Skip to main content
Log in

Do intergovernmental grants create ratchets in state and local taxes?

  • Published:
Public Choice Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

A large literature on the ‘flypaper effect’ examines how federal grants to states at time period t affect state spending (or taxes) at time period t. We explore the fundamentally different question of how federal grants at time period t affect state tax policy in the future. Federal grants often result in states creating new programs and hiring new employees, and when the federal funding is discontinued, these new state programs must either be discontinued or financed through increases in state own source taxes. Government programs tend to be difficult to cut, as goes Milton Friedman’s famous quote about nothing being as permanent as a temporary government program, suggesting that it is likely that temporary federal grants create permanent (future) ratchets in state taxes. Far from being purely an academic question, this argument is why South Carolina’s Governor Mark Sanford attempted to turn down federal stimulus monies for his state. We examine both the impact of federal grants on future state budgets and how federal and state grants affect future local government budgets. Our findings confirm that grants indeed result in future state and local tax increases of roughly 40 cents for every dollar in grant money received in prior years.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. The original Friedman quote appears both in the October 27th, 2993 issue of the Cleveland Plain Dealer and in the book he coauthored with his wife Rose D. Friedman, Tyranny of the Status Quo (Harourt Brace Jovanovich, San Diego, CA, 1984, pg. 115). Variants of this quote have also been attributed to President Ronald Reagan and Utah Senator Wallace F. Bennett. Reagan’s quote is “We have long since discovered that nothing lasts longer than a temporary government program,” appearing in Ronald Reagan: The Great Communicator (Harper Perennial, New York, NY, 2001, pg. 59). Bennett’s quote is “It is an age-old Washington axiom that there is nothing so permanent as a temporary government program,” appearing (somewhat ironically given the topic of our paper) in a government committee review of federal grants to states (Periodic Congressional Review of Federal Grants-in-aid, published by United States Congress, Senate, Committee on Government Operations, 1964, pg. 15).

  2. See Higgs (1987), Chap. 8, for a discussion of the many remaining ‘institutional legacies’ of the New Deal programs.

  3. The ‘leviathan’ model of government is one that assumes the objective of government is to maximize its size, see Brennan and Buchanan (1977, 1978, 1980).

  4. For evidence that political factors influenced the allocation of stimulus funds in the recent American Recovery and Reinvestment Act see Young and Sobel (2011).

  5. For evidence that this problem is inherent in the U.S. constitutional structure, see Holcombe (1991, 1992).

  6. In this section we provide only a brief summary of the main arguments in this rather large literature. See Hines and Thaler (1995) and Bailey and Connolly (1998) for excellent overviews and summaries of this large empirical literature and the theoretical expectations.

  7. Nearly all states operate under some sort of balanced budget rule. As such, an analysis of state revenues (as we carry our here) is essentially the same as an analysis which uses state expenditures.

  8. We experimented with the inclusion of state-specific time trends in addition to our fixed effects. Our results (presented in Appendix 3) did not change in any meaningful way.

  9. A panel unit root test confirmed that our dependent variable is stationary, thus we carry out our analysis in levels.

  10. We have adjusted for the difference between federal and state fiscal years in the data by pre-lagging federal funds by one year.

  11. More formally, VIF statistics show a very high level of multicollinearity amongst our variables in all of our models containing lags.

  12. Both the AIC and BIC statistics indicate that our specifications with five lags are preferred to those with fewer lags.

  13. One can back out the implied flypaper effect coefficients (on spending) from our regressions (on taxes) for comparison with previous literature by calculating 1−β 1, which is 0.2357 in the final specification.

  14. Specifically, we multiply each state’s electoral votes by one minus the percentage margin of victory. In other words, for a given set of electoral votes states characterized by closer contests are given more weight.

  15. Percentages are for federal grants to state and local governments for federal fiscal year 2008.

  16. We thank the editor for this insight.

  17. Regressions using the top marginal tax rate as the dependent variable yielded insignificant results. Importantly, income tax revenues can be increased in a variety of ways other than changing the top marginal tax rate, including manipulation of deductions, exemptions, and tax brackets. Given our significant findings using income tax revenue, the results suggest one (or some combination) of these alternative mechanisms is being used to raise future revenue in response to the federal grant.

  18. In theory, the maximum coefficient on the current period is one, and in the table some of the coefficients are greater than one; however, none of these are significantly different from one at traditional levels.

References

  • Aragón, F. M. (2010). The flypaper effect and costly tax collection. Mimeo.

  • Bailey, S. J., & Connolly, S. (1998). The flypaper effect: identifying areas for further research. Public Choice, 95, 335–361.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brennan, G., & Buchanan, J. (1977). Towards a tax constitution for Leviathan. Journal of Public Economics, 8, 255–274.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brennan, G., & Buchanan, J. (1978). Tax instruments as constraints on the disposition of public revenues. Journal of Public Economics, 9, 301–318.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brennan, G., & Buchanan, J. (1980). The power to tax: analytical foundations of a fiscal constitution. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Courant, P. N., Gramlich, E. M., & Rubinfeld, D. L. (1979). The simulative effects of intergovernmental grants: or why money sticks where it hits. In P. Mieszkowski & W. H. Oakland (Eds.), Fiscal federalism and grant-in-aid (pp. 5–21). Washington: Urban Institute.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cullis, J., & Jones, P. (1998). Public finance and public choice (2nd ed.). New York: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Filimon, R., Romer, T., & Rosenthal, H. (1982). Asymmetric information and agenda control: the bases of monopoly power in public spending. Journal of Public Economics, 17, 51–70.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grossman, P. J. (1989a). Federalism and the size of government. Southern Economic Journal, 55, 580–593.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grossman, P. J. (1989b). Fiscal decentralization and government size: an extension. Public Choice, 62, 63–69.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grossman, P. J. (1990). The impact of federal and state grants on local government spending: a test of the fiscal illusion hypothesis. Public Finance Quarterly, 18, 313–327.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grossman, P. J. (1994). A political theory of intergovernmental grants. Public Choice, 78, 295–304.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grossman, P. J., & West, E. G. (1994). Federalism and the growth of government revisited. Public Choice, 79, 19–32.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hamilton, J. (1986). The flypaper effect and the deadweight loss from taxation. Journal of Urban Economics, 19, 148–155.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Higgs, R. (1987). Crisis and Leviathan: critical episodes in the growth of American government. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hines, J. R., & Thaler, R. H. (1995). Anomalies: the flypaper effect. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 9, 217–226.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Holcombe, R. G. (1991). Constitutions as constraints: a case study of three American constitutions. Constitutional Political Economy, 2, 303–328.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Holcombe, R. G. (1992). The distributive model of government: evidence from the Confederate constitution. Southern Economic Journal, 58, 762–769.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Holcombe, R. G. (1993). Are there ratchets in the growth of federal government spending? Public Finance Quarterly, 21, 33–47.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Holcombe, R. G. (2005). Government growth in the twenty-first century. Public Choice, 124, 95–114.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Holcombe, R. G., & Zardkoohi, A. (1981). The determinants of federal grants. Southern Economic Journal, 48, 393–399.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Knight, B. (2002). Endogenous grants and crowd-out of state government spending: theory and evidence from the Federal Highway Aid Program. American Economic Review, 92, 71–92.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Musgrave, R. (1981). Leviathan cometh—or does he? In H. Ladd & T. N. Tiedman (Eds.), COUPE papers on public economics: Vol. 5. Tax and expenditure limitations (pp. 77–120). Washington: The Urban Institute.

    Google Scholar 

  • Niskanen, W. A. (1971). Bureaucracy and representative government. Chicago: Aldine-Atherton.

    Google Scholar 

  • Niskanen, W. A. (2001). Bureaucracy. In W. F. Shughart II & L. Razzolini (Eds.), The Elgar companion to public choice (pp. 258–270). Northampton: Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Oates, W. E. (1979). Lump-sum grants have price effects. In P. Mieszkowski & W. H. Oakland (Eds.), Fiscal federalism and grant-in-aid (pp. 23–30). Washington: Urban Institute.

    Google Scholar 

  • Olson, M. (1982). The rise and decline of nations. New Haven: Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Peacock, A. T., & Wiseman, J. (1961). The growth of government expenditures in the United Kingdom. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rasler, K. A., & Thompson, W. R. (1985). War making and state making: governmental expenditures, tax revenues, and global wars. American Political Science Review, 79, 491–507.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Singhal, M. (2008). Special interest groups and the allocation of public funds. Journal of Public Economics, 92, 548–564.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Turnbull, G. K. (1998). The overspending and flypaper effects of fiscal illusion: theory and empirical evidence. Journal of Urban Economics, 44, 1–26.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Young, A. T., & Sobel, R. S. (2011). Recovery and Reinvestment Act spending at the state level: Keynesian stimulus or distributive politics? Public Choice. doi:10.1007/s11127-011-9876-x.

  • Weingast, B. R., Shepsle, K. A., & Johnsen, C. (1981). The political economy of benefits and costs: a neoclassical approach to distributive politics. Journal of Political Economy, 89, 642–664.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

We thank Thomas Stratmann, Richard Williams, the participants at the 2011 Southern Economic Association meetings in Washington, DC, the editor of this journal, and two anonymous referees for helpful comments and suggestions, and also gratefully acknowledge the financial support of the Mercatus Center.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to George R. Crowley.

Appendices

Appendix 1: Variable descriptions and data sources

figure a

Appendix 2: Statistical significance of individual lags

figure b

Appendix 3: Primary specification including state-specific year trends

figure c

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Sobel, R.S., Crowley, G.R. Do intergovernmental grants create ratchets in state and local taxes?. Public Choice 158, 167–187 (2014). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-012-9957-5

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-012-9957-5

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation