Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

A dynamic Duverger’s law

  • Published:
Public Choice Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Electoral systems promote strategic voting and affect party systems. Duverger (Les partis politiques, 1951) proposed that plurality rule leads to bi-partyism and proportional representation leads to multi-partyism. We show that in a dynamic setting, these static effects also lead to a higher option value for existing minor parties under plurality rule, so their incentive to exit the party system is mitigated by their future benefits from continued participation. The predictions of our model are consistent with multiple cross-sectional predictions on the comparative number of parties under plurality rule and proportional representation. In particular, there could be more parties under plurality rule than under proportional representation at any point in time. However, our model makes a unique time-series prediction: the number of parties under plurality rule should be less variable than under proportional representation. We provide extensive empirical evidence in support of these results.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Our data come from the Constituency-Level Elections (CLE) Dataset (Brancati 2013).

  2. In Myerson and Weber (1993) and Palfrey (1989), an expected loser gets no votes, while in Myatt (2007), since voters face aggregate uncertainty, an expected loser is hurt by voters’ coordination but still receives some votes

  3. See references therein for related finding in experimental settings.

  4. An alternative would be to assume that, say, a party of type 1 is present in all elections, and that two left of center interest groups, of types -1 and 0, decide whether or not to support parties in each election. Such a model is almost equivalent to our specification and would yield closely related results.

  5. We could allow for persistence in electoral states, although this would add computational complexity without affecting our central conclusions. Likewise, the simplifying assumption that non-centrist preference states \(s_{1}\) and \(s_{-1}\) occur with equal probability allows us to exploit symmetry, but it is not essential.

  6. See Crutzen and Sahuguet (2009), Hamlin and Hjortlund (2000), Ortuno-Ortin (1997) and Myerson (1993) for related reduced-form treatments of post-election legislative arrangements under proportional representation.

  7. That the centrist party never benefits from the coordination costs imposed on minor parties is assumed for convenience and is not important for our results.

  8. The proofs of propositions 1 and 2, which follow from standard equilibrium verification arguments, are in the supplementary appendix.

  9. Interest group j’s actions are not yet specified if the preference state is \(s_{-j}\) and no interest groups supported parties in the previous elections (i.e., \(\phi ^{t}=\emptyset\)). These histories only occur off the equilibrium path, and the details are in the proof of proposition 2 in the online Supplementary appendix.

  10. Condition (2) does not play a role in the proof of proposition 2, but is included in order to establish that the equilibria \(\underline{\sigma }^{{\text{PL}}}\) and \(\overline{\sigma }^{{\text{PL}}}\) can exist under plurality under parametric restrictions that ensure that \(\sigma ^{{\text{PR}}}\) is the unique equilibrium under proportional representation. That the conditions of proposition 2 can be met for some parameter values can be shown by example: the neighborhood of the point with \(\delta \approx 1\), \(\underline{c}=\overline{c}=\frac{1}{4}\), \(\underline{p}=p=\frac{1}{4}\), \(\beta =\frac{1}{9}\), \(\overline{u}-u=1\) and \(u-\underline{u}=\frac{3}{2}\) contains an open set of parameters for which the conditions of proposition 2 are met and for which \(\underline{\alpha }<\underline{p}-\beta\) and \(\overline{\alpha }>0\), so that both \(\overline{\sigma }^{{\text{PL}}}\) and \(\underline{\sigma }^{{\text{PL}}}\) can be equilibria at those parameters, depending on the value of \(\alpha\).

  11. In all but one country in our sample, this binary variable does not change over time.

  12. Effective district magnitude can differ from average district magnitude, which is defined as the total number of legislative seats divided by the number of electoral districts. Taagepera and Shugart (1989) argue that effective district magnitude is the superior measure of the proportionality of an electoral system. To the extent that a legislature does not feature at-large seats, these measures are identical.

  13. See also Lijphart (1994) and Taagepera and Grofman (2003).

  14. We report the countries and elections covered by our data in Table B1 of the supplementary appendix. The CLE unfortunately does not contain data on all democratic elections since 1945. Indeed, no single source does. We use only those elections contained in the CLE for our analysis and do not supplement our data set with data from other sources in order to maintain consistent reporting. We replicated our analysis using a similar (thought not identical) sample of elections from the CLEA data set and obtained similar results. We report results using only the CLE because this is the data set that has been primarily used to construct disproportionality indices (Gallagher and Mitchell 2005).

  15. Our decade dummies are defined for the periods 1940–1949, 1950–1959,…, 2000–2009. We replicated our analysis defining decade dummies for all possible periods (e.g., 1948–1957,…) and obtained results that were statistically indistinguishable from those presented.

  16. In the results presented, we include polynomials of all orders up to 6 in \(D_{ct}\) and \(\log D_{ct}\) (i.e., 12 additional covariates). As a robustness check, we replicated our analysis with polynomials of all orders up to 10 and obtained qualitatively similar and precise estimates of our coefficients of interest.

  17. We specify flexible controls for the number of parties in an analogous manner to the number of districts (i.e., 12 additional covariates).

  18. The total numbers of entries, exits, movements, districts and parties are all considered continuous variables. By specifying these variables in logarithms, we mitigate measurement error by ensuring that electoral systems with many parties (which tend to be more proportional, per the static results) do not simply exhibit a large amount of partisan churn by construction. Rather, any such relationship between proportionality and partisan churn should be interpreted as independent of the total number of parties. We provide further support for this interpretation by flexibly controlling for the number of parties in some specifications. Because elections may feature zero entries, exits or net movements, we transform these variables as \(\log \left( 1+x\right)\) in order to conserve data.

  19. We present results with and without flexible controls for the number of parties because the inclusion of these controls may adversely affect the interpretation of the relationship of interest when using the disproportionality index.

  20. In Tables B2 and B3 of the supplementary appendix, we reproduce these results using total party entries and total party exits as the dependent variables respectively. We find broadly consistent and robust results.

References

  • Anagol, S., & Fujiwara, T. (2015). The runner-up effect. Journal of Political Economy (forthcoming).

  • Austen-Smith, D. (2000). Redistributing income under proportional representation. Journal of Political Economy, 108(6), 1235–1269.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Austen-Smith, D., & Banks, J. (1988). Elections, coalitions, and legislative outcomes. American Political Science Review, 82(02), 405–422.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baron, D. P., & Diermeier, D. (2001). Elections, governments, and parliaments in proportional representation systems. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 116(3), 933–967.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Benoit, K. (2002). The endogeneity problem in electoral studies: A critical re-examination of Duverger’s mechanical effect. Electoral Studies, 21(1), 35–46.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Benoit, K. (2006). Duverger’s law and the study of electoral systems. French Politics, 4(1), 69–83.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blais, A., & Carty, R. K. (1991). The psychological impact of electoral laws: measuring Duverger’s elusive factor. British Journal of Political Science, 21(1), 79–93.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brancati, D. (2013). Global Elections Dataset. New York: Global Elections Database, http://www.globalelectionsdatabase.com.

  • Chhibber, P., & Kollman, K. (1998). Party aggregation and the number of parties in india and the united states. American Political Science Review, 92(2), 329–342.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chhibber, P., & Murali, G. (2006). Duvergerian dynamics in the Indian states federalism and the number of parties in the state assembly elections. Party Politics, 12(1), 5–34.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cox, G. W. (1997). Making votes count: Strategic coordination in the world’s electoral systems (Vol. 7). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Crutzen, B. S., & Sahuguet, N. (2009). Redistributive politics with distortionary taxation. Journal of Economic Theory, 144(1), 264–279.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Diwakar, R. (2007). Duverger’s law and the size of the indian party system. Party Politics, 13(5), 539–561.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Duverger, M. (1951). Les partis politiques. Paris: Armand Colin.

    Google Scholar 

  • Faravelli, M., & Sanchez-Pages, S. (2014). (Don’t) make my vote count. Journal of Theoretical Politics, 27(4), 1–26.

    Google Scholar 

  • Feddersen, T., Sened, I., & Wright, S. (1990). Rational voting and candidate entry under plurality rule. American Journal of Political Science, 34, 1005–1016.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Feddersen, T. J. (1992). A voting model implying Duverger’s law and positive turnout. American Journal of Political Science, 36, 938–962.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fey, M. (1997). Stability and coordination in Duverger’s law: A formal model of preelection polls and strategic voting. American Political Science Review, 91(1), 135–147.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fujiwara, T. (2011). A regression discontinuity test of strategic voting and Duverger’s law. Quarterly Journal of Political Science, 6(3–4), 197–233.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gaines, B. J. (1999). Duverger’s law and the meaning of Canadian exceptionalism. Comparative Political Studies, 32(7), 835–861.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gallagher, M. (1991). Proportionality, disproportionality and electoral systems. Electoral Studies, 10(1), 33–51.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gallagher, M., & Mitchell, P. (2005). The politics of electoral systems. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Hamlin, A., & Hjortlund, M. (2000). Proportional representation with citizen candidates. Public Choice, 103(3–4), 205–230.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Herrera, H., Morelli, M., & Palfrey, T. (2014). Turnout and power sharing. The Economic Journal, 124(574), F131–F162.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Indridason, I. H. (2011). Proportional representation, majoritarian legislatures, and coalitional voting. American Journal of Political Science, 55(4), 955–971.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lijphart, A. (1994). Electoral systems and party systems: A study of twenty-seven democracies, 1945–1990. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Mershon, C., & Shvetsova, O. (2013). The microfoundations of party system stability in legislatures. The Journal of Politics, 75(04), 865–878.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Morelli, M. (2004). Party formation and policy outcomes under different electoral systems. The Review of Economic Studies, 71(3), 829–853.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Myatt, D. P. (2007). On the theory of strategic voting. The Review of Economic Studies, 74(1), 255–281.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Myerson, R. B. (1993). Effectiveness of electoral systems for reducing government corruption: A game-theoretic analysis. Games and Economic Behavior, 5(1), 118–132.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Myerson, R. B., & Weber, R. J. (1993). A theory of voting equilibria. American Political Science Review, 87(01), 102–114.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Neto, O. A., & Cox, G. W. (1997). Electoral institutions, cleavage structures, and the number of parties. American Journal of Political Science, 41(1), 149–174.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ordeshook, P. C., & Shvetsova, O. V. (1994). Ethnic heterogeneity, district magnitude, and the number of parties. American Journal of Political Science, 38(1), 100–123.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ortuno-Ortin, I. (1997). A spatial model of political competition and proportional representation. Social Choice and Welfare, 14(3), 427–438.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Osborne, M. J., & Slivinski, A. (1996). A model of political competition with citizen-candidates. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 111(1), 65–96.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Palfrey, T. (1989). A mathematical proof of Duverger’s law. In P. C. Ordeshook (Ed.), Models of strategic choice in politics. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Persson, T., & Tabellini, G. E. (2005). The economic effects of constitutions. Cambridge: MIT press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Powell, G. B. (2000). Elections as instruments of democracy: Majoritarian and proportional visions. New Haven: Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Reed, S. R. (2001). Duverger’s law is working in Italy. Comparative Political Studies, 34(3), 312–327.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Riker, W. H. (1982). The two-party system and Duverger’s law: An essay on the history of political science. The American Political Science Review, 76(4), 753–766.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shugart, M. S. (2005). Comparative electoral systems research: the maturation of a field and new challenges ahead. In M. Gallagher & P. Mitchell (Eds.), The politics of electoral systems. Cambridge: Cambridge Univiversity Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Taagepera, R., & Grofman, B. (2003). Mapping the indices of seats-votes disproportionality and inter-election volatility. Party Politics, 9(6), 659–677.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Taagepera, R., & Shugart, M. S. (1989). Seats and votes: The effects and determinants of electoral systems. New Haven: Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

We thank Catherine Bobtcheff, Daniel Diermeier, Carlo Prato, seminar audiences at Carleton, UQAM and Ryerson, conference participants at CPEG 2013, Elections and Electoral Institutions IAST 2014, MPSA 2014, Formal Theory and Comparative Politics 2015, and Scott Legree for excellent research assistance. Finally, the editors and two referees provided excellent comments and suggestions.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Vikram Maheshri.

Electronic supplementary material

Below is the link to the electronic supplementary material.

Supplementary material 1 (pdf 124 KB)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Forand, J.G., Maheshri, V. A dynamic Duverger’s law. Public Choice 165, 285–306 (2015). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-016-0309-8

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-016-0309-8

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation