Skip to main content
Log in

Behavioral models of managerial decision-making

  • Published:
Marketing Letters Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper reviews the literature that applies behavioral economic models to managerial decisions. It organizes the literature into research that focuses on alternative utility functions and research that focuses on non-equilibrium models. Generally, behavioral models have seen less application to manager decisions than to consumer decisions and therefore there are many opportunities to develop new theoretical models, new laboratory experiments, and new field applications. The application of these models to field data is particularly underdeveloped.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

References

  • Aguirregabiria, V., & Magesan, A. (2011). Identification and estimation of dynamic games when players’ beliefs are not in equilibrium. Working paper, University of Toronto.

  • Akerlof, G. A., & Kranton, R. E. (2000). Economics and identity. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 115(3), 715–753.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Akerlof, G. A., & Kranton, R. E. (2005). Identity and the economics of organizations. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 19(1), 9–32.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Amaldoss, W., & Jain, S. (2005a). Conspicuous consumption and sophisticated thinking. Management Science, 51(10), 1449–1466.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Amaldoss, W., & Jain, S. (2005b). Pricing of conspicuous goods: a competitive analysis of social effects. Journal of Marketing Research, 42, 30–42.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Amaldoss, W., & Jain, S. (2008). Trading up: a strategic analysis of reference group effects. Marketing Science, 27(5), 932–942.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Amaldoss, W., & Jain, S. (2010). Reference groups and product line decisions: an experimental investigation of limited editions and product proliferation. Management Science, 56(4), 621–644.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Anderson, E., & Simester, D. (2004). Long-run effects of promotion depth on new versus established customers: three field studies. Marketing Science, 23(1), 4–20.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Anderson, E., & Simester, D. (2008). Does demand fall when customers perceive that prices are unfair? The case of premium pricing for large sizes. Marketing Science, 27(3), 492–500.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Anderson, E., & Simester, D. (2010). Price stickiness and customer antagonism. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 125(2), 729–765.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baker, M., Ruback, R., & Wurgler, J. (2007). Behavioral corporate finance: a survey. In E. Eckbo (Ed.), Handbook in corporate finance: empirical corporate finance (pp. 145–188). North Holland: Elsevier. ch. 4.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Bertrand, M., & Schoar, A. (2003). Managing with style: the effect of managers on firm policies. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 118, 1169–1208.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bloom, N., & Van Reenen, J. (2007). Measuring and explaining management practices across firms and countries. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 122(4), 1351–1408.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brown, A. L., Camerer, C. F., & Lovallo, D. (2012). To review or not to review? Limited strategic thinking at the movie box office. American Economic Journal: Microeconomics, 4(2), 1–26.

    Google Scholar 

  • Brown, A. L., Camerer, C. F., & Lovallo, D. (forthcoming). Estimating structural models of limited strategic thinking in the field: the case of missing movie critic reviews. Management Science.

  • Camerer, C. F. (2003). Behavioral game theory: experiments in strategic interaction. Princeton University Press, NJ.

  • Camerer, C., & Ho, T.-H. (1999). Experience-weighted attraction learning in normal form games. Econometrica, 67, 837–874.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Camerer, C., & Lovallo, D. (1999). Overconfidence and excess entry: an experimental approach. American Economic Review, 89(1), 306–318.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Camerer, C., & Malmendier, U. (2007). Behavioral economics and its applications, in behavioral economics of organizations. Princeton University Press.

  • Camerer, C. F., Ho, T.-H., & Chong, J.-K. (2004). A cognitive hierarchy model of games. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 119(3), 861–898.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Che, H., Sudhir, K., & Seetharaman, P. B. (2007). Bounded rationality in pricing under state-dependent demand: do firms look ahead? How far ahead? Journal of Marketing Research, 44(3), 434–449.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chen, R., & Chen, Y. (2011). The potential of social identity for equilibrium selection. American Economic Review, 101, 2562–2589.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chen, Y., & Cui, T. H. (2010). The benefit of uniform price for branded variants. Working Paper.

  • Chen, Y., & Li, S. (2009). Group identity and social preferences. American Economic Review, 99(1), 431–457.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Conlin, M., O’Donoghue, T., & Vogelsang, T. (2007). Projection bias in catalog orders. American Economic Review, 97(4), 1217–1249.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cooper, A. C., Woo, C. A., & Dunkelberg, W. (1988). Entrepreneurs perceived chances for success. Journal of Business Venturing, 3, 97–108.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cui, T. H., Mallucci, P. (2010). Quantal response equilibrium in a fair channel—an experimental investigation. Working Paper.

  • Cui, T. H., Raju, J. S., & Zhang, Z. J. (2007). Fairness and channel coordination. Management Science, 53(8), 1303–1314.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cui, T. H., Raju, J. S., Shi, M. (2010). S-shaped incentive schemes and pay caps. Working Paper.

  • DellaVigna, S. (2009). Psychology and economics: evidence from the field. Journal of Economic Literature, 47, 315–372.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • DellaVigna, S., & Malmendier, U. (2006). Paying not to go to the gym. American Economic Review, 96(3), 694–719.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • DeLong, J. B. A., Shleifer, L. H. Summers, & Waldmann, R. J. (1990). Noise trader risk in financial markets. Journal of Political Economy, 98(4), 703–738.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Demirag, O. C., Chen, Y. F., & Li, J. (2010). Channel coordination under fairness concerns and nonlinear demand. European Journal of Operational Research, 207, 1321–1326.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ellison, G., & Fudenberg, D. (2003). Knife-edge or plateau: when do market models tip? Quarterly Journal of Economics, 118(4), 1249–1278.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Farber, H. S. (2008). Reference-dependent preferences and labor supply: the case of New York City taxi drivers. American Economic Review, 98(3), 1069–1082.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fehr, E., & Schmidt, K. M. (1999). A theory of fairness, competition and co-operation. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 114(3), 817–868.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fehr, E., Alexander, K., & Schmidt, K. M. (2007). Fairness and contract design. Econometrica, 75(1), 121–154.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fiorillo, C., Tober, P., & Schultz, W. (2003). Discrete coding of reward probability and uncertainty by dopamine neurons. Science, 299, 1898–1902.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Galasso, A. (2011). Broad cross-license negotiations. Working paper, University of Toronto.

  • Galasso, A., & Simcoe, T. (2011). CEO overconfidence and innovation. Management Science, 57, 1469–1484.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Genesove, D., & Mayer, C. (2001). Loss aversion and seller behavior: evidence from the housing market. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 116(4), 1233–1260.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Goeree, J. K., & Holt, C. A. (2005). An experimental study of costly coordination. Games and Economic Behavior, 51(2), 349–364.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Goldfarb, A., & Xiao, M. (2011). Who thinks about the competition? Managerial ability and strategic entry in US local telephone markets. American Economic Review, 101, 3130–3161.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Goldfarb, A., & Yang, B. (2009). Are all managers created equal? Journal of Marketing Research, 46(5), 612–622.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grossman, S. J. (1981). The informational role of warranties and private disclosure about product quality. Journal of Law and Economics, 24, 461–483.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grubb, M. (2009). Selling to overconfident consumers. American Economic Review, 99(5), 1770–1807.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Güth, W., Schmittberger, R., & Schwarze, B. (1982). An experimental analysis of ultimatum bargaining. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 3(4), 367–388.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Haltiwanger, J., & Waldman, M. (1985). Rational expectations and the limits to rationality: an analysis of heterogeneity. American Economic Review, 75(3), 326–340.

    Google Scholar 

  • Heidhues, P., & Koszegi, B. (2008). Competition and price variation when consumers are loss averse. American Economic Review, 98, 1245–1268.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ho, T.-H., & Su, X. (2009). Peer-induced fairness in games. American Economic Review, 99(5), 2022–2049.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ho, T.-H., & Zhang, J.-J. (2008). Designing price contracts for boundedly rational customers: does the framing of the fixed fee matter? Management Science, 54(4), 686–700.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ho, T.-H., Camerer, C., & Weigelt, K. (1998). Iterated dominance and iterated best response in experimental P-beauty contests. American Economic Review, 88, 947–969.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ho, T.-H., Lim, N., & Camerer, C. (2006). Modeling the psychology of consumer and firm behavior with behavioral economics. Journal of Marketing Research, 43(3), 307–331.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ho, T.-H., Camerer, C., & Chong, J.-K. (2007). Self-tuning experience-weighted attraction learning in games. Journal of Economic Theory, 133(1), 177–198.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hortacsu, A., & Puller, S. (2008). Understanding strategic models of bidding in deregulated electricity markets: a case study of ERCOT. The RAND Journal of Economics, 39, 86–114.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hossain, T., & Morgan, J. (2006). …Plus shipping and handling: revenue (non)-equivalence in field experiments on eBay. Advances in Economic Analysis & Policy, 6(2).

  • Hossain, T., & Morgan, J. (2011). When do markets tip? A cognitive hierarchy approach. Working Paper, University of Toronto.

  • Hossain, T., Minor, D., & Morgan, J. (2011). Competing matchmakers: an experimental analysis. Management Science, 57, 1913–1925.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hsu, M., Mathewson, K., & Zhu, L. (2010). Neural computations underlying strategic learning, Manuscript. Berkeley: University of California.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kahneman, D., Knetsch, J. L., & Thaler, R. (1986). Fairness as a constraint on profit seeking: entitlements in the market. American Economic Review, 76(4), 728–741.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kaplan, S. N., Klebanov, M., & Sorenson, M. (2008) Which CEO characteristics and abilities matter? NBER working paper #14195.

  • Katok, E., & Pavlov, V. (2009). Fairness and coordination failures in supply chain contracts. Working Paper.

  • Lim, N. (2010). Social loss aversion and optimal contest design. Journal of Marketing Research, 47, 777–787.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lim, N., & Ho, T.-H. (2007). Designing price contracts for boundedly rational customers: does the number of blocks matter? Marketing Science, 26(3), 312–326.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lim, N., Chen, H., & Ahearne, M. (2010). Do group incentives work? Evidence from the field and lab. Marketing Department Working Paper, University of Wisconsin-Madison.

  • Loewenstein, G., & Prelec, D. (1992). Anomalies in intertemporal choice: evidence and an interpretation. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 107, 573–598.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Loewenstein, G. E., Thompson, L., & Bazerman, M. H. (1989). Social utility and decision making in interpersonal contexts. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 57(3), 426–441.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Malmendier, U., & Tate, G. (2005). CEO overconfidence and corporate investment. Journal of Finance, 60(6), 2661–2700.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Malmendier, U., & Tate, G. (2008). Who makes acquisitions? CEO overconfidence and the market’s reaction. Journal of Financial Economics, 89(1), 20–43.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Milgrom, P. R. (1981). Good news and bad news: representation theorems and applications. Bell Journal of Economics, 12(2), 380–391.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Monderer, D., & Shapley, L. S. (1996). Potential games. Games and Economic Behavior, 14, 124–143.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Moore, D. A., & Cain, D. M. (2007). Overconfidence and underconfidence: when and why people underestimate (and overestimate) the competition. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes, 103, 197–213.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nagel, R. (1995). Unravelling in guessing games: an experimental study. American Economic Review, 85(5), 1313–1326.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nyarko, Y., & Schotter, A. (2002). An experimental study of belief learning using elicited beliefs. Econometrica, 70(3), 971–1005.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Orhun, A. Y. (2009). Optimal product line design when consumers exhibit choice set-dependent preferences. Marketing Science, 28(5), 868–886.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Oster, S., & Scott Morton, F. (2005). Behavioral biases meet the market: the case of magazine subscription prices. Advances in Economic Analysis and Policy, 5(1), 1.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rabin, M. (1993). Incorporating fairness into game theory and economics. American Economic Review, 83(5), 1281–1302.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rapoport, A., & Amaldoss, W. (2000). Mixed strategies and iterative elimination of strongly dominated strategies: an experimental investigation of states of knowledge. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 42, 483–521.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Roth, A., & Erev, I. (1995). Learning in extensive-form games: experimental data and simple dynamic models in the intermediate term. Games and Economic Behavior, 8(1), 164–212.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rutstrom, E., & Wilcox, N. (2009). Stated beliefs versus empirical beliefs: a methodological inquiry and experimental test. Games and Economic Behavior, 67, 616–632.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Scheer, L. K., Kumar, N., & Steenkamp, J. B. E. M. (2003). Reactions to perceived inequity in U.S. and Dutch interorganizational relationships. Academy of Management Journal, 46(3), 303–316.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Simonsohn, U. (2010a). eBay’s crowded evenings: competition neglect in market entry decisions. Management Science, 56(7), 1060–1073.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Simonsohn, U. (2010b). Weather to go to college. The Economic Journal, 120(543), 270–280.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Simonsohn, U., & Ariely, D. (2008). When rational sellers face non-rational consumers: evidence from herding on eBay. Management Science, 54(9), 1624–1637.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Simonson, I., & Tversky, A. (1993). Context-dependent preferences. Management Science, 39(10), 1179–1189.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Soman, D., Ainslie, G., Frederick, S., Li, X., Lynch, J., Moreau, P., et al. (2005). The psychology of intertemporal choice. Marketing Letters, 16(3), 347–360.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stahl, D. O. (1993). Evolution of Smartn Players. Games and Economic Behavior, 5, 604–617.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stahl, D. O., & Wilson, P. (1995). On players’ models of other players: theory and experimental evidence. Games and Economic Behavior, 10(1), 213–254.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sutton, R. S., & Barto, A. G. (1981). Toward a modern theory of adaptive networks: expectation and prediction. Psychological Review, 88(2), 135–170.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Svenson, O. (1981). Are we all less risky and more skilful than our fellow drivers? Acta Psychologica, 47(2), 143–148.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Thaler, R. (1981). Some empirical evidence on dynamic inconsistency. Economics Letters, 8(3), 201–207.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Van Huyck, J. B., Battalio, R. C., & Beil, R. O. (1990). Tacit coordination games, strategic uncertainty, and coordination failure. American Economic Review, 80, 234–248.

    Google Scholar 

  • Watanabe, Y. (2010). Learning and bargaining in dispute resolution: theory and evidence from medical malpractice litigation. Working paper.

  • Wilcox, N. (2006). Theories of learning in games and heterogeneity bias. Econometrica, 74(5), 1271–1292.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zhang, X., & Zhu, F. (2011). Group size and incentives to contribute: a natural experiment at Chinese Wikipedia. American Economic Review, 101, 1601–1615.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Avi Goldfarb.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Goldfarb, A., Ho, TH., Amaldoss, W. et al. Behavioral models of managerial decision-making. Mark Lett 23, 405–421 (2012). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11002-012-9183-4

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11002-012-9183-4

Keywords

Navigation