Skip to main content
Log in

Gypsy law

  • Published:
Public Choice Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

How do the members of societies that can’t use government or simple ostracism produce social order? To investigate this question I use economics to analyze Gypsy law. Gypsy law leverages superstition to enforce desirable conduct in Gypsy societies where government is unavailable and simple ostracism is ineffective. According to Gypsy law, unguarded contact with the lower half of the human body is ritually polluting, ritual defilement is physically contagious, and non-Gypsies are in an extreme state of such defilement. These superstitions repair holes in simple ostracism among Gypsies, enabling them to secure social cooperation without government. Gypsies’ belief system is an efficient institutional response to the constraints they face on their choice of mechanisms of social control.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Gypsy population estimates vary wildly. These estimates are notoriously unreliable because Gypsies don’t typically classify themselves as such when asked, like other people on the fringe of society are among the least likely to be counted in official census measures, and are commonly confused with various other ethnicities by officials. All such estimates should be taken with a grain of salt. However, according to one estimate, there are some 3–15 million Gypsies worldwide living in 40 countries (Weyrauch and Bell 1993: 340). This figure of course includes all Gypsy groups, not just the Vlax Roma.

  2. Though not technically a religion, this belief system, which defines ritually pure and impure, or moral and immoral, things/actions has religious/spiritual aspects. Gypsies’ belief system might be described as a folk religion and is typically adhered to alongside an at least professed belief in the dominant religion (some variety of Christianity) of the host country in which a Gypsy society is located.

  3. The residents of the countries to which Roma migrated dubbed them “Gypsies” because they mistakenly believed that the Roma had migrated from Egypt.

  4. Gypsies have been persecuted since this time. In some places they continue to suffer persecution today. For an account of the history of Gypsy persecution, see Hancock (1987).

  5. Other prominent subgroups include the Finnish Kaale, located in Northern Europe, the Iberian Kaale, located in Spain and neighboring countries, the Sinti, located in German-speaking Europe, and the Romanichal, located in the United Kingdom.

  6. These categories may overlap. For example, contact with fecal matter is both physically and, according to Romaniya, ritually polluting.

  7. My description of Romaniya below, and my description of Gypsy organization above, is based on the (largely overlapping) descriptions provided in Brown (1929), Clébert (1963), Lee (1967, 1997), Yoors (1967), Trigg (1973), Gropper (1975), Miller (1975), Sutherland (1975), Liégeois (1986), Sway (1988), and Weyrauch and Bell (1993).

  8. For example, I don’t consider purity rules relating to pregnancy and childbirth, which are quite remarkable in their own right.

  9. Weyrauch and Bell (1993: 337) translate gaje loosely as “barbarians.”

  10. On Gypsies’ economic activities and strategies, see Lauwagie (1979), Williams (1982), and Silverman (1982).

  11. For an odd defense of Gypsy criminality, see Lee (1967).

  12. There’s some evidence that Gypsies engage in rent seeking by lobbying local public officials to keep fortune-telling illegal as a means of restricting entry into this industry; see Tyrner-Stastny (1977: 38).

  13. Gypsy nomadism is less pronounced today than it was in past. However, it remains an important part of many Gypsies’ lifestyles and identities.

  14. On the possibility of self-enforcing exchange in large, socially heterogeneous populations, see Leeson (2008).

  15. In some cases Gypsies also permit women to attend and participate.

  16. Kaale kin groups tend to pursue economic activities in separate territories, each group viewing one territory as its own. Thus those groups monopolize the regions in which they live. However, this “cartelization” is different from the Vlax Roma’s. Kaale cartelization is informal and tacit. Vlax Roma cartels are explicit inter-kumpania agreements to restrict competition.

  17. Finnish Kaale Gypsies do in fact “divorce” just as they “marry” clandestinely and without acknowledgement. However, since, like marriage, divorce officially doesn’t exist, the potential conflicts that require adjudication when American Vlax Roma marriages end don’t, and in fact can’t, create conflicts when Finnish Kaale Gypsy (non-)marriages end.

  18. On the law and economics of blood feuding along the 16th-century Anglo-Scottish border, see Leeson (2009c).

References

  • Acton, T. A. (1971). The functions of the avoidance of Moxadi Kovels. Journal of the Gypsy Lore Society, 50, 108–136.

    Google Scholar 

  • Acton, T., Caffrey, S., & Mundy, G. (1997). Theorizing Gypsy law. American Journal of Comparative Law, 45(2), 237–249.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Anderson, T. L., & Hill, P. J. (2004). The not so wild, wild West: property rights on the frontier. Stanford: Stanford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Benson, B. L. (1990). The enterprise of law: justice without the state. San Francisco: Pacific Research Institute.

    Google Scholar 

  • Berman, E. (2000). Sect, subsidy, and sacrifice: an economist’s view of ultra-orthodox Jews. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 115(3), 905–953.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brown, I. (1929). The Gypsies in America. Journal of the Gypsy Lore Society, 8, 145–176.

    Google Scholar 

  • Carmichael, C. (1997). Gypsy law and Jewish law. American Journal of Comparative Law, 45(2), 269–289.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Clay, K. (1997). Trade without law: private-order institutions in Mexican California. Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization, 13(1), 202–231.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Clébert, J.-P. (1963). The Gypsies. Baltimore: Penguin Books.

    Google Scholar 

  • Department of Justice and Federal Bureau of Investigation (2004). Crime in the United States 2004. Available at: http://www.fbi.gov/ucr/cius_04/persons_arrested/table_38-43.html.

  • Dixit, A. K. (2009). Governance institutions and economic activity. American Economic Review, 99(1), 5–24.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ellickson, R. C. (1991). Order without law: how neighbors settle disputes. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Evans-Pritchard, E. E. (1940). The Nuer: a description of the modes of livelihood and political institutions of a Nilotic people. Oxford: Clarendon Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ficowski, J. (1951). Supplementary notes on the Mageripen code amongst Polish Gypsies. Journal of the Gypsy Lore Society, 30, 123–132.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fike, R. (2012). Is anarchy without coercion possible? Lessons from the Old Order Amish and their exemptions from the federal government. Mimeo.

  • Fraser, A. (1990). A rum lot. In M. T. Salo (Ed.), 100 years of Gypsy studies. Cheverly: The Gypsy Lore Society.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fraser, A. (1992). The Gypsies. Oxford: Blackwell.

    Google Scholar 

  • Friedman, D. (1979). Private creation and enforcement of law: a historical case. Journal of Legal Studies, 8(2), 399–415.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Greif, A. (1989). Reputation and coalitions in medieval trade: evidence on the Maghribi traders. Journal of Economic History, 48(4), 857–882.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Greif, A. (1993). Contract enforceability and economic institutions in early trade: the Maghribi traders’ coalition. American Economic Review, 83(3), 525–548.

    Google Scholar 

  • Grönfors, M. (1986). Social control and law in the Finnish Gypsy community: blood feuding as a system of justice. Journal of Legal Pluralism, 24, 101–125.

    Google Scholar 

  • Grönfors, M. (1997). Institutional non-marriage in the Finnish Roma community and its telationship to Rom traditional law. American Journal of Comparative Law, 45(2), 305–327.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gropper, R. C. (1975). Gypsies in the city. Princeton: Darwin Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hancock, I. (1987). The pariah syndrome. Ann Arbor: Karoma Publishers.

    Google Scholar 

  • Iannaccone, L. R. (1992). Sacrifice and stigma: reducing free-riding in cults, communes, and other collectives. Journal of Political Economy, 100(2), 271–291.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Koyama, M. (2012, forthcoming). The law and economics of private prosecutions in industrial revolution England. Public Choice.

  • Lauwagie, B. N. (1979). Ethnic boundaries in modern states: Romano Lavo-Lil revisited. American Journal of Sociology, 85(2), 310–337.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lee, R. (1967). The Gypsies in Canada. Journal of the Gypsy Lore Society, 46, 38–51.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lee, R. (1997). The Rom-Vlach Gypsies and the kris-Romani. American Journal of Comparative Law, 45(2), 345–392.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Leeson, P. T. (2007). An-arrgh-chy: the law and economics of pirate organization. Journal of Political Economy, 115(6), 1049–1094.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Leeson, P. T. (2008). Social distance and self-enforcing exchange. Journal of Legal Studies, 37(1), 161–188.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Leeson, P. T. (2009a). The invisible hook: the hidden economics of pirates. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Leeson, P. T. (2009b). The calculus of piratical consent: the myth of the myth of social contract. Public Choice, 139(3–4), 443–459.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Leeson, P. T. (2009c). The laws of lawlessness. Journal of Legal Studies, 38(2), 471–503.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Leeson, P. T. (2012a, forthcoming). Ordeals. Journal of Law and Economics.

  • Leeson, P. T. (2012b, forthcoming). God damn: the law and economics of monastic malediction. Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization.

  • Leeson, P. T., & Coyne, C. J. (2012). Conflict-inhibiting norms. In M. Garfinkel & S. Skaperdas (Eds.), Oxford handbook of the economics of peace and conflict. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Liégeois, J.-P. (1986). Gypsies: an illustrated history. London: Al Saqi Books.

    Google Scholar 

  • Miller, C. (1975). American Rom and the ideology of defilement. In F. Rehfisch (Ed.), Gypsies, tinkers and other travellers. London: Academic Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Posner, R. A. (1980). A theory of primitive society, with special reference to law. Journal of Law and Economics, 23(1), 1–53.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Richman, B. D. (2006). How communities create economic advantage: Jewish diamond merchants. Law and Social Inquiry, 31(2), 383–420.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Silverman, C. (1982). Everyday drama: impression management of urban Gypsies. Urban Anthropology, 11(3–4), 377–398.

    Google Scholar 

  • Skarbek, D. B. (2010). Putting the ‘con’ into constitutions: the economics of prison gangs. Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization, 26(2), 183–211.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Skarbek, D. B. (2011). Governance and prison gangs. American Political Science Review, 105(4), 702–716.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Skarbek, D. B. (2012a). Prison gangs, norms, and organizations. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 82(1), 96–109.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Skarbek, D. B. (2012b, forthcoming). The governance institutions of a drug trafficking organization. Public Choice.

  • Sutherland, A. (1975). Gypsies: the hidden Americans. Long Grove: Waveland Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sway, M. (1988). Familiar strangers: Gypsy life in America. Chicago: University of Illinois Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Thies, C. F. (2000). The success of American communes. Southern Economic Journal, 67(1), 186–199.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Thompson, T. W. (1922). The uncleanness of women among English Gypsies. Journal of the Gypsy Lore Society, 1, 15–43.

    Google Scholar 

  • Trigg, E. B. (1973). Gypsy demons and divinities. Secaucus: Citadel Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tyrner-Stastny, G. (1977). The Gypsy in northwest America. Olympia: Washington State American Revolution Bicentennial Commission.

    Google Scholar 

  • Watts, T. A. (2008). The political economy of the Amish. Mimeo.

  • Weyrauch, W. O. (2001a). Romaniya: an introduction to Gypsy law. In W. O. Weyrauch (Ed.), Gypsy law: Romani legal traditions and culture. Berkeley: University of California Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Weyrauch, W. O. (2001b). Oral legal traditions of Gypsies and some American equivalents. In W. O. Weyrauch (Ed.), Gypsy law: Romani legal traditions and culture. Berkeley: University of California Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Weyrauch, W. O., & Bell, M. A. (1993). Autonomous lawmaking: the case of the “Gypsies”. Yale Law Journal, 103(2), 323–399.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Williams, P. (1982). The invisibility of the Kalderash of Paris: some aspects of the economic activity and settlement patterns of the Kalderash Rom of the Paris suburbs. Urban Anthropology, 11(3–4), 315–346.

    Google Scholar 

  • Yoors, J. (1967). The Gypsies. Long Grove: Waveland Press.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

I thank Gary Becker, Pete Boettke, Chris Coyne, Tom Ginsburg, Robert Lawson, Richard McAdams, Richard Posner, Jens Prüfer, Jesse Shapiro, Andrei Shleifer, and William F. Shughart II for helpful suggestions and conversation. Dan Smith provided valuable research assistance. I also thank the Becker Center on Chicago Price Theory at the University of Chicago where I conducted this research.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Peter T. Leeson.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Leeson, P.T. Gypsy law. Public Choice 155, 273–292 (2013). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-012-0048-4

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-012-0048-4

Keywords

Navigation