Skip to main content
Log in

The Effect of IP Protection on Radical and Incremental Innovation

  • Published:
Journal of the Knowledge Economy Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper examines the effects of risk in shaping and developing innovations at the country level by introducing the idea that strong patent protection can lead innovators to rest on their laurels. Specifically, in the context of a simple static framework, the model shows that there is a negative relationship between the ability of the economy to innovate and how strong patent protection should be.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. As Soskice [30] notes, the most important elements of this framework are, the corporate governance system, the financial system, the industrial relations/worker training system, the education system, the organization of employer associations and the relations among firms.

  2. Patent breath in this model is best captured by the number of patent claims allowed by the PTO, as well as the courts’ attitude towards infringement.

  3. This assumption accords with the evidence offered by Panagopoulos [25].

  4. US law has an experimentation exemption. However, here, the winning innovation leads directly to a final product. Therefore, any re-innovation will translate itself in a commercial product and this is prohibited.

  5. For a discussion on the uncertainty surrounding innovation see Rosenberg [28].

  6. An example of an innovation, which in its development involved fundamental research, is the invention of the transistor by Bell Laboratories in 1947. The aim of this research was to create a better electron emitting diode, one that was superior to the traditional ‘bulbs’ that were in use at the time. From its start, Bell Laboratories had two choices. To either continue working on the traditional diode and try to improve it, or, alternatively, try and concentrate on an entirely new line of physics, namely solid-state physics. Solid-state physics had only been introduced in the graduate curriculum of the top US universities in the mid 1930s and at the time there was little understanding (and a lot of uncertainty) involved around its potential. Therefore, solid-state physics was a research path that could have provided a dead end result. Successful, as it turned out to be, it led to applications that where beyond the imagination of the creators of the transistor, since the transistor was, at the time, perceived as an innovation with limited potential. In fact, Bell was initially hesitant on applying for a patent.

    However, in addition to the work that Bell carried out on solid-state physics applications, a great deal of the research that led to the invention of the transistor was supplemented by the use of well-understood technologies. For example, in order to put theory into use Bell had to work on well-known metallurgy technologies, which were needed in order to create the silicon sandwich material in which the transistor is bonded into. In fact, many of the subsequent improvements on the transistor, even to this day, have been based on improving this sandwich so that it allows less current to pass through, while permitting finer and more even transistors to be manufactured.

  7. This formulation treats (1 − s i )γ and s i v i as perfect substitutes. In reality, (1 − s i )γ is the expected part of an innovation and s i v i is the unexpected part. Considering this, since i has the choice to employ (or not) in its research some a priori unexpected research path, it is irrational for i to contact its research mainly using s i v i ; as s i v i can attain negative values and i may end up with an innovation which is less than expected.

  8. Hence, Eq. 1 must be re-expressed as, \( {A_j} = A_j^{\prime } + \max \left\{ {0,\Delta {A_j},\lambda \Delta {A_i}} \right\} \)

  9. Which is broadly comprised by three independent and different national systems, the French, the German and the UK one.

  10. In the US, the firm in cooperation with universities is central to research, while in European NSIs the state has a larger role to play

  11. See Harris and Vickers [13], as well as Dasgupta and Stiglitz [5].

  12. For a review of tournament models see Reinganum [27].

  13. In proving the above point, I have assumed that there is no cost in choosing s. Since there is no cost, it does not matter how far apart the firms are positioned, because (as long as μ j  > γ to any increase in A j firm i will always respond with an increase in S i . Panagopoulos [26], working in a similar framework, relaxes these restrictions and shows that there exists a Nash equilibrium where both firms choose to increase their s only if they are positioned very close to each other; if they are positioned far apart they will abstain from increasing s.

References

  1. Aghion P, Howitt P (1992) A model of growth through creative destruction. Econometrica 60:323–351

    Article  Google Scholar 

  2. Beath J, Katsoulakos Y, Ulph D (1989) Strategic R&D policy. Econ J 99(395):74–83

    Article  Google Scholar 

  3. Braithwaite J, Drahos P (2000) Global business regulation. Cambridge University Press

  4. Chang H (1995) Patent scope, antitrust policy and cumulative innovation. Rand J Econ 26:34–57

    Article  Google Scholar 

  5. Dasgupta P, Stiglitz J (1980) Entry, innovation, exit: towards a dynamic theory of oligopolistic industrial structure. Eur Econ Rev 15:139–158

    Google Scholar 

  6. Denicolò V (1996) Patent races and optimal patent breadth and length. J Ind Econ 44(3):249–265

    Article  Google Scholar 

  7. Denicolò V (2000) Two stage patent races and patent policy. Rand J Econ 31:488–501

    Article  Google Scholar 

  8. Gallini N (1992) Patent length and breadth with costly imitation. Rand J Econ 44:52–63

    Article  Google Scholar 

  9. Gallini N (2002) The economics of patents: lessons from recent us patent reform. J Econ Perspect 16(2):131–154, Spring

    Article  Google Scholar 

  10. Gilbert R, Shapiro C (1990) Optimal patent length and breadth. Rand J Econ 21(1):106–112

    Article  Google Scholar 

  11. Goyer M (2001) Corporate governance and the innovation system in France 1985–2000. Ind Innov 8(2):135–158

    Google Scholar 

  12. Green J, Scotchmer S (1995) On the diffusion of profit in sequential innovation. Rand J Econ 26:20–33

    Article  Google Scholar 

  13. Harris C, Vickers J (1987) Racing with uncertainty. Rev Econ Stud 54:1–21

    Article  Google Scholar 

  14. Henderson R, Orsenigo L, Pisano G (1999) The pharmaceutical industry and the revolution in molecular biology. In: Mowery D, Nelson R (eds) Sources of industrial leadership: studies of seven industries. Oxford University Press, New York

    Google Scholar 

  15. Horowitz A, Lai E (1996) Patent length and the rate of innovation. Int Econ Rev. Nov. pp 785–801

  16. Jones C (2001). Was the industrial revolution inevitable? Economic growth over the very long run. Adv Macroeconomics. 2001, 1(2), Article 1

  17. Klemperer P (1990) How broad should the scope of patent protection be? Rand J Econ 21(1):113–130

    Article  Google Scholar 

  18. Lerner J (2004) 150 years of patent protection. Am Econ Rev Pap Proc 92:221–225

    Google Scholar 

  19. Matutes C, Regibeau P, Rockett K (1996) Optimal patent protection and the diffusion of innovation. Rand J Econ 27:60–83

    Article  Google Scholar 

  20. Mowery D, Rosenberg N (1998) Path of innovation: Technology change in 20th century America. Cambridge University Press

  21. Nelson R (1992) National innovation systems: a retrospective on a study? Ind Corp Change 1(2):347–374

    Article  Google Scholar 

  22. Nordhaus W (1969) Invention growth and welfare: a theoretical treatment of technological change. MIT Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  23. O’Donaghue T, Scotchmer S, Thisse J (1998) Patent breadth, patent length and the pace of technological progress. J Econ Manage Strategy 7:1–32

    Article  Google Scholar 

  24. Pakes A, Schankerman M (1979) The rate of obsolescence of knowledge, research gestation lags, and the private rate of return to research resources. NBER Working Paper, No. 0346

  25. Panagopoulos A (2004a) The role of sequential innovations and R&D workers in limiting scale effects. J Interdiscip Econ No. 6

  26. Panagopoulos A (2004b) ‘When does patent protection stimulate innovation?’. Working Paper, University of Bristol

  27. Reinganum J (1989) The timing of innovation: research development and diffusion. In: Schmalensee R, Willig R (eds) Handbook of industrial organization, vol. 1. North-Holland, New York

    Google Scholar 

  28. Rosenberg N (1996) In: Landau R, Wright G (eds) Uncertainty and technological change. The Mosaic of economic growth? Stanford University Press, Stanford, pp 334–356

    Google Scholar 

  29. Scotchmer S (1991) Standing on the shoulders of giants: cumulative research and the patent law. J Econ Perspec, Symposium on Intellectual Property Law

  30. Soskice D (1999) Divergent production regimes: coordinated and uncoordinated market economies in the 1980’s and 1990’s. In: Kitschelt H et al (eds) Continuity and change in contemporary capitalism. Cambridge University Press, New York, pp 101–134

    Google Scholar 

  31. Thorton R, Thompson P (2000) Learning from experience and learning from others an exploration of learning and spillovers in wartime shipbuilding. Working Paper, University of Houston

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Andreas Panagopoulos.

Appendix

Appendix

The winner will maximize its profits π i subject to x. This maximization problem has the following FOC,

$$ x = {\left( {\frac{{{a^2}{A_i}}}{\kappa }} \right)^{{\frac{1}{{1 - a}}}}} $$
(5)

Since the firm must choose its s at the beginning of the patent race, before its innovation is materialized, firms solve the following problem, maximizing expected profits times the expected probability of winning the patent race, i.e. \( \mathop{{\max }}\limits_{{{s_i}}} {p_i}{A_i} \). Using Eqs. 45, the FOC from this maximization is given by the following implicit function, \( F\left( {{s_i}} \right) = \frac{{\partial {p_i}}}{{\partial {s_i}}}{\pi_i} + {p_i}\frac{{\partial {\pi_i}}}{{\partial {s_i}}} = 0 \). Using the implicit function theorem on F(s i ), accounting for Eq. 2 the following condition is derived,

$$ \frac{{\partial {s_i}}}{{\partial {A_j}}} = - \frac{{\left( {1 - 2a} \right)\frac{{\partial {p_i}}}{{\partial {A_j}}} + {{\left( {1 - a} \right)}^2}{A_i}\frac{{{\partial^2}{p_i}}}{{\partial {A_i}\partial {A_j}}}}}{{{M_i}\left( {2\left( {1 - 2a} \right)\frac{{\partial {p_i}}}{{\partial {A_i}}} + {{\left( {1 - a} \right)}^2}{A_i}\frac{{{\partial^2}{p_i}}}{{\partial A_i^2}}} \right)}} $$
(6)

In Eq. 6, if \( a \in \left( {0.5,1} \right) \), then \( \frac{{\partial {s_i}}}{{\partial {A_j}}} \) is always greater than zero if (a) M i  > 0, and (b) \( \frac{{\partial {p_i}}}{{\partial {A_j}}} > - \frac{{{{\left( {1 - a} \right)}^2}{A_i}}}{{\left( {1 - 2a} \right)}}\frac{{{\partial^2}{p_i}}}{{\partial {A_i}\partial {A_j}}} \). Furthermore, if \( a \in \left( {0,0.5} \right) \), then \( \frac{{\partial {s_i}}}{{\partial {A_j}}} \) is always greater than zero if a) M i  > 0, and b) \( \frac{{\partial {p_i}}}{{\partial {A_i}}} > - \frac{{{{\left( {1 - a} \right)}^2}{A_i}}}{{2\left( {1 - 2a} \right)}}\frac{{{\partial^2}{p_i}}}{{\partial A_i^2}} \).

Overall, the above discussion allows one to concentrate on the following question, how will the leader respond to an increase in A j ? As it turns out, if μ i  > γ and \( \frac{{\partial {p_i}}}{{\partial {A_j}}} > - \frac{{{{\left( {1 - a} \right)}^2}{A_i}}}{{\left( {1 - 2a} \right)}}\frac{{{\partial^2}{p_i}}}{{\partial {A_i}\partial {A_j}}} \), \( \frac{{\partial {p_i}}}{{\partial {A_i}}} > - \frac{{{{\left( {1 - a} \right)}^2}{A_i}}}{{2\left( {1 - 2a} \right)}}\frac{{{\partial^2}{p_i}}}{{\partial A_i^2}} \) any increase in A j should ceteris paribus lead i to respond by adopting a greater s i ; by assumption \( \frac{{\partial {p_i}}}{{\partial {A_i}}} > \frac{{{\partial^2}{p_i}}}{{\partial A_i^2}} \) and \( \frac{{\partial {p_i}}}{{\partial {A_j}}} > \frac{{{\partial^2}{p_i}}}{{\partial {A_i}\partial {A_j}}} \), thus the above inequalities always hold. In a similar fashion, if μ j  > γ, when the follower j faces the leader’s higher technology it must also adopt a greater s j in its innovation process; because \( \frac{{\partial {s_j}}}{{\partial {A_i}}} \). The above intuition implies that if between two periods there is an increase in λ, which leads to more competition, then there will be an increase in s. As a result, considering that \( \Delta {A_i} = \gamma + {s_i}\left( {{\mu_i} - \gamma } \right) \), if μ j  > γ, increases in λ lead to a greater s, a greater expected innovation and a greater expected technology A i .Footnote 13

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Panagopoulos, A. The Effect of IP Protection on Radical and Incremental Innovation. J Knowl Econ 2, 393–404 (2011). https://doi.org/10.1007/s13132-011-0039-6

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s13132-011-0039-6

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation