Skip to main content
Log in

Public choice and the economic analysis of anarchy: a survey

  • Survey Article
  • Published:
Public Choice Aims and scope Submit manuscript

“It is high time to shift out of the pragmatic mind-set that has been our national characteristic. The grand alternatives for social organization must be reconsidered. The loss of faith in the socialist dream has not, and probably will not, restore faith in laissez-faire. But what are the effective alternatives? Does anarchism deserve a hearing, and, if so, what sort of anarchism?”

James M. Buchanan (1974: 914)

Abstract

Public choice economists began studying anarchy in the 1970s. Since then, the amount of research on anarchy has burgeoned. This article surveys the important public choice contributions to the economics of anarchy. Following early public choice economists, many economists are researching how individuals interact without government. From non-public-interested explanations of the creation of government to historical studies of internalizing externalities under anarchy, public choice scholars are arriving at a more realistic perspective of human interaction with and without government. Although the economics of politics receives more attention, the economics of anarchy is an important area of research in public choice.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

References

  • Anderson, T. L., & Hill, P. J. (1979). An American experiment in anarcho-capitalism: The not so wild, wild, west. Journal of Libertarian Studies, 3, 9–29.

    Google Scholar 

  • Anderson, T. L., & Hill, P. J. (2004). The not so wild, wild west: Property rights on the frontier. Stanford: Stanford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Anderson, J. E., & Marcouiller, D. (2005). Anarchy and autarky: endogenous predation as a barrier to trade. International Economic Review, 46(1), 189–213.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Axelrod, R. (1981). The emergence of cooperation among egoists. American Political Science Review, 75, 306–318

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Axelrod, R. (1984). The evolution of cooperation. New York: Basic Books.

    Google Scholar 

  • Barzel, Y. (2002). A theory of the state: economic rights, legal rights, and the scope of the state. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Basu, K. (2000). A study of the social and political foundations of economics. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bates, R. H. (2008). When things fell apart: State failure in late-century Africa. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Beaulier, S. (2005). Polycentrism and power: A reply to Warren Samuels. In E. P. Stringham (Ed.), Anarchy, state and public choice (pp. 178–190). Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Benson, B. (1988). Legal evolution in primitive societies. Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics, 144, 772–788.

    Google Scholar 

  • Benson, B. (1989). The spontaneous evolution of commercial law. Southern Economic Journal, 55, 644–661.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Benson, B. L. (1990). The enterprise of law: Justice without the state. San Francisco: Pacific Research Institute for Public Policy.

    Google Scholar 

  • Benson, B. L. (1991). Reciprocal exchange as the basis for recognition of law: Examples from American history. Journal of Libertarian Studies, 10, 53–82.

    Google Scholar 

  • Benson, B. L. (1994). Are public goods really common pools? Considerations of the evolution of policing and highways in England. Economic Inquiry, 32, 249–271.

    Google Scholar 

  • Benson, B. L. (1998). To serve and protect: Privatization and community in criminal justice. New York: New York University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Benson, B. (2005). The spontaneous evolution of cyber law: Norms, property rights, contracting, dispute resolution and enforcement without the state. Journal of Law, Economics & Policy, 1(2), 269–348.

    Google Scholar 

  • Berman, H. (1983). Law and revolution: The formation of the Western legal tradition. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bernstein, L. (1992). Opting out of the legal system: Extralegal contractual relations in the diamond industry. Journal of Legal Studies, 21(1), 115–157.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Boettke, P. (1993). Why Perestroika failed: The politics and economics of socialist transformation. New York: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Boettke, P. (2005). Anarchism as a progressive research program in political economy. In E. P. Stringham (Ed.), Anarchy, state and public choice (pp. 206–220). Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Boettke, P., & Leeson, P. (2008, forthcoming). Two-tiered entrepreneurship and economic development. International Review of Law and Economics

  • Bos, D., & Kolmar, M. (2003). Anarchy, efficiency, and redistribution. Journal of Public Economics, 87(11), 2431–2457.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Block, W., & DiLorenzo, T. (2000). Is voluntary government possible? A critique of constitutional economics. Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics, 156, 567–582.

    Google Scholar 

  • Buchanan, J. (1972). Before public choice. In G. Tullock (Ed.), Explorations in the theory of anarchy (pp. 27–37). Blacksburg: Center for Study of Public Choice.

    Google Scholar 

  • Buchanan, J. (1973). A defense of organized crime? In S. Rottenberg (Ed.), Economics of crime and punishment. Washington: American Enterprise Institute.

    Google Scholar 

  • Buchanan, J. (1974). Review of The machinery of freedom: Guide to a radical capitalism. Journal of Economic Literature, 12, 914–915.

    Google Scholar 

  • Buchanan, J. (1975). The limits of liberty: Between anarchy and Leviathan. Chicago: University of Chicago.

    Google Scholar 

  • Buchanan, J. (1986). From redistributive churning to the plantation state. Public Choice, 51, 241–243.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Buchanan, J. M. (1992). Better than plowing and other personal essays. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Buchanan, J. M. (2003). Public choice: the origins and development of a research program. Fairfax: Center for Study of Public Choice.

    Google Scholar 

  • Buchanan, J. M. (2004). Heraclitian vespers. In J. Pitt, D. Salehi-Isfahami, & D. Echel (Eds.), The production and diffusion of public choice policy economy (pp. 263–271). Malden: Blackwell.

    Google Scholar 

  • Buchanan, J. (2005). Reflections after three decades. In E.P. Stringham (Ed.) Anarchy, state and public choice (pp. 191–193). Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bush, W. (1972). Individual welfare in anarchy. In G. Tullock (Ed.), Explorations in the theory of anarchy (pp. 5–18). Blacksburg: Center for Study of Public Choice.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bush, W., & Mayer, L. (1974). Some implications of anarchy for the distribution of property. Journal of Economic Theory, 8, 401–412.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Caplan, B., & Stringham, E. P. (2003). Networks, law, and the paradox of cooperation. Review of Austrian Economics, 16, 309–326.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Caplan, B., & Stringham, E. P. (2008). Privatizing the adjudication of disputes. Theoretical Inquiries in Law, 9(2), 503–528.

    Google Scholar 

  • Carter, J., & Anderton, C. (2001). An experimental test of a predator-prey model of appropriation. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 45, 83–97.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Clay, K. (1997). Trade without law: Private-order institutions in Mexican California. Journal of Law, Economics, & Organization, 13(1), 202231.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cowen, T. (1992). Law as a public good: The economics of anarchy. Economics and Philosophy, 8(2), 249–267.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cowen, T. (1994). Rejoinder to David Friedman on the economics of anarchy. Economics and Philosophy, 10(2), 329–332.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cowen, T., & Sutter, D. (2005). Conflict, cooperation and competition in anarchy. Review of Austrian Economics, 18(1), 109–115.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Coyne, C. (2005). Social interaction without the state. In E. P. Stringham (Ed.), Anarchy, state and public choice (pp. 49–59). Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Coyne, C. (2006). Reconstructing weak and failed states: Foreign intervention and the nirvana fallacy. Foreign Policy Analysis, 2, 343–361.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Coyne, C. (2008). After war: The political economy of exporting democracy. Palo Alto: Stanford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Coyne, C., & Leeson, P. (2005). Who’s to protect cyberspace. Journal of Law, Economics & Policy, 1(2), 473–496.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dixit, A. K. (2004). Lawlessness and economics: Alternative modes of governance. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dowd, K. (1997). Anarchy, warfare, and social order: Comment on Hirshleifer. Journal of Political Economy, 105(3), 648–651.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Duffy, J., & Kim, M. (2005). Anarchy in the laboratory (and the role of the state). Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 56(3), 297–329.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Eggertsson, T. (1990). Economic behavior and institutions. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ekelund, R., & Dorton, C. (2003). Criminal justice institutions as a common pool: The 19th century analysis of Edwin Chadwick. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 50, 271–294.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ellickson, R. C. (1989). A hypothesis of wealth-maximizing norms: Evidence from the whaling industry. Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization, 5, 83–97.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ellickson, R. C. (1991). Order without law: How neighbors settle disputes. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Frey, B. S. (2001). A utopia? Government without territorial monopoly. Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics, 157, 162–175.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Friedman, D. (1973/1989). The machinery of freedom, guide to radical capitalism (2nd ed.). La Salle: Open Court.

    Google Scholar 

  • Friedman, D. (1976). Review of Further explorations in the theory of anarchy edited by Gordon Tullock. Public Choice, 16(1), 101–104.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Friedman, D. (1979). Private creation and enforcement of law: A historical case. Journal of Legal Studies, 8, 399–415.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Friedman, D. (1994). Law as a private good: A response to Tyler Cowen on the economics of anarchy. Economics and Philosophy, 10(2), 319–327.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Friedman, D. (2005). From Imperial China to cyberspace: Contracting without the state. Journal of Law, Economics & Policy, 1(2), 349–370.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fuller, L. (1964). The morality of law. New Haven: Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Greif, A. (1989). Reputation and coalitions in medieval trade: Evidence on the Maghribi traders. Journal of Economic History, 49, 857–882.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Greif, A. (1993). Contract enforceability and economic institutions in early trade: The Maghribi traders’ coalition. American Economic Review, 83, 525–548.

    Google Scholar 

  • Greif, A. (2005). Institutions and the path to the modern economy: Lessons from medieval trade. In C. Menard & M. Shirley (Eds.), Handbook of new institutional economics (pp. 727–786). Dordrecht: Springer.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Grossman, H. (2002). ‘Make us a king’: Anarchy, predation, and the state. European Journal of Political Economy, 18(1), 31–46.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grossman, H., Kim, M., & Mendoza, J. (2001). Decisiveness and the viability of anarchy. Available at SSRN: http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=261697.

  • Gunning, J. P. (1972). Towards a theory of the evolution of government. In G. Tullock (Ed.), Explorations in the theory of anarchy (pp. 19–26). Blacksburg: Center for Study of Public Choice.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hampton, J. (1986). Hobbes and the social contract tradition. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hausken, K. (2006). The stability of anarchy and breakdown of production. Defense and Peace Economics, 17(6), 589–603.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hirshleifer, J. (1995). Anarchy and its breakdown. Journal of Political Economy, 103(1), 26–52.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hirshleifer, J. (2001). The dark side of the force: Economic foundations of conflict theory. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hogarty, T. (1972). Cases in anarchy. In G. Tullock (Ed.), Explorations in the theory of anarchy (pp. 51–64). Blacksburg: Center for Study of Public Choice.

    Google Scholar 

  • Holcombe, R. (2004). Government: Unnecessary but inevitable. Independent Review, 8(3), 325–42.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hoppe, H. H. (Ed.). (2003). The myth of national defense: Essays on the theory and history of security production. Auburn: Mises.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hummel, J. R. (2001). The will to be free: The role of ideology in national defense. Independent Review, 5(4), 523–537.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hummel, J. R. (2005). Tullock on anarchy. In E. Stringham (Ed.), Anarchy, state and public choice (pp. 200–205). Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • de Jasay, A. (1985/1998). The state. Indianapolis: Liberty Fund.

    Google Scholar 

  • de Jasay, A. (1990). Social contract, free ride: A study of the public goods problem. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • de Jasay, A. (1997). Against politics: On government, anarchy, and order. New York: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • de Jasay, A. (2008). On the monopoly of rule enforcement. Journal of Private Enterprise, 23(2), 135–148.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kavka, G. (1986). Hobbesian moral and political theory. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kimbrough, E., Smith, V., & Wilson, B. (2008). An experimental inquiry into the origin of property rights. Working paper, George Mason University. http://gunston.gmu.edu/bwilson3/papers/OriginofPropertyRights.pdf.

  • Kurrild-Klitgaard, P. (2002). Opting-out: The constitutional economics of exit. American Journal of Economics and Sociology, 61(1), 123–158.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kurrild-Klitgaard, P., & Svendsen, G. T. (2003). Rational bandits: Plunder, public goods, and the Vikings. Public Choice, 117(3–4), 255–272.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Landa, J. (1981). A theory of ethnically homogenous middleman group: An institutional alternative to contract law. Journal of Legal Studies, 10, 349–362.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Landa, J. (1994). Trust, ethnicity, and identity. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Leeson, P. T. (2005). Do contracts require formal enforcement? In E. P. Stringham (Ed.), Anarchy, state and public choice (pp. 67–76). Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Leeson, P. T. (2006). Cooperation and conflict: Evidence on self-enforcing arrangements and heterogeneous groups. American Journal of Economics and Sociology, 65(4), 891–907.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Leeson, P. T. (2007a). Anarchy, monopoly, and predation. Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics, 163(3), 467–482.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Leeson, P. T. (2007b). An-arrgh-chy: The law and economics of pirate organization. Journal of Political Economy, 115(6), 1049–1094.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Leeson, P. T. (2007c). Better off stateless: Somalia before and after government collapse. Journal of Comparative Economics, 35(4), 689–710.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Leeson, P. T. (2007d). Efficient anarchy. Public Choice, 130(1–2), 41–53.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Leeson, P. T. (2007e). Review of Edward P. Stringham, ed., Anarchy and the law. Public Choice, 133, 253–256.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Leeson, P. T. (2007f). Trading with bandits. Journal of Law and Economics, 50(2), 303–321.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Leeson, P. T. (2008a). How important is state enforcement for trade? American Law and Economics Review, 10(1), 61–89.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Leeson, P. T. (2008b). Social distance and self-enforcing exchange. Journal of Legal Studies, 37(1), 161–188.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Leeson, P. T. (2008c, forthcoming). The laws of lawlessness. Journal of Legal Studies.

  • Leeson, P. T., & Stringham, E. P. (2005). Is government inevitable? Comment on Holcombe’s analysis. Independent Review, 9(4), 543–549.

    Google Scholar 

  • Long, R., & Machan, T. R. (Eds.). (2008). Anarchism/Minarchism: Is a government part of a free country. Burlington: Ashgate.

    Google Scholar 

  • Liggio, L. (1999). The medieval law merchant: Economic growth challenged by the public choice state. Journal des Économistes et des Études Humaines, 9(1), 63.

    Google Scholar 

  • McCabe, K. A., Rassenti, S. J., & Smith, V. L. (1996). Game theory and reciprocity in some extensive form experimental games. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences of the United States of America, 93(23), 13421–13428.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McGuire, M., & Olson, M. (1996). The economics of autocracy and majority rule: The invisible hand and the use of force. Journal of Economic Literature, 34(1), 72–96.

    Google Scholar 

  • Milgrom, P., Doglass, N., & Weingast, B. (1990). The role of institutions in the revival of trade: The law merchant, private judges, and the champagne fairs. Economics & Politics, 2(19), 1–23.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Morris, A. P. (1998). Miners, vigilantes and cattlemen: Overcoming free rider problems in the private provision of law. Land and Water Law Review, 33, 581–696.

    Google Scholar 

  • Morriss, A., & Korosec, J. (2005). Private dispute resolution in the card context: Structure, reputation, and incentives. Journal of Law, Economics & Policy, 1(2), 473–496.

    Google Scholar 

  • Moselle, B., & Polak, B. (2001). A model of a predatory state. Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization, 17(1), 1–33.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Moss, L. S. (1974). Private property anarchism: An American variant. In G. Tullock (Ed.), Further explorations in the theory of anarchy (pp. 1–31). Blacksburg: Center for Study of Public Choice.

    Google Scholar 

  • Moss, L. S. (1980). Optimal jurisdictions and the economic theory of the state: Or, anarchy and one-world government are only corner solutions. Public Choice, 35(1), 17–26.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mueller, D. C. (1988). Anarchy, the market, and the state. Southern Economic Journal, 54(4), 821–830.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nozick, R. (1974). Anarchy, state and utopia. New York: Basic Books.

    Google Scholar 

  • Okuguchi, K. (1976). Natural equilibrium in the Bush-Mayer model of anarchy: A dynamic analysis. Public Choice, 26, 129–134.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Olson, M. (2000). Power and prosperity. New York: Basic Books.

    Google Scholar 

  • Osborne, J. (2005). Jungle or just bush? Anarchy and the evolution of cooperation. In E. P. Stringham (Ed.), Anarchy, state and public choice (pp. 10–23). Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ostrom, E. (1990). Governing the commons: The evolution of institutions for collective action. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Peden, J. R. (1977). Property rights in Celtic Irish law. Journal of Libertarian Studies, 1, 81–95.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pingry, D. (1974). Anarchy, externalities, and the environment. In G. Tullock (Ed.), Further explorations in the theory of anarchy (pp. 59–64). Blacksburg: Center for Study of Public Choice.

    Google Scholar 

  • Powell, B. (2005a). Is cybersecurity a public good? Evidence from the financial services industry. Journal of Law, Economics & Policy, 1(2), 497–510.

    Google Scholar 

  • Powell, B. (2005b). Public choice and Leviathan. In E. P. Stringham (Ed.), Anarchy, state and public choice (pp. 88–97). Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Powell, B. (Ed.). (2008). Making poor nations rich: Entrepreneurship and the process of economic development. Palo Alto: Stanford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Powell, B., & Coyne, C. (2003). Do pessimistic assumptions justify government? Journal of Libertarian Studies, 18, 17–37.

    Google Scholar 

  • Powell, B., Ford, R., & Nowrasteh, A. (2008). Somalia after state collapse: Chaos or improvement. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 67.

  • Powell, B., & Wilson, B. (2008). An experimental investigation of Hobbesian jungles. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 66(3–4), 669–686.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rajan, R. (2004). Assume anarchy? Why an orthodox economic model may not be the best guide for policy. Finance and Development, 41(3), 56–57.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rothbard, M. (1970). Power and market: Government and the economy. Menlo Park: Institute for Humane Studies.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rothbard, M. (1973/1996). For a new liberty: Libertarian manifesto. San Francisco: Fox and Wilkes.

    Google Scholar 

  • Samuels, W. (1974). Anarchism and the theory of power. In G. Tullock (Ed.), Further explorations in the theory of anarchy (pp. 33–57). Blacksburg: Center for Study of Public Choice.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schofield, N. (1985). Anarchy, altruism, and cooperation. Social Choice and Welfare, 2(3), 207–219.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Skoble, A. J. (2008). Deleting the state: An argument about government. Chicago: Open Court.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sobel, R. S., & Osoba, B. J. (forthcoming). Youth gangs as pseudo governments: Implications for violent crime. Southern Economic Journal.

  • Solvason, B., & Runolfsson, T. (1992). Ordered anarchy: Evolution of the decentralized legal order in the Icelandic commonwealth. Icelandic Economic Papers, 17.

  • Smith, A. (1766/1982). Lectures on jurisprudence. Indianapolis: Liberty Classics.

    Google Scholar 

  • De Soto, H. (1989). The other path: The invisible revolution in the Third World. London: I.B. Tauris.

    Google Scholar 

  • De Soto, H. (2000). The mystery of capital: Why capitalism triumphs in the West and fails everywhere else. London: Bantam.

    Google Scholar 

  • Smith, V. L. (1996). The two faces of Adam Smith. Southern Economic Journal, 65(1), 2–19.

    Google Scholar 

  • Storr, V. (2005). Defining anarchy as rock ‘n’ roll: Rethinking Hogarty’s three cases. In E. P. Stringham (Ed.), Anarchy, state and public choice (pp. 113–122). Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stringham, E. P. (2002). The emergence of the London stock exchange as a self-policing club. Journal of Private Enterprise, 17(2), 1–19.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stringham, E. P. (2003). The extralegal development of securities trading in seventeenth century Amsterdam. Quarterly Review of Economics and Finance, 43, 321–344.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stringham, E. P. (Ed.). (2005a). Anarchy, state, and public choice. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stringham, E. P. (2005b). The capability of government in providing protection against online fraud: Are classical liberals guilty of the nirvana fallacy? Journal of Law, Economics & Policy, 1(2), 371–392.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stringham, E. P. (2005c). When States Fail: Causes and Consequences edited by Robert I. Rotberg. Quarterly Journal of Austrian Economics, 8(3), 97–99.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stringham, E. P. (2006). Overlapping jurisdictions, proprietary communities, and competition in the realm of law. Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics, 162, 516–534.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stringham, E. P. (Ed.). (2007). Anarchy and the law. Somerset: Transaction Publishers.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sutter, D. (1995). Asymmetric power relations and cooperation in anarchy. Southern Economic Journal, 61, 602–613.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sutter, D. (2008). Review of Edward P. Stringham, ed., Anarchy, state and public choice. Public Choice, 134, 491–493.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Taylor, M. (1976). Anarchy and cooperation. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Taylor, M. (1987). The possibility of cooperation. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Telser, L. G. (1980). A theory of self-enforcing agreements. Journal of Business, 53, 27–44.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tullock, G. (1971). Public decisions as public goods. Journal of Political Economy, 79, 913–918.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tullock, G. (Ed.). (1972). Explorations in the theory of anarchy. Blacksburg: Center for Study of Public Choice.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tullock, G. (Ed.). (1974a). Further explorations in the theory of anarchy. Blacksburg: University Publications.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tullock, G. (1974b). The social dilemma: The economics of war and revolution. Blacksburg: University Publications.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tullock, G. (1985). Adam Smith and the prisoners’ dilemma. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 100(Suppl.), 1073–1081.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tullock, G. (1999). Non-prisoner’s dilemma. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 39, 455–458.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tullock, G. (2005). Anarchy. In E. P. Stringham (Ed.), Anarchy, state and public choice (pp. 194–199). Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Vanderschraaf, P. (2006). War or peace? A dynamical analysis of anarchy. Economics and Philosophy, 22(2), 243–279.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Warneryd, K. (1993). Anarchy, uncertainty, and the emergence of property rights. Economics and Politics, 5(1), 1–14.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Witt, U. (1992). The emergence of a protective agency and the constitutional dilemma. Constitutional Political Economy, 3(2), 255–266.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zywicki, T. (2003). The rise and fall of efficiency in the common law: A supply-side analysis. Northwestern University Law Review, 97(4), 1551–1634.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Edward P. Stringham.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Powell, B., Stringham, E.P. Public choice and the economic analysis of anarchy: a survey. Public Choice 140, 503–538 (2009). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-009-9407-1

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-009-9407-1

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation