Skip to main content
Log in

Can overconfidence explain the consumption hump?

A general equilibrium inquiry

  • Published:
Journal of Economics and Finance Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

The standard neoclassical life-cycle model predicts that individual consumption should either increase, remain constant or fall monotonically depending on whether the market rate of return on savings is greater than, equal to or less than the discount rate. However, empirical evidence suggests that even after controlling for economic growth and family size, household consumption exhibits a robust hump at around age 45–55, with the ratio of peak consumption to consumption when entering the workforce greater than 1.1. This paper extends the “overconfidence” explanation (Caliendo and Huang, J. Macroecon 30(4):1347–1369, 2008) of this macroeconomic puzzle to a calibrated general equilibrium environment. The main finding is that although it is possible to identify parameter values under which overconfidence alone generates life-cycle consumption profiles and macro-indicators consistent with U.S. experience, quite extreme assumptions about both the magnitude and distribution of overconfidence in the population are generally required to obtain them.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5
Fig. 6
Fig. 7
Fig. 8
Fig. 9
Fig. 10
Fig. 11

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Laibson (1997) examines time-inconsistent behavior in the presence of hyperbolic discounting, in which the consumer is modeled as a sequence of temporal selves making choices in a dynamic game. The equilibrium behavior in such a framework is given by the subgame perfect equilibrium of the dynamic game.

  2. Time-arbitrage opportunities arise when there is a difference between the rate at which an agent discounts future utility and the rate of return from his assets. Agents having a discount rate lower than the rate of return are net savers and allocate higher consumption to future periods, and those with a discount rate higher than the rate of return are net dissavers and allocate lower consumption to future periods.

  3. See the appendix of Caliendo and Huang (2008) for the procedure of deriving the actual consumption profile.

  4. As empirical evidence points out, the consumption hump is a work life phenomenon rather than retired life. Also, there is considerable evidence that retirees tend to annuitize their wealth (Johnson et al. 2004; Gale and Phillips 2006). Therefore, it seems reasonable to abstract from overconfident behavior during retirement.

  5. I consider alternative assumptions about the distribution of overconfident agents in the population in the sensitivity analysis section.

  6. This specification of the loss function follows Caliendo (2008).

  7. I use equal weight for each target, i.e. ω i  = 0.5 ∀ i.

  8. Degrees of overconfidence as high as 100% may not be totally unrealistic if investors have a tendency to ignore taxation on capital income, which can easily reach up to 50% when accounting for both corporate and personal taxation. Gordon (1985) shows that taxation of corporate income can theoretically leave corporate investment and individual savings incentives unaffected. Using data from the Citizens Utility Company (CU), Stamford, CT, Hubbard and Michaely (1997) find evidence that investors do ignore dividend taxation.

  9. One limitation of the baseline calibration in general equilibrium is that there is a range of z values for which the parameters that minimize the MSE satisfy r < ρ. Technically, this makes it a model of “underconfidence”, in which time-arbitrage motives dictate the agent to borrow at a rate higher than the market rate. Fortunately, this problem naturally corrects itself in the other calibrations.

  10. See Findley and Caliendo (2009) and other references therein for more information on this value.

  11. Note that we abstract from lumpy age distributions in the population (phenomena like the Post World War II Baby Boom).

  12. See Findley and Caliendo (2009) and other references therein.

  13. See Campbell and Mankiw (1990), Shapiro and Slemrod (1995) among others.

  14. These shares were estimated based on the assumption that the population consists of only two types of agents: permanent income consumers and rule-of-thumb consumers. Therefore, using the estimated shares from Campbell and Mankiw (1990), Shapiro and Slemrod (1995) may not be entirely appropriate. However, given that we have no other information about the share of overconfident consumers in the economy, this seems to be a reasonable approximation.

References

  • Agarwal S (2007) The impact of homeowners’ housing wealth misestimation on consumption and saving decisions. Real Estate Econ 35(2):135–154

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Attanasio OP, Browning M (1995) Consumption over the life cycle and over the business cycle. Am Econ Rev 85(5):1118–1137

    Google Scholar 

  • Barber BM, Odean T (2000) Trading is hazardous to your wealth: the common stock investment performance of individual investors. J Finance 55(2):773–806

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barber BM, Odean T (2001) Boys will be boys: gender, overconfidence, and common stock investment. Q J Econ 116(1):261–292

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bertaut C, Starr-McCluer M (2000) Household portfolios in the United States. Federal reserve board of Governers working paper

  • Browning M, Ejrnæs M (2009) Consumption and children. Rev Econ Stat 91(1):93–111

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Browning M, Deaton A, Irish M (1985) A profitable approach to labor supply and commodity demands over the life-cycle. Econometrica 53(3):503–544

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brunnermeier MK, Parker JA (2005) Optimal expectations. Am Econ Rev 95(4):1092–1118

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bucciol A (2007) Temptation toward consumption and life-cycle behaviour. SSRN eLibrary

  • Bucciol A (2008) Social security, dynamic efficiency and self-control problems. SSRN eLibrary

  • Bullard J, Feigenbaum J (2007) A leisurely reading of the life-cycle consumption data. J Monet Econ 54(8):2305–2320

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bütler M (2001) Neoclassical life-cycle consumption. Econ Theory 17:209–221

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Caliendo FN (2008) Is social security behind the collapse of personal saving?: a general equilibrium approach. Working paper

  • Caliendo FN, Aadland D (2007) Short-term planning and the life-cycle consumption puzzle. J Econ Dyn Control 31:1392–1415

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Caliendo FN, Gahramanov E (2009) Hunting the unobservables for optimal social security: a general equilibrium approach. Public Finance Rev (in press)

  • Caliendo FN, Huang KXD (2008) Overconfidence and consumption over the life cycle. J Macroecon 30(4):1347–1369

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Campbell JY, Mankiw NG (1990) Permanent income, current income, and consumption. J Bus Econ Stat 8(3):265–279

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Carroll CD (1997) Buffer-stock saving and the life cycle/permanent income hypothesis. Q J Econ 112(1):1–55

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Carroll CD (2000) Why do the rich save so much? In: Slemrod JB (ed) Does atlas shrug? the economic consequences of taxing the rich. Harvard University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Carroll CD, Summers LH (1991) Consumption growth parallels income growth: some new evidence. In: Douglas B, Shoven J (eds) National saving and economic performance. University of Chicago Press, Chicago

    Google Scholar 

  • Deaves R, Lüders E, Schröder M (2005) The dynamics of overconfidence: evidence from stock market forecasters. Center for European economic research discussion paper 05-83

  • Feigenbaum J (2007) Precautionary saving unfettered. Working paper

  • Feigenbaum J (2008) Can mortality risk explain the consumption hump? J Macroecon 30(3):844–872

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Feldstein M (1985) The optimal level of social security benefits. Q J Econ 100(2):303–320

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fernández-Villaverde J, Krueger D (2002) Consumption and saving over the life cycle: how important are consumer durables? Stanford Institute for economic policy research discussion paper 01-34

  • Fernández-Villaverde J, Krueger D (2007) Consumption over the life cycle: facts from consumer expenditure survey data. Rev Econ Stat 89(3):552–565

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Findley TS, Caliendo FN (2009) Short horizons, time inconsistency, and optimal social security. Int Tax Public Financ (in press)

  • Fisher KL, Statman M (2002) Bubble expectations. J Wealth Manag 5(2):17–22

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gale WG, Phillips JWR (2006) Pensions, social security, wealth and lifetime earnings: evidence from the health and retirement study. Center for retirement research working paper

  • Gervais S, Odean T (2001) Learning to be overconfident. Rev Financ Stud 14(1):1–27

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gordon RH (1985) Taxation of corporate capital income: tax revenues versus tax distortions. Q J Econ 100(1):1–27

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gourinchas PO, Parker JA (2002) Consumption over the life cycle. Econometrica 70(1):47–89

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gul F, Pesendorfer W (2001) Temptation and self-control. Econometrica 69(6):1403–1435

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hansen LP, Heckman JJ (1996) The empirical foundations of calibration. J Econ Perspect 10(1):87–104

    Google Scholar 

  • Heckman JJ (1974) Life cycle consumption and labor supply: an explanation of the relationship between income and consumption over the life cycle. Am Econ Rev 64(1):188–194

    Google Scholar 

  • Huang K, Caliendo FN (2007) Rationalizing seven consumption-saving puzzles in a unified framework. Working paper

  • Hubbard J, Michaely R (1997) Do investors ignore dividend taxation? a reexamination of the citizens utilities case. J Financ Quant Anal 32(1):117–135

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hubbard R, Skinner J, Zeldes S (1994) The importance of precautionary motives in explaining individual and aggregate saving. Carnegie-Rochester Conf Ser Public Policy 40:59–125

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hvide HK (2002) Pragmatic beliefs and overconfidence. J Econ Behav Organ 48(1):15–28

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • İmrohoroğlu A, İmrohoroğlu S, Joines DH (2003) Time-inconsistent preferences and social security. Q J Econ 118(2):745–784

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Johnson RW, Burman LE, Kobes DI (2004) Annuitized wealth at older ages: evidence from the health and retirement study. Final report to the employee benefits security administration US Department of Labor

  • Laibson D (1997) Golden eggs and hyperbolic discounting. Q J Econ 112(2):443–477

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nagatani K (1972) Life cycle saving: theory and fact. Am Econ Rev 62(3):344–353

    Google Scholar 

  • Park HS (2008) Bounded rationality and lifecycle consumption: a general equilibrium model with short term planning. Working paper

  • Ríos-Rull JV (1996) Life-cycle economies and aggregate fluctuations. Rev Econ Stud 63(3):465–489

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shapiro MD, Slemrod JB (1995) Consumer response to the timing of income: evidence from a change in tax withholding. Am Econ Rev 85(1):274–283

    Google Scholar 

  • Siegel JJ (1999) The shrinking equity premium: historical facts and future forecasts. J Portf Manage (Fall):10–17

  • Thurow LC (1969) The optimum lifetime distribution of consumption expenditures. Am Econ Rev 59(3):324–330

    Google Scholar 

  • Yaari ME (1965) Uncertain lifetime, life Insurance, and the theory of the consumer. Rev Econ Stud 32(2):137–150

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Shantanu Bagchi.

Additional information

I have benefited from helpful conversations with Frank Caliendo, Jim Feigenbaum and Scott Findley, and from seminars at Illinois State and Utah State. The detailed recommendations of an anonymous referee have been particularly helpful.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Bagchi, S. Can overconfidence explain the consumption hump?. J Econ Finan 35, 41–70 (2011). https://doi.org/10.1007/s12197-009-9082-6

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s12197-009-9082-6

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation