Skip to main content
Log in

Short or long-term contract? Firm’s optimal choice

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
Empirica Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This article studies the behaviour of a firm searching to fill a vacancy. The main assumption is that the firm can offer two different kinds of contracts to the workers, either a short-term contract or a long-term one. The short-term contract acts as a probationary stage in which the firm can learn about the worker. After this stage, the firm can propose a long-term contract to the worker or it can decide to look for another worker. We show that, if the short-term wage is fixed endogenously, it can be optimal for firms to start a working relationship with a short-term contract, but that this policy decreases unemployment and welfare. On the contrary, if the wage is fixed exogenously, this policy could be optimal also from a welfare point of view.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. See OECD (2009) for a more detailed information of the evolution of temporary contracts in OECD countries.

  2. Additional to this, a recent paper by Ederveen and Thissen (2007) for the new EU member states finds that the impact of the rigidity of labor market instituions on unemployment is mixing.

  3. The implications of exogenous wages on economic performance have already been analysed by Zagler (2005). In his model, endogenous salaries obtained from the bargaining process between individual firms and unions could generate a distorted remuneration system that pays too much to the innovation sector and too little to the existing stock of knowledge. Zagler (2005) suggests that optimal salaries may be obtained from centralized wage pacts and not by government policy.

  4. See also Paolini (2007).

  5. It can be interpreted as including the value of leisure and home production, net of search costs. This wide notion of unemployment income also justifies the assumption that benefits are related to the type of worker.

  6. We give the definition of contract, a, in the next section.

  7. Given that M > N, evidently v > u.

  8. Notice that this is only a hypothetical wage, as the firm will extend the contract only to workers in σ.

  9. Remember, however, that all the workers with \(x \in ({\frac{w_{o}}{\gamma }},1]\) will always reject the STC.

References

  • Albrecht J, Axel B (1984) An equilibrium model of search unemployment. J Polit Econ 92:824–40

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Booth AL, Francesconi M, Frank J (2000) Temporary jobs: who gets them, what are they worth, and do they lead anywhere? ILR working papers 054, Institute for Labour Research

  • Booth AL, Francesconi M, Frank J (2002) Temporary jobs: stepping stones or dead ends? Econ J 112(480):189–213

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cahuc P, Postel-Vinay F (2002) Temporary jobs, employment protection and labour market performance. Labour Econ 9:63–91

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • D’Addio A Cr, Rosholm M (2005) Exits from temporary jobs in Europe: a competing risks analysis. Labour Econ 12:449–468

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Diamond P (1982) Wage determination and efficiency in search equilibrium. Rev Econ Stud 49(2):217–27

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dolado JJ, García-Serrano C, Jimeno JF (2002) Drawing lessons from the boom of temporary jobs in Spain. Econ J 112:270–295

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ederveen S, Thissen L (2007) Can labour market institutions explain high unemployment rates in the new EU member states? Empirica 34:299–317

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gagliarducci S (2005) The dynamics of repeated temporary jobs. Labour Econ 12(4):429–448

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Güell M, Petrongolo B (2007) How binding are legal limits? Transitions from temporary to permanent work in Spain. Labour Econ 14:153–183

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jovanovic B (1979) Job matching and the theory of turnover. J Polit Econ 87(5):972–990

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jovanovic B (1984) Matching, turnover, and unemployment. J Polit Econ 92(1):108–122

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mortensen DT (1982) The matching process as a non-cooperative/bargaining game. In: McCall JJ (eds) The economics of information and uncertainty. University of Chicago Press, Chicago

    Google Scholar 

  • OECD (2009) Employment Outlook. Paris

  • Paolini D (2007) Search and the firm’s choice of the optimal labor contract. CRENoS 2007/08

  • Pissarides CA (2000) Equilibrium unemployment theory. MIT, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Salvanes KG (1997) Market rigidities and labour market flexibility: an international comparison. Scand J Econ 99:315–333

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wasmer E (1999) Competition for jobs in a growing economy and the emergence of dualism in employment. Econ J 109:349–371

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zagler M (2005) Wage pacts and economic growth. J Econ Stud 32(5):420–434

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

We would like to thank F. Bloch, L. Deidda, S. Perelman, V. Vannetelbosch, and especially G. Bloise and T. Pietra for their helpful comments and discussions. Remaining errors are ours. Financial support of the Italian MIUR is gratefully acknowledged.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Dimitri Paolini.

Additional information

A previous version of the paper has been circulated as “Search and the Firm’s Choice of the Optimal Labor Contract”, CRENoS 07-08.

Appendices

Appendix 1: Search equilibrium on the SL policy with w O exogenous

Proof of Proposition 2: First, observe that the set X of workers that the firm accepts in SL contract is always an interval (x +, 1], some x +. Indeed, by the definition of undominated equilibrium, \({\frac{x}{1-\delta (1-\beta )}}>\delta \Uppi^{SL}(x)\). Hence for any \(x^{\prime }>x,{\frac{x^{\prime}}{1-\delta (1-\beta )}}\geq \delta \Uppi^{SL}\).

When w O is fixed exogenously, by Proposition 1, all the workers with \(x\in ({\frac{w_{O}}{\gamma }},1]\) will always reject the STC.

Thus, the search problem faced by the firm may be rewritten, from (6) above, as:

$$ \max \Uppi^{SL}={\frac{\kappa \left[ q\delta (1-\beta )\left( \int_{0}^{x^{-}}xf(x)dx-w_{0}\right) \right] +q\delta ^{2}(1-\beta )^{2}\left[ (\int_{x^{-}}^{x^{+}}xf(x)dx)-Ew_{sl}\right]}{\kappa \left[ 1-\delta (1-qE)-q\delta ^{2}(1-\beta )(1-\int_{x^{+}}^{1}f(x)dx)\right]}} $$

or

$$ \max \Uppi^{SL}={\frac{\kappa \left[ q\delta (1-\beta )\left( \int_{0}^{x^{-}}xf(x)dx-w_{0}\right) \right] +q\delta ^{2}(1-\beta )^{2}\left[ C(\int_{x^{-}}^{x^{+}}xf(x)dx)-D\right]}{\kappa \left[ 1-\delta +qE\delta -q\delta ^{2}(1-\beta )(1-\int_{x^{+}}^{1}f(x)dx) \right]}} $$
(21)

where \(\kappa =(1-\delta (1-\beta )), Ew_{sl}={\frac{\gamma (\int\nolimits_{x^{-}}^{x^{+}}xf(x)dx)+\alpha \delta (1-\beta )w_{O}}{1+\alpha \delta (1-\beta )}}, x^{+}={\frac{w_{O}}{\gamma}}, E\) is the probability to meet a worker in the set [0, x +).

$$ C={\frac{1-\gamma +\alpha \delta (1-\beta )}{1+\alpha \delta (1-\beta )}}\hbox{ and }D={\frac{\alpha \delta (1-\beta )w_{O}}{1+\alpha \delta (1-\beta )}}. $$

The first-order conditions with respect to x are given by

$$ \begin{aligned} &-x^{-}f(x^{-})Cq\delta ^{2}(1-\beta )^{2}(1-\delta (1-\beta ))\left[ \left( 1-\delta +qE\delta -q\delta ^{2}(1-\beta )(1-\int\limits_{x^{-}}^{1}f(x)dx)\right) \right]\\ &\quad+q\delta ^{2}(1-\beta )f(x)(1-\delta (1-\beta ))\\ &\qquad\left[ q\delta ^{2}(1-\beta )^{2}\left[ C(\int\limits_{x^{-}}^{x^{+}}xf(x)dx)-D\right] +(1-\delta (1-\beta ))\left[ q\delta (1-\beta )\left( \int\limits_{0}^{x^{+}}xf(x)dx-w_{0}\right) \right] \right]=0 \end{aligned} $$

or

$$ x^{-}={\frac{q\delta ^{2}(1-\beta )\left( \int\limits_{x^{-}}^{x^{+}}xf(x)dx)-\int\limits_{x^{-}}^{1}f(x)dx-{\frac{D}{C}} \right) +{\frac{\kappa }{C}}\left[ q\delta \left( \int\limits_{0}^{x^{+}}xf(x)dx-w_{0}\right) \right] } {\left[ 1-\delta +qE\delta -q\delta ^{2}(1-\beta )\right] }} $$
(22)

To check that the solution is unique, observe that the left-hand side of Eq. 22 is increasing in x , with range (0,1). On the other hand, the right-hand side of Eq. 22 is decreasing in x , falling from

$$ {\frac{q\delta ^{2}(1-\beta )\left( \int\nolimits_{x^{-}}^{x^{+}}xf(x)dx)-\int\nolimits_{x^{-}}^{1}f(x)dx-{\frac{D}{C}} \right) +{\frac{\kappa}{C}}\left[ q\delta \left( \int\nolimits_{0}^{x^{+}}xf(x)dx-w_{0}\right) \right]} {\left[ 1-\delta +qE\delta -q\delta ^{2}(1-\beta )\right] }} $$

to \({\frac{q\delta ^{2}(1-\beta )\left( -{\frac{D}{C}}\right) +{\frac{\kappa }{C}}\left[ q\delta \left( \int\nolimits_{0}^{x^{+}}xf(x)dx-w_{0}\right) \right] }{\left[ 1-\delta +qE\delta -q\delta ^{2}(1-\beta )\right] }}\). Hence a unique solution to (22) exists.

Appendix 2: Search equilibrium on the SL policy with w O endogenous

Proof of Proposition 3: As in the Proof of Proposition 1, the search problem faced by the firm may be rewritten as

$$ \max \Uppi^{SL}={\frac{\kappa \left[ q\delta (1-\beta )(1-\gamma )\left( \int\nolimits_{0}^{1}xf(x)dx\right) \right] +q\delta ^{2}(1-\beta )^{2}\left[ (1-\gamma )(\int\nolimits_{z}^{1}xf(x)dx)\right] } {\kappa \left( 1-\delta (1-q)-q\delta ^{2}(1-\beta )(1-\int\nolimits_{z}^{1}f(x)dx)\right)}} $$

where κ = (1 − δ(1 − β)) with \(w_{SL}=w_{O}=\gamma x\).

The first-order conditions with respect to z are given by

$$ \begin{aligned} &-zf(z)q\delta ^{2}(1-\beta )^{2}(1-\gamma )\left[ (1-\delta (1-\beta ))\left( 1-\delta +q\delta -q\delta ^{2}(1-\beta )(1-\int\limits_{z}^{1}f(x)dx)\right) \right]\\ &\quad+q\delta ^{2}(1-\beta )f(z)(1-\delta (1-\beta ))\\ &\qquad\left[ q\delta ^{2}(1-\beta )^{2}(1-\gamma )\left[ (\int\limits_{z}^{1}xf(x)dx)\right] +\left( 1-\delta (1-\beta )\right) \left( q\delta (1-\beta )(1-\gamma )\left( \int\limits_{0}^{1}xf(x)dx\right) \right) \right] =0 \end{aligned} $$

or

$$ z={\frac{q\delta}{1-\delta +q\delta -q\delta ^{2}(1-\beta )}}\left[ \delta (1-\beta )\left( \int\limits_{z}^{1}(x-z)f(x)dx\right) +\kappa \left( \int\limits_{0}^{1}xf(x)dx\right) \right] $$
(23)

To check that the solution is unique, observe that the left-hand side of Eq. 23 is increasing in z, with range (0,1). On the other hand, the right-hand side of Eq. 23 is decreasing in z, falling from

$$ {\frac{q\delta}{1-\delta +q\delta -q\delta ^{2}(1-\beta )}}\left[ \delta (1-\beta )\left( \int\limits_{0}^{1}(x-z)f(x)dx\right) +\kappa \left( \int\limits_{0}^{1}xf(x)dx\right) \right] $$

to \({\frac{q\delta}{1-\delta +q\delta -q\delta ^{2}(1-\beta)}}\left[ \kappa \left( \int\nolimits_{0}^{1}xf(x)dx\right) \right].\) Hence a unique solution to (23) exists.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Paolini, D., Tena, J.D. Short or long-term contract? Firm’s optimal choice. Empirica 39, 1–18 (2012). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10663-010-9152-1

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10663-010-9152-1

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation