )]}}{{\partial{{\updelta}}_{ij} }} = \frac{{{\text{Cov}}[y_{i} ,y_{ip}(\varvec{\delta}_{i}^{\dag } )]}}{{{\text{Var[}}y_{ip}(\varvec{\delta}_{i}^{\dag } )]}}\frac{{\partial{\text{Var}}[y_{ip} (\varvec{\delta}_{i}^{\dag } )]}}{{\partial{{\updelta}}_{ij} }}\quad {\text{for}}\,{\text{all}}\quad j \ne i.$$
(24)

Using \( \frac{{\partial {\text{Cov}}[ {y_{i} ,\sum\nolimits_{j = 1}^{n} {\delta_{ij} y_{j} } }]}}{{\partial \delta_{ij} }} = {\text{Cov}}[y_{i} ,y_{j} ] \) and \( \frac{{\partial {\text{Var}}[y_{ip} (\varvec{\delta}_{i} )]}}{{\partial \delta_{ij} }} = \frac{{\partial {\text{Cov}}\left[ {\sum\nolimits_{k = 1}^{n} {\delta_{ik} y_{k} }, \sum\nolimits_{k = 1}^{n} {\delta_{ik} y_{k} } } \right]}}{{\partial \delta_{ij} }} = 2{\text{Cov}}\left[ {\sum\nolimits_{k = 1}^{n} {\delta_{ik} y_{k} ,y_{j} } } \right] = 2{\text{Cov}}[y_{ip} (\varvec{\delta}_{i} ),y_{j} ] \), we can rewrite (24) as

$$ {\text{Cov}}[y_{i} ,y_{j} ] = \frac{{{\text{Cov}}[y_{i} ,y_{ip} (\varvec{\delta}_{i}^{\dag } )]{\text{Cov}}[y_{ip} (\varvec{\delta}_{i}^{\dag } ),y_{j} ]}}{{{\text{Var}}[y_{ip} (\varvec{\delta}_{i}^{\dag } )]}} = \rho_{i\dag } \rho_{j\dag } {\text{SD}}[y_{i} ]{\text{SD}}[y_{j} ]\quad {\text{for}}\,{\text{all}}\quad j \ne i. $$
(25)

Noting Cov[y i , y j ] = ρ ij SD[y i ]SD[y j ], (25) implies ρ ij  = ρ i ρ j for all j ≠ i and, given the above definition of ρ ij·†, then it follows that ρ ij·† = 0, for all j ≠ i. □

Proof of Lemma 1

Due to the orthogonal regression in (12a) and (12b), the variables \( y_{u} (\varvec{\delta}^{e} ) \) and \( y_{s} (\varvec{\delta}^{e} ) \) are not correlated. The regression coefficient in (15) is given by

$$ \hat{\beta }_{s} (\varvec{\delta}^{b} ,\varvec{\delta}^{e} ) = {\text{Cov}}[w(\varvec{\delta}^{b} ),y_{s} (\varvec{\delta}^{e} )]/{\text{Var}}[y_{s} (\varvec{\delta}^{e} )]. $$
(26)

Substituting \( y_{s} (\varvec{\delta}^{e} ) = ({\text{Cov}}[y_{f} ,y_{p} (\varvec{\delta}^{e} )]/{\text{Var}}[y_{p} (\varvec{\delta}^{e} )])y_{p} (\varvec{\delta}^{e} ) \) as per (12a), \( w (\varvec{\delta}^{b} ) = f^{b} + v_{f}^{b} y_{f} + v_{p}^{b} y_{p} (\varvec{\delta}^{b} ), \) and the ratio \( v_{p}^{b} /v_{f}^{b} = - {\text{Cov}}[y_{f} ,y_{p} (\varvec{\delta}^{b} )]/{\text{Var}}[y_{p} (\varvec{\delta}^{b} )] \) into (26), and simplifying yields

$$ \hat{\beta }_{s} (\varvec{\delta}^{b} ,\varvec{\delta}^{e} ) = \left( {1 - \frac{{{\text{Cov}}[y_{f} ,y_{p} (\varvec{\delta}^{b} )]{\text{Cov}}[y_{p} (\varvec{\delta}^{e} ),y_{p} (\varvec{\delta}^{b} )]}}{{{\text{Cov}}[y_{f} ,y_{p} (\varvec{\delta}^{e} )]{\text{Var}}[y_{p} (\varvec{\delta}^{b} )]}}} \right)v_{f}^{b} . $$
(27)

Using the correlation coefficients, ρ fb , ρ be , and ρ fe , and simplifying (27) results in (15). Finally, using the partial correlation coefficient, ρ fe·b  = (ρ fe  − ρ fb ρ be )[(1 − ρ 2 fb )(1 − ρ 2 be )]−1/2, yields the right hand side of (15). □

Proof of Proposition 2

Given risk-minimized aggregated peer performance, \( y_{p}^{b} = y_{p} (\varvec{\delta}^{\dag } ) \), following Corollary 1, the performance of the focal firm, y f , is conditionally independent from the performance of any peer firm, y j , that is, ρ fj  − ρ fb ρ jb  = 0 for any peer firm j ≠ f. Accordingly, the performance of the focal firm is also conditionally independent from any aggregation of peer performance, implying that

$$ \rho_{fe} - \rho_{fb} \rho_{be} = 0,\quad {\text{for}}\,{\text{any}}\,{\text{aggregation}}\,\varvec{\delta}^{e} \ne 0. $$
(28)

Substituting (28) in (15) completes the proof. □

Proof of Proposition 3

From Lemma 1, \( \hat{\beta }_{s} (\varvec{\delta}^{b} ,\varvec{\delta}^{e} ) = 0 \) if and only if ρ fe  = ρ fb ρ be . As shown in (25), ρ fe  = ρ fb ρ be can be equivalently restated as

$$ {\text{Cov}}[y_{f} ,y_{p} (\varvec{\delta}^{e} )]/{\text{Cov}}[y_{f} ,y_{p} (\varvec{\delta}^{b} )] = {\text{Cov}}[y_{p} (\varvec{\delta}^{e} ),y_{p} (\varvec{\delta}^{b} )]/{\text{Var}}[y_{p} (\varvec{\delta}^{b} )]. $$
(29)

The left side of (29) does not depend on firm specific risk, since \( {\text{Cov}}[y_{f} ,y_{p} (\varvec{\delta}^{e} )] = \mu_{f} \sum\nolimits_{j} {} \delta_{j}^{e} \mu_{j} \sigma_{m}^{2} ,\,{\text{Cov}}[y_{f} ,y_{p} (\varvec{\delta}^{b} )] = \mu_{f} \sum\nolimits_{j} {} \delta_{j}^{b} \mu_{j} \sigma_{m}^{2} , \) and thus \( {\text{Cov}}[y_{f} ,y_{p} (\varvec{\delta}^{e} )]/{\text{Cov}}[y_{f} ,y_{p} (\varvec{\delta}^{b} )] = (\sum\nolimits_{j} {} \delta_{j}^{e} \mu_{j} )/(\sum\nolimits_{j} {} \delta_{j}^{b} \mu_{j} ). \)

The right side of (29), \( {\text{Cov}}[y_{p} (\varvec{\delta}^{e} ),y_{p} (\varvec{\delta}^{b} )]/{\text{Var}}[y_{p} (\varvec{\delta}^{b} )] \), is the regression coefficient when regressing the empiricist’s peer-group performance, \( y_{p} (\varvec{\delta}^{e} ) \), on the board’s peer-group performance, \( y_{p} (\varvec{\delta}^{b} ) \). In general, this regression coefficient depends on each peer j’s firm-specific risk, σ 2 j , that is,

$$ {\text{Cov}}[y_{p} (\varvec{\delta}^{e} ),y_{p} (\varvec{\delta}^{b} )] = \sum\limits_{j} {\delta_{j}^{e} \delta_{j}^{b} \sigma_{j}^{2} } + \left( {\sum\limits_{j} {\delta_{j}^{e} \mu_{j} } } \right)\left( {\sum\limits_{j} {\delta_{j}^{b} \mu_{j} } } \right)\sigma_{m}^{2} ,\,{\text{and}} $$
(30)
$$ {\text{Var}}[y_{p} (\varvec{\delta}^{b} )] = \sum\limits_{j} {(\delta_{j}^{b} )^{2} \sigma_{j}^{2} } + \left( {\sum\limits_{j} {\delta_{j}^{b} \mu_{j} } } \right)^{2} \sigma_{m}^{2} . $$
(31)

Since the left side of (29) is independent of firm-specific risk, the condition \( \hat{\beta }_{s} (\varvec{\delta}^{b} ,\varvec{\delta}^{e} ) = 0 \) is only satisfied if the right side of (29) is not affected by the peers’ firm-specific risk. This result, however, requires that either the board’s peer-group performance is a sufficient statistic for the empiricist’s peer-group performance, implying \( \varvec{\delta}^{b} =\varvec{\delta}^{\dag } \), or that the board’s peer-group performance and the empiricist’s peer-group performance coincide, that is, \( \varvec{\delta}^{b} =\varvec{\delta}^{e} . \)

Proof of Proposition 4

Using (16), the regression coefficient is characterized by

$$ \hat{\beta }_{s} (0,\varvec{\delta}^{e} ) = {\text{Cov}}[w(0),y_{s} (\varvec{\delta}^{e} )]/{\text{Var}}[y_{s} (\varvec{\delta}^{e} )]. $$
(32)

Substituting into (32) the agent’s compensation, (16), plus the definition for \( y_{s} (\varvec{\delta}^{e} ) \), (12a), and simplifying yields

$$ \hat{\beta }_{s} (0,\varvec{\delta}^{e} ) =\frac{{{\text{Cov}}\left[ {v_{f}^{0} y_{f},\frac{{{\text{Cov}}[y_{f} ,y_{p} (\varvec{\delta}^{e})]}}{{{\text{Var}}[y_{p} (\varvec{\delta}^{e} )]}}y_{p}(\varvec{\delta}^{e} )} \right]}}{{{\text{Var}}\left[{\frac{{{\text{Cov}}[y_{f} ,y_{p} (\varvec{\delta}^{e})]}}{{{\text{Var}}[y_{p} (\varvec{\delta}^{e} )]}}y_{p}(\varvec{\delta}^{e} )} \right]}} = \frac{{{\frac{{{\text{Cov}}[y_{f} ,y_{p} (\varvec{\delta}^{e})]}}{{{\text{Var}}[y_{p} (\varvec{\delta}^{e} )]}}} ^{2} }}{{{\frac{{{\text{Cov}}[y_{f} ,y_{p} (\varvec{\delta}^{e})]}}{{{\text{Var}}[y_{p} (\varvec{\delta}^{e} )]}}} ^{2}}}v_{f}^{0} = v_{f}^{0} \ne 0. $$

Proof of Proposition 5

From Lemma 1, we get

$$ \begin{aligned} \hat{\beta }_{s} (\varvec{\delta}^{b} ,\varvec{\delta}^{e} ) = & \left( {1 - \frac{{\rho_{fb} \rho_{be} }}{{\rho_{fe} }}} \right)v_{f}^{b} = \left( {1 - \frac{{{\text{Cov}}[y_{f} ,y_{p} (\varvec{\delta}^{b} )]}}{{{\text{Cov}}[y_{f} ,y_{p} (\varvec{\delta}^{e} )]}}\frac{{{\text{Cov}}[y_{p} (\varvec{\delta}^{b} ),y_{p} (\varvec{\delta}^{e} )]}}{{{\text{Var}}[y_{p} (\varvec{\delta}^{b} )]}}} \right)v_{f}^{b} \\ = & \left( {1 - \frac{{\mu_{f} \mu_{b} \sigma_{m}^{2} }}{{\mu_{f} \mu_{e} \sigma_{m}^{2} }}\frac{{{\text{Cov}}[y_{p} ({{\updelta}}^{b} ),y_{p} ({{\updelta}}^{e} )]}}{{\mu_{b}^{2} \sigma_{m}^{2} + \sigma_{b}^{2} }}} \right)v_{f}^{b} . \\ \end{aligned} $$

Noting that in case (i):

$$ {\text{Cov}}[y_{p} (\varvec{\delta}^{b} ),y_{p} (\varvec{\delta}^{e} )] = \mu_{b} \mu_{e} \sigma_{m}^{2} + {\text{Cov}}\left[ {\sum\limits_{{j \in I_{b} }} {\delta_{j}^{e} \varepsilon_{j} } ,\sum\limits_{{j \in I_{b} }} {\delta_{j}^{b} \varepsilon_{j} } } \right] = \mu_{b} \mu_{e} \sigma_{m}^{2} + \sum\limits_{{j \in I_{b} }} {\delta_{j}^{e} \delta_{j}^{b} \sigma_{j}^{2} } , $$

in Case (ii), \( {\text{Cov}}[y_{p} (\varvec{\delta}^{b} ),y_{p} (\varvec{\delta}^{e} )] = \mu_{b} \mu_{e} \sigma_{m}^{2} + {\text{Cov[}}\sum\nolimits_{{j \in I_{e} }} {\delta_{j}^{e} \varepsilon_{j} } ,\sum\nolimits_{{j \in I_{b} }} {\delta_{j}^{b} \varepsilon_{j} } ]= \mu_{b} \mu_{e} \sigma_{m}^{2} + \sum\nolimits_{{j \in I_{e} }} {\delta_{j}^{e} \delta_{j}^{b} \sigma_{j}^{2} } , \) and in Case (iii), \( {\text{Cov}}[y_{p} (\varvec{\delta}^{b} ),y_{p} (\varvec{\delta}^{e} )] = \mu_{b} \mu_{e} \sigma_{m}^{2} , \) proves our result. □

Proof of Proposition 6

Using (12b), (13), and (14), we get:

$$ \begin{aligned} \hat{\beta }_{u} (\varvec{\delta}^{b} ,\varvec{\delta}^{e} ) = & {\text{Cov}}[w(\varvec{\delta}^{b} ),y_{u} (\varvec{\delta}^{e} )]/{\text{Var}}[y_{u} (\varvec{\delta}^{e} )] \\ = & {\text{Cov}}\left[ {v_{f}^{b} \left( {y_{f} + \frac{{v_{p}^{b} }}{{v_{f}^{b} }}y_{p} (\varvec{\delta}^{b} )} \right),y_{f} - \frac{{{\text{Cov}}[y_{f} ,y_{p} (\varvec{\delta}^{b} )]y_{p} (\varvec{\delta}^{e} )}}{{{\text{Var}}[y_{p} (\varvec{\delta}^{b} )]}}} \right]/{\text{Var}}\left[ {y_{f} - \frac{{{\text{Cov}}[y_{f} ,y_{p} (\varvec{\delta}^{e} )]y_{p} (\varvec{\delta}^{e} )}}{{{\text{Var}}[y_{p} (\varvec{\delta}^{b} )]}}} \right] \\ = & \frac{{1 - \rho_{fe}^{2} - \rho_{fb}^{2} - \rho_{fb} \rho_{fe} \rho_{be} }}{{1 - \rho_{fe}^{2} }}v_{f}^{b} . \\ \end{aligned} $$

Using \( \hat{\beta }_{s} (\varvec{\delta}^{b} ,\varvec{\delta}^{e} ) = [1 - (\rho_{fb} \rho_{be} /\rho_{fe} )]v_{f}^{b} \) from Lemma 1 and rearranging yields (17), which is zero when ρ be·f  = 0. □

Proof of Proposition 7

Using (16), the regression coefficient is characterized by

$$ \begin{aligned} \hat{\beta }_{u} (0,\varvec{\delta}^{e} ) = & {\text{Cov}}[w(0),y_{u} (\varvec{\delta}^{e} )]/{\text{Var}}[y_{u} (\varvec{\delta}^{e} )] \\ = & {\text{Cov}}\left[ {v_{f}^{0} y_{f} ,y_{f} - \frac{{{\text{Cov}}[y_{f} ,y_{p} (\varvec{\delta}^{e} )]y_{p} (\varvec{\delta}^{e} )}}{{{\text{Var}}[y_{p} (\varvec{\delta}^{e} )]}}} \right]/{\text{Var}}\left[ {y_{f} - \frac{{{\text{Cov}}[y_{f} ,y_{p} (\varvec{\delta}^{e} )]y_{p} (\varvec{\delta}^{e} )}}{{{\text{Var}}[y_{p} (\varvec{\delta}^{e} )]}}} \right] \\ = & v_{f}^{0} \left( {{\text{Var}}[y_{f} ] - \frac{{{\text{Cov}}[y_{f} ,y_{p} (\varvec{\delta}^{e} )]^{2} }}{{{\text{Var}}[y_{p} (\varvec{\delta}^{e} )]}}} \right)/\left( {{\text{Var}}[y_{f} ] - \frac{{{\text{Cov}}[y_{f} ,y_{p} (\varvec{\delta}^{e} )]^{2} }}{{{\text{Var}}[y_{p} (\varvec{\delta}^{e} )]}}} \right) = v_{f}^{0} . \\ \end{aligned} $$

Recalling from Proposition 4, \( \hat{\beta }_{s} (0,\varvec{\delta}^{e} ) = v_{f}^{0} , \) yields \( \hat{\beta }_{u} (0,\varvec{\delta}^{e} ) - \hat{\beta }_{s} (0,\varvec{\delta}^{e} ) = 0 \) for any aggregation \( \varvec{\delta}^{e} \ne 0. \)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Dikolli, S.S., Hofmann, C. & Pfeiffer, T. Relative performance evaluation and peer-performance summarization errors. Rev Account Stud 18, 34–65 (2013). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11142-012-9212-9

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11142-012-9212-9

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation