Skip to main content
Log in

NGO monitoring and the legitimacy of international cooperation: A strategic analysis

  • Published:
The Review of International Organizations Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

States often invite NGOs to monitor international cooperation. Under what circumstances are states likely to take this step? We argue that NGO monitoring allows states to provide domestic publics with credible evidence regarding successful cooperation, but that this credibility carries a cost: if states fail to cooperate, a participating NGO will expose this failure and thus delegitimize the cooperation effort. Our formal analysis indicates that states obtain a dual benefit from NGO participation: in addition to enhanced legitimacy, NGO scrutiny helps states credibly commit to high cooperation levels vis-á-vis each other. The increased costs of failure, however, may deter state use of NGO monitoring. Surprisingly, we find that NGO monitoring is the most useful for states when the cooperation cost is relatively low. We explore the empirical relevance of our theoretical argument in NGO monitoring of World Bank development projects and compliance with the Kyoto Protocol. We also explain why NGO monitoring has been disallowed in the Global Environment Facility. Our analysis provides a firm strategic foundation for the idea that NGO participation sometimes confers benefits to states, and our theory has several empirically falsifiable implications.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. To be sure, NGOs can often monitor policy implementation without state permission. As we explain in the next section, in this article we focus on situations wherein formal access is important for effective monitoring.

  2. See http://www.worldbank/inspectionpanel.

  3. See http://www.ilo.org/ipec.

  4. According to a story told to the authors by one senior activist, several NGO leaders were once invited to dine with Jim Wolfensohn, then President of the World Bank, as part of his effort to develop closer relationships between the Bank and its critics. After dinner, Wolfensohn asked his guests whether they were his friends or his enemies. One replied, “Well, I guess we’re frienemies.”

  5. We recognize that international treaties may also be used to establish formal organizations with autonomous monitoring functions; the IMF is one such example. Such organizations, however, pose particular risks to states as their autonomy may allow them to escape state control (Barnett and Finnemore 1999) and are relatively uncommon.

  6. In the main model, we assume that all states are under NGO scrutiny. However, we also extend the model to cover partial monitoring of some but not all states. All our results continue to hold.

  7. In principle, NGOs should cease to be credible if they no longer represent the desires or interests of their claimed stakeholders. In practice, NGOs’ reputation for principled advocacy is often such that even when NGOs make inaccurate claims regarding the interests of their purported constituencies, they may still be perceived as trustworthy (Wade 2009; Nelson 2000).

  8. Because all NGOs involved in monitoring are subject to the same state selection and conditions, we treat them as a single actor. We recognize that a given NGO may be an umbrella organization representing multiple smaller actors, or that monitoring may be conducted by a variety of allied NGOs.

  9. We assume c > 1 to ensure that the equilibrium is interior.

  10. It is also technically necessary because if the cooperation cost was simply \(c \dot E_{i}^2\), the only equilibrium of this cooperation subgame would be zero cooperation by both states. To avoid this implausible and uninteresting outcome, we allow the cooperation cost to be somewhat lower.

  11. As shown below, this technical assumption ensures that the equilibrium is interior. Our main results would hold without this limitation, but the exposition would be cumbersome.

  12. UNFCCC 2001, Decision 24/CP.7, Section VIII

  13. ibid.

  14. Austria, Australia, Belgium, Brazil, Canada, China, Denmark, Egypt, Finland, France, Germany, India, Indonesia, Italy, Japan, Mexico, Morocco, the Netherlands, Norway, Pakistan, Spain, Sweden, Switzerland, Turkey, United Kingdom, and the United States (Reed 1993).

References

  • Aghion, P., Tirole, J. (1997). Formal and real authority in organizations. Journal of Political Economy, 105(1), 1–29.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Al-Jurf, S. (2007). Participatory development & NGOs: A. look at the World Bank in the 1990s. Viewed 6 Nov 2010 from http://www.uiowa.edu/ifdebook/ebook2/contents/part2-I.V..shtml.

  • Bank Information Center (2003) BIC toolkits for activists, issue 6: The role of Congress in multilateral development bank reform. Viewed 6 Nov 2010 from http://www.bicusa.org/en/Article.304.aspx.

  • Barnett, M., & Finnemore, M. (1999). The politics, power, and pathologies of international organizations. International Organization, 53(4), 699–732.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bodansky, D. (1999). The legitimacy of international governance: A coming challenge for international environmental law? American Journal of International Law, 93(3), 596–624.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Clark, A. M. (2001). Diplomacy of conscience: Amnesty International and changing human rights norms. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Coleman, W., & Wayland, S. (2006). The origins of global civil society and non-territorial governance: Some empirical reflections. Global Governance, 12(3), 241–261

    Google Scholar 

  • Cooley, A., & Ron, J. (2002). The NGO scramble: Organizational insecurity and the political economy of transnational action. International Security, 27(1), 5–39.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Crossette, B. (1992). Movement builds to fight harmful projects in poor nations. The New York Times, 23 Jun 1992.

  • Dai, X. (2002). Information systems in treaty regimes. World Politics, 54(4), 405–436.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dai, X. (2005). Why comply? The domestic constituency mechanism. International Organization, 59(2), 363–398.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Depledge, J. (2008). Crafting the copenhagen consensus: Some reflections. Review of European Community and International Environmental Law, 17(2), 154–165.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Edwards, M. (2001). Introduction. In M. Edwards & J. Gaventa (Eds.), Global citizen action. Boulder: Lynne Rienner.

    Google Scholar 

  • Environmental News Service (2005). British industry cuts climate emissions below expectations. Viewed 5 Dec 2010 from http://www.ens-newswire.com/ens/jul2005/2005-07-21-04.html.

  • EurActiv (2007). Global carbon trading ‘short-sighted’, NGO says. Accessed 14 Jun, viewed 5 Dec 2010 from http://www.euractiv.com/en/climate-change/global-carbon-trading-short-sighted-ngo/article-164601.

  • Falk, R. (1993). The making of global citizenship. In J. Brecher, J. B. Childs, & J. Cutler (Eds.), Global visions: Beyond the New World Order. Boston: South End Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Florini, A., & Simmons, P. (2000). What the world needs now? In A. Florini (Ed.), The third force: The rise of transnational civil society. Washington, DC: Carnegie Endowment for International Peace.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fox, J., & Brown, L. D. (1998a). Assessing the impact of NGO advocacy campaigns on World Bank projects and policies. In J. Fox & L. D. Brown (Eds.), The struggle for accountability: The World Bank, NGOs, and grassroots movements. Cambridge: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fox, J., & Brown, L. D. (Eds.) (1998b). The struggle for accountability: The World Bank, NGOs and grassroots movements. Cambridge: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gemmill, B., & Bamidele-Izu, A. (2002). The role of NGOs and civil society in global environmental governance. In D. C. Esty & M. H. Ivanova (Eds.), Global environmental governance: Options & opportunities. New Haven: Yale Center for Environmental Law and Policy.

    Google Scholar 

  • Global Environment Facility (2008) Overview of the GEF. Viewed 18 Nov 2010 from http://207.190.239.143/uploadedFiles/Focal_Areas/Pollutants/POPS-GEF-Overview-June08pdf.pdf.

  • Global Environment Facility (2010). What is the GEF? Viewed 17 Nov 2010 from http://207.190.239.143/interior_right.aspx?id=50.

  • Gulbrandsen, L. H., & Andresen, S. (2004). NGO influence in the implementation of the Kyoto Protocol: Compliance, flexibility mechanisms, and sinks. Global Environmental Politics, 4(4), 54–75.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gulf Times (2006). EU states warned on missing emission plan deadline. Accessed 8 Apr, viewed 5 Dec 2010 from http://www.gulf-times.com/site/topics/printArticle.asp?cu_no=2&item_no=80730&version=1&template_id=39&parent_id=21.

  • Guzman, A. T. (2008). How international law works: A rational choice theory. New York: Oxford University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Gwin, C. (1994). U.S. Relations with the World Bank 1945–1992. Washington, DC: Brookings Institution.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hovi, J., Skodvin, T., & Andresen, S. (2003), The persistence of the Kyoto Protocol: Why other Annex I countries move on without the United States. Global Environmental Politics, 3(4), 1–23.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hurd, I. (1999). Legitimacy and authority in international politics. International Organization, 53(2), 379–408.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kapur, D., Lewis, J., & Webb, R. (1997). The World Bank: Its first half-century. Washington, DC: Brookings Institution.

    Google Scholar 

  • Keck, M. E., & Sikkink, K. (1998). Activists beyond borders: Advocacy networks in international politics. Ithaca: Cornell University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Keohane, R. O. (1984). After hegemony: Cooperation and Discord in the World Political Economy. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Linaweaver, S. (2002). Catching the boomerang: EIA, the World Bank, and excess accountability. SOAS Water Issues Group Occassional Papers 42.

  • Lipschutz, R. (1992). Reconstructing world politics: The emergence of global civil society. Millenium: Journal of International Studies, 21(3), 389–420.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mitchell, R. B. (1994). Regime design matters: Intentional oil pollution and treaty compliance. International Organization, 48(3), 425–458.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nelson, P. (1997). Deliberation, leverage, or coercion? The World Bank, NGOs, and global environmental politics. Journal of Peace Research, 34(4), 467–470.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nelson, P. (2000). Heroism and ambiguity: NGO advocacy in international policy. Voluntas, 13(4), 478–490.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nordhaus, W. (2001). Global warming economics. Science, 294, 1283–1284.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • O’Neill, B., & Oppenheimer, M. (2002). Dangerous climate imacts and the Kyoto Protocol. Science, 296, 1971–1972.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Payne, R. (1996). Deliberating global environmental politics. Journal of Peace Research, 33(2), 129–136.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pew Center on Global Climate Change (2010). History of the Kyoto Protocol. Viewed 9 Nov 2010 from http://www.pewclimate.org/history_of_kyoto.cfm.

  • Pralle, S. (2003). Venue shopping, political strategy, and policy change: The internationalization of Canadian forest advocacy. Journal of Public Policy, 23(3), 233–260.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Price, R. (1998). Reversing the gun sights: Transnational civil society targets land mines. International Organization, 52(3), 613–644.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Raustiala, K. (1997). States, NGOs, and international environmental institutions. International Studies Quarterly, 41(4), 719–740.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Reed, D. (1993). The Global Environment Facility and non-governmental organizations. American University Journal of International Law and Policy, 9(1), 191–213.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rich, B. (1994). Mortgaging the Earth: The World Bank, environmental improvishment, and the crisis of development. Boston: Beacon Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rieman, K. (2006). A view from the top: International politics, norms and the worldwide growth of NGOs. International Studies Quarterly, 50(1), 45–67.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Risse, T. (2000). The power of norms versus the norms of power: Transnational civil society and human rights. In A. Florini (Ed.), The third force: The rise of transnational civil society. Washington, DC: Carnegie Endowment for International Peace.

    Google Scholar 

  • Robinson, E. (1992). At Earth Summit, south aims to send bill north; developing nations, putting priority on growth, say cleanup is possible—for a price. The Washington Post 1 June 1992.

  • Shaw, M. (1992). Global society and global responsibility: The theoretical, historical, and political limits of ‘international society’. Millenium: Journal of International Studies, 21(3), 421–434.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shihata, I. (1991). The World Bank in a changing world (Vol. 2). Boston: M. Nijhoff Publishers.

    Google Scholar 

  • Simmons, B. A. (2009). Mobilizing for human rights: International law in domestic politics. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Simmons, P. (1998). Learning to live with NGOs. Foreign Policy, 112, 82–96.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Spiro, P. (1998). New global communities: Nongovernmental organizations in international decision making institutions. Washington Quarterly, 18(1), 45–56.

    Google Scholar 

  • Streck, C. (2001). The Global Environment Facility—a role model for international governance? Global Environmental Politics, 1(2), 71–94.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Thomas, D. (2001). The Helsinki effect: International norms, human rights, and the demise of communism. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Thompson, A. (2006). Coercion through I.O.s: The Security Council and the logic of information transmission. International Organization, 60(1), 1–34.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Udall, L. (1998). The World Bank and public accountability: Has anything changed? In J. Fox & L. D. Brown (Eds.), The struggle for accountability: The World Bank, NGOs, and grassroots movements. Cambridge: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • United Nations (1997). UN Earth summit: Background. Viewed 28 Nov 2010 from http://www.un.org/geninfo/bp/envirp2.html.

  • USAID (2001a). Multilateral development bank loans that raise environmental concerns: Introduction. Viewed 6 Nov 2010 from http://www.usaid.gov/pubs/mdb/introduction.html.

  • USAID (2001b) Multilateral development bank loans that raise environmental concerns: Summary. Viewed 6 Nov 2010 from http://www.usaid.gov/pubs/mdb/index.html.

  • Wade, R. (1997) Greening the Bank: The struggle over the environment 1970–1995. In D. Kapur, J. Lewis, & R. Webb (Eds.), The World Bank: It’s first half-century (Vol. 2). Brookings Institution, Greening the Bank.

  • Wade, R. (2009). Accountability gone wrong: The World Bank, nongovernmental organizations and the US government in a fight over China. New Political Economy, 14(1), 25–48.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Woerdman, E. (2000). Implementing the Kyoto Protocol: Why JI and CDM show more promise than international emissions trading. Energy Policy, 28(1), 29–38.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Xing, L., Xiaohua, S., & Jing, F. (2009). China committed to emission cut: Wen. China Daily 19 Dec, viewed 5 Dec 2010 from http://news.asiaone.com/News/Latest20091219-186871.html.

  • Young, Z. (1999). NGOs and the Global Environment Facility: Friendly foes? Environmental Politics, 8(1), 243–267.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

We thank Mary Anne Borelli, Nora Keller, the anonymous reviewers, and the editor of the Review of International Organizations for comments and advice.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Christopher L. Pallas.

Appendix

Appendix

1.1 A. Mathematical Appendix: Equilibrium

To find the subgame-perfect equilibrium, consider first the cooperation levels \(E_{A}^{*},E_{B}^{*}\) without NGO monitoring. The cooperation effort of state i, \(E_{i}^{*}\), must meet the first-order condition for the expected payoff given in expression 1:

$$ E_{j}^{*} + 1 = 2c \cdot E_{i}, $$
(9)

where j ≠ i. The left side measures the benefits from increased cooperation effort (depending on how much the other state cooperates), whereas the right side measures the marginal cost of additional cooperation effort. Recall that c > 1 by assumption. This linear system of two equations has two endogenous variables, so the interior solution is unique. It is provided in expression 4 in the main text.

Suppose now NGO monitoring is allowed. Each state i selects cooperation efforts to meet the following first-order condition for expression 2:

$$ E_{j} \cdot \left(1 + L(1)\right) + 1 = 2c \cdot E_{i}. $$
(10)

Most importantly, the payoff from cooperation increases relative to the baseline case without NGO participation. Again, the linear system of two equations has two endogenous variables, so the interior solution is unique. It is given in expression 6 in the main text.

Proof of Proposition 1

The equilibrium levels of cooperation are \(\frac{1}{2c-1}\) without NGO monitoring and \(\frac{1}{2c-1-L(1)}\) with it, so the difference is

$$ \frac{L(1)}{\left(2c-1-L(1)\right)\cdot(2c-1)}, $$
(11)

an unambiguously positive expression: realistically, cooperation always increases under NGO scrutiny. Differentiation with respect to L(1) yields a strictly positive expression. □

Proof of Proposition 2

Recall that expression 11 is strictly positive. Differentiating with respect to c yields a strictly negative expression. □

1.2 B. Mathematical Appendix: Extensions

In this mathematical appendix, we demonstrate that our main results are robust to plausible variations in model assumptions. We do so by first developing a general, asymmetric version of the model and showing that our main results remain unchanged. We then explore variants of this asymmetric model to show that our main finding regarding the effect of the legitimacy payoff L(1) on NGO participation is fully robust.

1.2.1 Asymmetric States

A substantively plausible generalization of the model is to allow asymmetric cooperation costs across states. This can be attained by replacing the common coefficient c with specific coefficients c A , c B  > 1. Note that this model is fully general, and it subsumes the symmetric model.

The equilibrium solutions 4 and 6 with and with NGO participation, respectively, are now replaced by expressions \(E_{i}^{*}=\frac{1+2c_{j}}{4c_{1}c_{2}-1}\) and \(E_{i}^{*}=\frac{(1+2c_{j})(1+L)}{4c_{1}c_{2}-1}\) (by choice of parameters that ensure an interior equilibrium). With a strictly positive value of L(1), equilibrium cooperation is strictly higher under NGO participation.

Consider next the effect of varying L(1). If L(1) is high enough, we have \(E_{A}^{*},E_{B}^{*} \rightarrow 1\), so it follows that each state obtains a higher payoff. Thus, as long as the legitimacy payoff L(1) is high enough, states allow NGO participation. It follows that our main result continues to hold in the asymmetric variant of the model.

1.2.2 Unilateral Participation Allowance

Consider the general asymmetric model but suppose that state A can unilaterally decide on NGO participation prior to the cooperation subgame. The cooperation subgame remains unchanged, and so do the payoffs to state A. Thus, state A says ‘yes’ to NGO participation if and only if it obtains a higher payoff under NGO participation than otherwise. As shown in the previous subsection, this must be the case as long as L(1) is high enough.

1.2.3 Identifiable Defectors

Consider the general asymmetric model but suppose the external publics can identify whose cooperation failed. Thus, the legitimacy L is only a function of state i’s own success or failure. Now the legitimacy payoff to state i remains at ρ 0 without NGO participation. With NGO participation, the probability of the full legitimacy payoff is exactly E i while the probability of zero legitimacy is 1 − E i . Clearly, each state i has a higher best response to any given \(E_{j}^{*}\), where j ≠ i, under NGO participation than otherwise. The strictly increasing best responses imply that both states select higher cooperation levels under NGO participation.

Regardless of \(E_{j}^{*}\), state i obtains the maximal legitimacy payoff L(1) with probability \(E_{i}^{*}\). Thus, as long as \(E_{i}^{*}\) is high enough, because the cooperation cost coefficient c i is low enough and L(1) is high enough, the probability of the zero legitimacy payoff for state i is negligible. Consequently, even if the other state j fails to cooperate, state i will not be blamed for the failure.

1.2.4 Endogenous Participation

Consider the general asymmetric model but suppose that if states A,B say ‘yes’ to NGO participation, the NGO must pay a cost P > 0 to participate. Suppose the payoff for the NGO from participation is some strictly increasing function V(E A E B ), so that the NGO prefers to maximize cooperation between the states.

Note first that the cooperation subgame is again, with and without the NGO, unchanged from the original cooperation subgame. Suppose now both states have said ‘yes,’ so that the NGO must decide on participation. If it rejects, its payoff is \(V(E_{A}^{0}E_{B}^{0})^2\), where \(E_{A}^{0},E_{B}^{0}\) denote the equilibrium cooperation levels without NGO participation. If it accepts, its payoff is \(V(E_{A}^{1}E_{B}^{1})\), where \(E_{A}^{1},E_{B}^{1}\) denote the equilibrium cooperation levels under NGO participation. With \(E_{A}^{1},E_{B}^{1}>E_{A}^{0},E_{B}^{0}\), the cooperation subgame payoff to the NGO is higher under participation. Thus, the NGO participates if and only if the payoff difference exceeds the cost P.

Consider now the initial participation decisions by the states. If NGO participation benefits the states, as low as the cost P is long enough, a Pareto-efficient subgame-perfect equilibrium exists, whereby states A,B say ‘yes’ and the NGO accepts. If NGO participation harms the states, in any subgame-perfect equilibrium of the game at least one state says ‘no.’ When P is high enough, the NGO never participates, and no equilibrium of the game allows NGO participation.

1.2.5 General Functional Forms

Consider the general asymmetric model but suppose that the cooperation payoff to state i is K(E A E B ), where K is an increasing and strictly concave function such that K′(0) → ∞. Suppose the cooperation cost is C(E i ), where C′(0) = 0 and C′(1) → ∞. Without NGO participation, in equilibrium we must have

$$ K'(E_{A}^{*}K_{B}^{*}) = C'(E_{i}). $$
(12)

Since both states benefit from cooperation, we select the highest equilibrium \(E_{A}^{*}=E_{B}^{*}\) that exists.

Under NGO participation, we have instead

$$ K'(E_{A}^{*}K_{B}^{*}) + E_{A}^{*}E_{B}^{*} \cdot L(1) = C'(E_{i}). $$
(13)

Given that the best responses have positive slopes everywhere, it is immediate that the cooperation levels must increase relative to the case without NGO participation. Thus, as long as L(1) is high enough, the payoffs to both states must also increase.

1.2.6 Endogenous Revelation Effort

Let us now suppose that while states select cooperation efforts E A , E B , the NGO simultaneously selects a monitoring effort M ∈ [0, 1]. Suppose the cost of monitoring M is m(M), where M is an increasing and strictly convex function such that m′(0) = 0 and m′(1) → ∞. Suppose M is interpreted as the probability that the NGO obtains hard evidence about the success or failure of cooperation that can therefore be provided to the domestic publics for considerations. Suppose the NGO benefits from providing this evidence: if it obtains hard evidence, it obtains a payoff of 1.

Based on these assumptions, the NGO selects the monitoring M * such that m′(M *) = 1. Given this monitoring level, states understand that with probability M *, their legitimacy payoff is either L(0) or L(1), depending on failure or success, respectively. With probability 1 − M *, their legitimacy payoff is a constant. Thus, the states maximize a convex combination of payoffs with and without NGO participation (asymmetric variants of expression 1 and 2), with weights 1 − M * and M *, respectively. Thus, as M * increases, so does the incentive to cooperate by the resulting first-order conditions. Given that the case without NGO participation is equivalent to M * = 0, the main results continue to hold. Similarly, as long as L(1) is high enough, states allow NGO participation.

1.2.7 Compensation for NGO Participation

Suppose each state i = A,B obtains a bonus B > 0 if NGO participation is allowed in equilibrium. The model is otherwise unchanged except that the marginal payoff from allowing NGO participation must be strictly less than − B for NGO monitoring not to occur in equilibrium.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Pallas, C.L., Urpelainen, J. NGO monitoring and the legitimacy of international cooperation: A strategic analysis. Rev Int Organ 7, 1–32 (2012). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11558-011-9125-6

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Revised:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11558-011-9125-6

Keywords

Navigation