Skip to main content
Log in

Testing Böhm-Bawerk’s theory of capital: Some evidence from the Finnish economy

  • Published:
The Review of Austrian Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper considers the pure labour theory of value and Böhm-Bawerk’s theory of capital as approximations of Sraffa’s model of single production, and tests them with data from the Symmetric Input-output Tables of the Finnish economy. The results show that (i) in comparison with the labour values, the actual Böhm-Bawerkian production prices are ‘equally’ good or even better approximations of the actual Sraffian production prices and market prices; and (ii) the Sraffian production price-profit rate relationship is, by and large, governed by the differences in the Böhm-Bawerkian average periods of production.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. See Fink (1980); Shaikh (1984, 1998, 2012); Petrović (1987); Val’tukh (1987, ch. 4, 2005); Ochoa (1989); Cockshott et al. (1995); Tsoulfidis and Maniatis (2002); Tsoulfidis and Mariolis (2007); Tsoulfidis (2008), inter alia.

  2. Nevertheless, setting aside the various theoretical critiques of the labour theory of value, there are (i) an empirical study, based on SIOT, which shows that there exist vectors of ‘commodity values’ (Gintis and Bowles 1981) that are better approximations of the actual production and market prices than labour values (Soklis 2009); and (ii) two empirical studies, based on Supply and Use Tables (SUT) and, therefore, on models of joint production, which show that the actual systems do not necessarily have the usual properties of single-product systems (Mariolis and Soklis 2010, and Soklis 2011). These studies cast doubt on both the findings and the inner logic of the empirical labour theory of value.

  3. For a thorough survey and analysis of the issue, see Orosel (1979), who notes that “Böhm-Bawerk repeatedly mentions compound interest (as opposed to simple interest) and explicitly points out that only for simplicity he uses the principle of simple interest in his numerical examples” (pp. 5–6, footnote 5; on this point, see also Shibata 1935, p. 119). For the close relationships between average period of production and Marx’s ‘organic composition of capital’, see von Weizsäcker (1977).

  4. For the theoretical and historical relationships between (traditional and modern) Austrian and Sraffa’s capital theory, see Burmeister (1974, 1980, ch. 4); Faber (1980); Howard (1980); Bidard (1991, pp. 48–50 and Part 2); Kurz and Salvadori (1995, pp. 176–178, 213–214 and ch. 14); Lager (2000), inter alia.

  5. It should be noted that there are also three alternative, but rather different, non-linear approximations: Bienenfeld’s (1988) polynomial, Steedman’s (1999) polynomial, and the ‘spectral approximation’ (Mariolis and Tsoulfidis 2011, pp. 99–100). All these approximations are exact when profits equal zero, whilst the first and the third are also exact when the uniform profit rate equals its maximum feasible value.

  6. The transpose of an n × 1 vector \( x \equiv \left[ {{x_i}} \right] \) is denoted by x T. \( \hat{x} \) denotes the diagonal matrix formed from the elements of x, e the summation vector, i.e. \( e \equiv {\left[ {1,1,...,1} \right]^T} \), and e i the i-th unit vector. Finally, the symbols ‘>0’, ‘≥0’ denote strict positivity and semi-positivity, respectively.

  7. We hypothesize that wages are paid ante factum and that there are no savings out of this income in order to follow most of the empirical studies on this topic (see, for example, the studies mentioned in footnote 1). Moreover, complete prepayment of wages is compatible with the Austrian theory (see Burmeister 1974, pp. 416–418).

  8. It is noted that the series of dated quantities of labour is finite iff no commodity enters, directly or indirectly, into its own production. In that case A is strictly triangular and, therefore, nilpotent, i.e. there exists an integer number κ < n, such that \( {A^{\kappa }} = 0 \), and the system of production can be represented by a single flow input-point output process of finite duration (see also Burmeister 1974, pp. 444–445).

  9. It should be noted that, setting aside Marx’s ‘equal organic compositions of capital’ case, the entire price vector cannot be proportional to that of labour values at a positive level of the profit rate (see, e.g. Kurz and Salvadori 1995, pp. 111–112). Moreover, condition (5) does not hold true as r approaches R from below (for two alternative expressions for the first derivative of the price vector at r = R, see Kurz and Salvadori 1995, pp. 99–100, and Mariolis and Tsoulfidis 2011, p. 93).

  10. In the more realistic case of joint production each element of the vector of ‘labour commanded’ prices is not necessarily a strictly increasing function of r (see Sraffa 1960, §§68 and 71–72) and, therefore, T μ (r) may be negative for certain economically significant intervals of r (see also von Weizsäcker 1971, p. 72, and the empirical evidence provided by Soklis 2011, pp. 554–557).

  11. Let v, b be arbitrary n – vectors. Then

    $$ {\left[ {{I_n} - b{v^T}} \right]^{{ - 1}}} = {I_n} + \left[ {{{\left( {1 - {v^T}b} \right)}^{{ - 1}}}\left( {b{v^T}} \right)} \right] $$

    if \( {v^T}b \ne 1 \) (see, e.g. Horn and Johnson 1990, p. 19).

  12. Mathematica 7.0 is used in the calculations, whilst the precision in internal calculations is set to 16 digits. The analytical results are available on request from the authors.

  13. For this measure, see also the Appendix.

  14. That is, the vector of production prices (see Eq. 1) is normalized by setting \( {p^T}\left[ {I_n - A} \right]{x^{*}} = 1 \), with \( {L^T}{x^{*}} = 1 \), where x* denotes the right P-F eigenvector of A, which imply that (i) \( w = {(1 + r)^{{ - 1}}}(1 - {R^{{ - 1}}}r) \); (ii) p = v(0) at r = 0; and (iii) in condition 5a T i (r) should be replaced by

    $$ {{T}_{{\text{S}}}}(r) \equiv 1 + {{w}^{{ - 1}}}\left[ {\left( {{{p}^{{\text{T}}}}AB(r)\left[ {{{I}_{n}} - A} \right]{{x}^{*}}} \right){{{\left( {{{L}^{{\text{T}}}}B(r)\left[ {{{I}_{n}} - A} \right]{{x}^{*}}} \right)}}^{{ - 1}}}} \right] $$

    or

    $$ {T_{\text{S}}}(r) = 1 + {\left( {wR} \right)^{{ - 1}}} = \left( {1 + R} \right){\left( {R - r} \right)^{{ - 1}}} $$

    It should be noted that we use the Standard commodity as the numeraire in order to follow most of the relevant literature and thus make possible the direct comparison of our results with those of other similar studies.

  15. Industry Classification: 1. Products of agriculture, hunting and related services; 3. Fish and other fishing products; services incidental of fishing; 6. Other mining and quarrying products; 7. Food products and beverages; 8. Tobacco products; 13. Pulp, paper and paper products; 15. Coke, refined petroleum products and nuclear fuels; 16. Chemicals, chemical products; 19. Basic metals; 21. Machinery and equipment n.e.c.; 23. Electrical machinery and apparatus n.e.c.; 24. Radio, television and communication equipment and apparatus; 26. Motor vehicles, trailers and semi-trailers; 27. Other transport equipment; 29. Recovered secondary raw materials; 45. Real estate services.

  16. It goes without saying that non-monotonicity is a necessary, but not sufficient, condition for price-labour value reversal.

  17. It need hardly be said that, in general, the accuracy of both approximations is a decreasing (increasing) function of the uniform profit rate (of the exogenously given real wage rate).

  18. A remarkable exception can be found in Steedman and Tomkins (1998, p. 383), where the Sraffian production price-labour value deviations are greater than those usually estimated.

References

  • Bidard, C. (1991). Prix, Reproduction, Rareté. Paris: Dunod.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bienenfeld, M. (1988). Regularity in price changes as an effect of changes in distribution. Cambridge Journal of Economics, 12, 247–255.

    Google Scholar 

  • Böhm-Bawerk, E. von. ([1889] 1959). Capital and Interest. South Holland, Illinois: Libertarian Press.

  • Burmeister, E. (1974). Synthesizing the neo-Austrian and alternative approaches to capital theory: a survey. Journal of Economic Literature, 12, 413–456.

    Google Scholar 

  • Burmeister, E. (1980). Capital Theory and Dynamics. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cockshott, P., Cottrell, A., & Michaelson, G. (1995). Testing Marx: some new results from UK data. Capital and Class, 55, 103–129.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Faber, M. (1980). Relationships between modern Austrian and Sraffa’s capital theory. Zeitschrift für die gesamte Staatswissenschaft/Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics, 136, 617–629.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fink, G. (1980). Price distortions in the Austrian and in the Hungarian economy. Journal of Economics, 41, 111–132.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gintis, H., & Bowles, S. (1981). Structure and practice in the labor theory of value. Review of Radical Political Economics, 12, 1–26.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hicks, J. R. (1939). Value and Capital. Oxford: Clarendon.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hicks, J. R. (1973). Capital and Time: A Neo-Austrian Theory. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Horn, R., & Johnson, C. R. (1990). Matrix Analysis. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Howard, M. C. (1980). Austrian capital theory: an evaluation in terms of Piero Sraffa’s Production of Commodities by Means of Commodities. Metroeconomica, 32, 1–23.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kurz, H. D., & Salvadori, N. (1995). Theory of Production. A Long-Period Analysis. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Lager, C. (2000). Production, prices and time: a comparison of some alternative concepts. Economic Systems Research, 12, 231–253.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Macaulay, F. R. (1938). Some Theoretical Problems Suggested by the Movements of Interest Rates, Bond Yields, and Stock Prices in the United States since 1856. New York: Columbia University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mariolis, T., & Soklis, G. (2010). Additive labour values and prices: evidence from the supply and use tables of the French, German and Greek economies. Economic Issues, 15, 87–107.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mariolis, T., & Soklis, G. (2011). On constructing numeraire-free measures of price-value deviation: a note on the Steedman-Tomkins distance. Cambridge Journal of Economics, 35, 613–618.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mariolis, T., & Tsoulfidis, L. (2009). Decomposing the changes in production prices into ‘capital-intensity’ and ‘price’ effects: theory and evidence from the Chinese economy. Contributions to Political Economy, 28, 1–22.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mariolis, T., & Tsoulfidis, L. (2010). Measures of production price-labour value deviation and income distribution in actual economies: a note. Metroeconomica, 61, 701–710. enlarged version available at: http://econlab.uom.gr/~econwp/pdf/dp0210.pdf.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mariolis, T., & Tsoulfidis, L. (2011). Eigenvalue distribution and the production price-profit rate relationship: theory and empirical evidence. Evolutionary and Institutional Economics Review, 8, 87–122. enlarged version available at: http://econlab.uom.gr/~econwp/pdf/dp162010.pdf.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ochoa, E. (1989). Value, prices and wage-profit curves in the US economy. Cambridge Journal of Economics, 13, 413–429.

    Google Scholar 

  • Orosel, G. O. (1979). A reformulation of the Austrian theory of capital and its application to the debate on reswitching and related paradoxa. Journal of Economics, 39, 1–31.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pasinetti, L. (1973). The notion of vertical integration in economic analysis. Metroeconomica, 25, 1–29.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Petrović, P. (1987). The deviation of production prices from labour values: some methodological and empirical evidence. Cambridge Journal of Economics, 11, 197–210.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schefold, B. (2008a). Families of strongly curved and of nearly linear wage curves: a contribution to the debate about the surrogate production function. Bulletin of Political Economy, 2, 1–24.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schefold, B. (2008b). Approximate surrogate production functions. Institut für Volkswirtschaftslehre, Johann Wolfgang Goethe-Universität, Mimeo (New version (2010) available at: http://host.uniroma3.it/eventi/sraffaconference2010/abstracts/pp_schefold.pdf).

  • Shaikh, A. (1984). The transformation from Marx to Sraffa. In A. Freeman & E. Mandel (Eds.), Ricardo, Marx and Sraffa. London: Verso.

    Google Scholar 

  • Shaikh, A. M. (1998). The empirical strength of the labour theory of value. In R. Bellofiore (Ed.), Marxian Economics. A Reappraisal (2nd ed.). London: Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Shaikh, A. (2012). The empirical linearity of Sraffa’s critical output-capital ratios. In C. Gehrke, N. Salvadori, I. Steedman, & R. Sturn (Eds.), Classical Political Economy and Modern Theory. Essays in honour of Heinz Kurz. London and New York: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Shibata, K. (1935). On Böhm-Bawerk’s theory of interest-rate. Kyoto University Economic Review, 10, 107–127.

    Google Scholar 

  • Soklis, G. (2009). Alternative value bases and prices: evidence from the input-output tables of the Swedish economy. Journal of Applied Input-output Analysis, 15, 21–39.

    Google Scholar 

  • Soklis, G. (2011). Shape of wage-profit curves in joint production systems: evidence from the supply and use tables of the Finnish economy. Metroeconomica, 62, 548–560. enlarged version available at: http://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/30183/.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sraffa, P. (1960). Production of Commodities by Means of Commodities. Prelude to a Critique of Economic Theory. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Steedman, I. (1991). The irrelevance of Marxian values. In G. A. Caravale (Ed.), Marx and Modern Economic Analysis (Vol. 1). Aldershot: Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Steedman, I. (1999). Vertical integration and ‘reduction to dated quantities of labour. In G. Mongiovi & F. Petri (Eds.), Value Distribution and Capital. Essays in Honour of Pierangelo Garegnani. London and New York: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Steedman, I., & Tomkins, J. (1998). On measuring the deviation of prices from values. Cambridge Journal of Economics, 22, 379–385.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tsoulfidis, L. (2008). Price-value deviations: further evidence from input-output data of Japan. International Review of Applied Economics, 22, 707–724.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tsoulfidis, L., & Maniatis, T. (2002). Values, prices of production and market prices: some more evidence from the Greek economy. Cambridge Journal of Economics, 26, 359–369.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tsoulfidis, L., & Mariolis, T. (2007). Labour values, prices of production and the effects of income distribution: evidence from the Greek economy. Economic Systems Research, 19, 425–437.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Val’tukh, K. K. (1987). Marx’s Theory of Commodity and Surplus Value. Formalised Exposition. Moscow: Progress Publishers.

  • Val’tukh, K. K. (2005). The theory of value: statistical verification, generalization of information, and topical conclusions. Herald of the Russian Academy of Sciences, 75, 516–528.

    Google Scholar 

  • von Weizsäcker, C. C. (1971). Steady State Capital Theory. Berlin: Springer Verlag.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • von Weizsäcker, C. C. (1974). Substitution along the time axis. Kyklos, 27, 732–756.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • von Weizsäcker, C. C. (1977). Organic composition of capital and average period of production. Revue d’Économie Politique, 87, 198–231.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Theodore Mariolis.

Additional information

We are extremely grateful to three anonymous referees for apposite comments and hints. A first draft of this paper was presented at a Workshop of the ‘Study Group on Sraffian Economics’ at the Panteion University, in June 2010: we are indebted to Antonia Christodoulaki, Fotoula Iliadi, Eleftheria Rodousaki and Nikolaos Rodousakis for helpful comments and suggestions. Furthermore, we are also grateful to Lefteris Tsoulfidis for many insightful discussions and encouragement. The usual disclaimer applies.

Appendix: A Note on the Steedman-Tomkins distance

Appendix: A Note on the Steedman-Tomkins distance

Consider two price vectors, \( {{\chi }^{{\text{T}}}} \equiv \left[ {{{\chi }_{i}}} \right] \) and \( {{\psi }^{{\text{T}}}} \equiv \left[ {{{\psi }_{i}}} \right] \), i = 1, 2,…,n, corresponding to the same production technique [A, L]. The angle, θ, between \( {{{\text{X}}}^{{\text{T}}}} \equiv {{\chi }^{{\text{T}}}}{{\widehat{\psi }}^{{ - 1}}} = \left[ {{{\chi }_{i}}{{\psi }_{i}}^{{ - 1}}} \right] \) and \( {{\Psi }^{{\text{T}}}} \equiv {{\psi }^{{\text{T}}}}{{\widehat{\psi }}^{{ - 1}}} = {{{\text{e}}}^{{\text{T}}}} \), is determined by

$$ \cos \theta = {{{\left( {{{\text{{\text X}}}^{\text{T}}}{\text{e}}} \right)}} \left/ {{\left( {\left\| {\text{{\text X}}} \right\|\left\| {\text{e}} \right\|} \right)}} \right.} $$

where ||∙|| denotes the Euclidean norm of . When, for example, χχT, ψ T represent the vectors of Sraffian production prices and labour values, respectively, θ measures the degree to which relative Sraffian production prices deviate from relative labour values. Now, let d be the Steedman-Tomkins distance, i.e., the Euclidean distance between the unit vectors \( {\text{X}}\prime \equiv {\text{{\text X}}}{\left\| {\text{{\text X}}} \right\|^{{ - 1}}} \) and \( \Psi \prime \equiv \Psi {\left\| \Psi \right\|^{{ - 1}}} = {\text{e}}{\left( {\sqrt {n} } \right)^{{ - 1}}} \). Then

$$ d \equiv \left\| {{\text{X}}\prime - \Psi \prime } \right\| = \sqrt {{2\left( {1 - \cos \theta } \right)}} $$
(Α.1)

constitutes a measure of the deviation between χχT and ψ T, which is independent of the choice of numeraire and physical measurement units.

On this basis, we may note the following:

  1. (i).

    When all but one of the elements of X tend to zero, cosθ tends to its theoretically minimum value of \( {\left( {\sqrt {n} } \right)^{{ - 1}}} \) and the Steedman-Tomkins distance tends to its maximum value of \( D \equiv \sqrt {{2\left[ {1 - {{\left( {\sqrt {n} } \right)}^{{ - 1}}}} \right]}} \). Thus, in our case, where n = 57 and, therefore, \( D \cong 1.317 \), the ‘normalized Steedman-Tomkins distances’ (Mariolis and Soklis 2010, p. 94), defined as \( d{D^{{ - 1}}} \), are in the range of 0.052–0.256, for the year 1995, and 0.053–0.279, for the year 2004 (consider Table 2).

  2. (ii).

    As it has recently been pointed out, there exists an infinite number of distances à la Steedman-Tomkins, whose ranking is a priori unknown, and the choice between them depends either on the theoretical viewpoint or on the aim of the observer (Mariolis and Soklis 2011). Nevertheless, if one, in accordance with most of the empirical studies on this topic, pay regard to measure the extent to which an actual (or accepted) price vector (e.g., p aT) deviates from its approximation (e.g., \( {\text{p}}_{\text{A}}^{\text{aT}} \) or v(0)T), then the Steedman-Tomkins distance (defined by the equation (A.1)) is adequate (see Mariolis and Soklis 2011, p. 615).

  3. (iii).

    The traditional measures of price deviations, such as the ‘mean absolute deviation’, i.e., \( {n^{{ - 1}}}\sum\limits_{{i = 1}}^n {\left| {\left( {{x_i}{y_i}^{{ - 1}}} \right) - 1} \right|} \), the ‘mean absolute weighted deviation’ and the ‘root-mean-square-percent-error’ (see, e.g., Petrović 1987, and Ochoa 1989), are unit-free. However, they are not numeraire-free. Thus, there is a good reason for preferring the Steedman-Tomkins distance (for an exploration, both theoretical and empirical, of the relationships between all these measures, see Mariolis and Tsoulfidis 2010).

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Mariolis, T., Soklis, G. & Zouvela, E. Testing Böhm-Bawerk’s theory of capital: Some evidence from the Finnish economy. Rev Austrian Econ 26, 207–220 (2013). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11138-012-0187-3

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11138-012-0187-3

Keywords

JEL classification

Navigation