Introduction

Does good governance matter for trade? Does it boost export performance? Many works in the literature suggest that this is the case (see WB 2009; Nunn 2007; Anderson and Marcouiller 2002 and Ng and Yeats 1998). The implications for developing countries seem to be straightforward, seeking an export-oriented growth strategy necessitates institutional reform tackling governance-related aspects. Nevertheless, these claims are questioned by a body of literature resting on the not-too-distant experience of some East Asian countries. These countries pursued a successful export-led growth strategy under a “developmental state” (see Wade 2018 and Haggard 2015) whose practices contradicted with good governance premises and earned the label of crony capitalism (see Aligica and Tarko 2014 and Kang 2002).

The question of institutional reform is especially important for an export-led economic strategy targeting the highly competitive markets of developed countries. As one of the biggest five economies of the world and the biggest economy in the European Union (EU), access to the German market is a big objective for many developing countries. With imports of $1.24 trillion in 2019, representing more than 54% of EU imported goods (Comtrade 2020), increasing a developing country’s share of total German imports would be translated into substantial economic and financial gains. Moreover, success in exporting to the German market could open the way for integration into the German gigantic industrial supply chain as well as to the markets of other EU countries. Efficiency and competitiveness seem not to be the only institutional reform motives when trading with Germany. The country officially proclaimed its international commitment to promoting good governance (see BMZ, BMZ 2030 Reform Strategy). This implies that higher performance in institutions such as control of corruption and voice and accountability should be rewarded by more access to German markets. Such strong commitment makes Germany a very valid case study, even in comparison to other EU states, for studying the effect of good governance institutions on trade and exporting to a developed economy. Even if the EU as an organization promotes good governance, the commitment and the resources available to its member states to achieve this objective greatly vary. Germany with its well-established developmental cooperation and aid record stands in a unique position, not only in the EU but also on a global scale.

On the other hand, the literature suggests that the Arab World is a region whose poor export performance could be attributed to institutional deficiencies (see Karam and Zaki 2019; Martinez-Zarzoso et al. 2016; Bhattacharya and Wolde 2010, p. 16 and Méon and Sekkat 2004). There is more than one reason that would suggest that the Arab World should have an active trade relationship with Germany. The first is the Euro-Mediterranean Partnership that started with the Barcelona Declaration of 1995 and called for freer trade between EU countries and the Arab region.Footnote 1 Another is the comparative geographical proximity of the region to Germany. A third reason is the differences in factor endowments between both sides. Yet, figures suggest otherwise. Arab exports to Germany lagged behind most of the world regions’ levels, including Central and South Asia, South America, and Sub-Saharan Africa (own calculation of data obtained from Comtrade). If preferential trade agreements and trade theories—from Heckscher–Ohlin to simple gravity models—fail to explain this poor performance, institutions—and especially governance-related ones-could be better explanatory factors.

This paper is investigating whether and to what extent varying levels of governance within the Arab world affect the region’s export levels to Germany. It also explores which governance institutions boost these exports and which ones might harm them, accounting for the different theoretical perspectives on the subject. Many aspects underline the importance of this research. Firstly, the relationship between good governance and the export performance of the Arab countries has not been adequately researched. Secondly, the effect of some governance indicators such as voice and accountability (V&A) on trade was often explored from the perspective of importing countries (see Berden et al. 2014) rather than exporting countries, as done here. Furthermore, while some works in the literature examined developed countries’ sincerity in promoting good governance through foreign aid to developing countries (see Zanger 2000) opening up developed countries’ markets as an incentive tool was hardly explored. On a wider scale, this study could be thought of as a case study that investigates the effect of good governance on developing countries’ export opportunities in terms of accessing the markets of advanced economies, whether by enhancing developing countries’ exporting capabilities or letting them be regarded favorably as reformers.

The empirical results of this paper suggest that good governance generally boosts Arab exports to Germany and relatively more than it does for non-Arab exporters to Germany. This is especially true for governance indicators that directly affect exporting activities, such as regulatory quality and government effectiveness. For some indicators that affect exports indirectly, however, the results are mixed for both Arab and non-Arab countries alike, especially for the textile industry. This sheds doubts on Germany’s developmental commitment to fostering good governance principles.

The next section discusses the various theoretical perspectives related to the research question. This is followed by a section on our case study. It starts with an overview of Arab exports to Germany using the available statistical data. This is followed by a sub-section on the literature on governance institutions as explanatory factors for Arab export performance. The next section introduces the methodology which is then followed by a section on results. The paper ends with a conclusion that brings further insights and offers some policy recommendations.

Theoretical Perspective

The renowned Ricardian comparative advantage theory anticipated that even for a less efficient country, comparative advantage can be realized in the products which relatively cost less to produce (see Mankiw, 2015). The Hecksher–Ohlin model, on the other hand, suggests that countries would specialize according to their factor endowments (e.g.: labor, capital). Each country should produce goods that intensively use its cheaper and abundant factors of production and import goods that use intensively its expensive and scarce factors of production.Footnote 2 An adaptation to this perspective is offered by Aghion and Howitt (1998, pp. 376, 387, 395) who have argued that the accumulation of knowledge and experience resulting from learning by doing would influence what each country would specialize in. A less developed country starting from a low initial technological basis would tend to specialize in less sophisticated products with low learning potential.

Another important theoretical perspective is provided by the gravity model. The model expects that bilateral trade will increase the GDP levels of the two involved countries are more comparable and when the geographical distance between them is smaller. Other variables were later added to the model, such as common language, the comparative size of populations, access to the sea, common borders, and trade agreements (Bhattacharya and Wolde 2010, p. 9). Augmented forms of the gravity model further add other variables including institutional, governance, and economic factors (Martinez-Zarzoso et al. 2016, p. 11), making it a widely used model in the empirical literature on trade.

With reference to these augmented forms of the gravity model, governance institutions arguably provide a good explanatory framework. Governance could affect exporting, whether directly through trade regulations or indirectly through its impact on investment, innovation, and competitiveness. This should be true for the World Bank’s identified governance institutions (the World Governance Indicators—WGI) of voice and accountability (V&A), rule of law, regulatory quality, government effectiveness, and control of corruption. An important distinction that needs to be done is between indicators that directly affect trade- namely: regulatory quality and government effectiveness, and indicators that indirectly affect trade through creating better economic conditions, namely: V&A, rule of law, and control of corruption.

The first category of governance indicators reflects the ability to formulate and implement policies and regulations that support exporting activities. Higher regulatory quality, for instance, will be reflected in implementing better trade-related regulations. This dimension is captured by the Doing Business (DB) “trading across borders” indicator, which is measured according to three components measuring the number of needed documents, amount of time, and cost (trade tariffs are excluded) to export and import. WB (2009, pp. 45–47) points to empirical studies showing how delays in exporting lead to significant losses. Moreover, it also argues that delays in importing can substantially hurt economies taking part in global supply chains. For participants in these chains, well-timed delivery of imported inputs is very crucial for domestic producers. Higher levels of government effectiveness, on the other hand, would be reflected in better formulation and implementation of export promotion strategies. Government effectiveness reflects the quality of the bureaucracy, its independence, and policy formulation and implementation.

Both regulatory quality and government effectiveness could also indirectly affect exporting. Higher regulation of entry, for instance, is believed to be detrimental to economic outcomes, since it affects competition, innovation, and productivity (see Djankov et al. 2002; Aghion et al. 2010; Beck 2005). Many empirical works showed such a negative relationship between higher regulation of entry and economic outcomes (see WB 2009, pp. 9–10; Djankov 2009; and Alesina et al. 2005). On the other hand, “Weberian bureaucracy”, one which is coherent and recruited based on merit (Evans 1997), was found by Evans and Rauch (1999) to lead to better economic outcomes.

The indirect effect on exporting is also true for the three other considered governance indicators. Higher levels of V&A would indicate higher government accountability to the public and a more open stance to freedom of association. Freedom of association, in its turn, would enable the growth of stronger business associations capable of aggregating and representing the interests of businesspeople. Smith (2004) argued that participatory and open policymaking processes improve the business climate by involving the people and making them keen on obtaining better outcomes. The expected resulting public support should intensify exchange, minimize the risk of investing, and improve government policy. This should lead to better trade policy formulation and implementation.

As for control of corruption, Anderson and Marcouiller (2002) found that corruption harms trade by increasing the insecurity of the done exchange. Moreover, many works in the literature pointed out the existence of a negative relationship between corruption and economic outcomes, due to augmenting business costs, distorting policies (Smith 2004), decreasing investment, misguiding government expenditure (Wei 1999), and reducing credit accessible to good business initiatives because of inefficient allocation of resources (Barth et al. 2009). Concerning the rule of law, Nunn (2007) has found that better contract enforcement provides a trade comparative advantage in relationship-specific investments. Empirically, many works showed that a positive correlation exists between protection of property rights and contract enforcement on one hand and economic development on the other (see Shirley 2005; and Glaeser et al. 2003). Clague et al. (1999) believed that government enforcement of contracts prevents the presence of serious impediments to the expansion of investment, innovation, and obtaining new technologies.

Nevertheless, the literature on developmental states and the experience of many East Asian countries shed many doubts on the suggested positive causality between good governance institutions and export performance. For instance, Kang (2003), while mainly referring to the East Asian export-led development experience, argued that cronyism (preferential treatment to connected businesspersons) can have a positive effect on economic growth. This is due to facilitating the enforcement of agreements, reducing monitoring costs, reinforcing integrity and credibility, and enabling better circulation of information. Such a positive relationship between corruption and growth is argued by Rock and Bonnett (2004) to be exclusive for the rising economies of East Asia, contrary to the experience of most developing countries. Gani and Scrimgeour (2016) found evidence that contract enforcement and Asian exports to Australia are negatively correlated.

Arguably, export-promoting strategies resting on supporting business cronies’ exporting activities go hand in hand with preventing unconnected businesspeople from endangering those cronies’ privileged access to resources. It, thus, means blocking broad-based independent activities through business associations (low V&A), weak enforcement of rule of law, and strict market regulations to safeguard the cronies’ market shares. An independent bureaucracy would not also be in line with this strategy. The more that this strategy affects efficiency the more it would be destructive to the export capabilities of the implementing country. Based on the above discussion, it could be argued that a crony-based export promoting strategy would be particularly inefficient if it suppressed aspects of governance that directly affect exporting. These were suggested here to be government effectiveness and regulatory quality. It would also be inefficient if important importers are so keen on promoting good governance and are using trade as a means to realizing this objective. Table 1 suggests that Germany could be a good example in this regard.

Table 1 List of relevant trade and developmental agreements between Germany and Arab countries

The Case Study: Arab Exports to Germany

An Overview

The purpose of this section is to investigate, with the help of statistical data, current Arab exporting activities to Germany from a comparative perspective.

Many trade and developmental agreements were signed between Germany (whether as a part of the EU or alone) and most of the Arab countries (see Table 1). This should have been translated into high levels of Arab exports to Germany, but the literature and statistical evidence suggest otherwise.

Generally speaking, many works pointed to the low export performance of the Middle East and North Africa (MENA) region (see Bhattacharya and Wolde 2010, p. 3).Footnote 3 It has been estimated that the share of the Arab World of international exports of non-oil products stagnated at less than 1% for three decades (Chauffour 2011, p. 2). Al-Atrash and Youssef (2000) found that Arab trade, whether intra-Arab or international, is below its potential as would be predicted by the gravity model. Another study by Behar and Freund (2011, pp. 4–5) found that MENA non-oil exports are below the world average. MENA exports to the world were estimated to be “only a third of their potential”. Of more relevance to this study, Cieślik and Hagemejer (2009) found that MENA exports to Europe have not increased because of the Euro-Mediterranean free trade agreements, although MENA imports from Europe did increase. According to Ahmed (2010, p. 23), 60% of Arab exports since the 1970s have flown to Europe. Nevertheless, German imports from the Arab world are lagging behind its imports from other regions of the world, as would be realized from looking at Table 2a (and Fig. S1 in Supplementary Appendix).

Table 2 Share of different world regions of German imports and exports in 2016

Table 2a shows German imports from different regions of the world. The classification used in Table 2a and other tables is different from the one used by the United Nations (UN) in some aspects. First, our suggested categories are mutually exclusive, where each country could only be placed in one category. Second, our used classification categorizes countries based on geographical and political-economic dimensions. The latter, which is relatively disregarded in the UN classification, accounts for trade agreements and blocks as well as political-economic relations between countries of the same category (NAFTA, Commonwealth of Independent States-former Soviet states etc.). Both points make our classification more relevant for our analysis than the UN classification. In Appendix 1, more details on the used classification are provided.

Table 2b reports that, from a regional perspective, Arab countries stand in the fourth position as a destination for German exports, receiving around 3.37% of total German exports. It is preceded only by the EU, EU-Dependent, and Schengen countries (63%), East Asia (11.34%), and North America (10.61%). German imports from the Arab region, however, are less significant. The region stands at the 9th position contributing by less than 0.9% of German imports and surpassing only Central America and Oceania (see Table 2a and Fig. S1 in Supplementary Appendix). Excluding oil (HS code 27), the share of German imports from Arab countries shrinks to only 0.55%. Given the big weight of trading between Germany and EU, EU-Dependent and Schengen countries, looking at the share of the Arab region of extra EU, EU-Dependent, and Schengen German trade (after excluding trade with EU, EU-Dependent, and Schengen) is worthwhile. Total German imports from the Arab region amount to around 3% in this case (see Fig. S2 in Supplementary Appendix).

Looking at the trend followed by German trade with the Arab region, one can see that German exports to the region considerably and steadily grew between the years 2000 and 2008 from about $11 billion to $41 billion (see Fig. S3 in Supplementary Appendix). After a remarkable fall in 2009, it grew again reaching a new peak in 2014 at around $50 billion, before shrinking once again in 2015, 2016, and 2017. German imports from the Arab region followed a slightly similar path, with imports growing between 2001 and 2008 from around $7 billion to a peak of around $21 billion. It also fell in 2009 before growing once again to around $20 billion in 2013. Henceforth, the value of imports kept regressing steadily and dramatically, except for 2017 where it grew to $13 billion. The share of oil imports from Arab countries represented 42.43% of total German imports from these countries (own calculation from Comtrade data for the year 2016). Regardless of their comparable trend movements, the gap between exports and imports considerably grew over time. In 1991, the gap was around $1.4 billion (in favor of German exports). In 2017, the gap surpassed $29 billion. As shares of German trade, a different image is provided by the data (see Fig. S4 in Supplementary Appendix). The gap between German exports to and imports from the Arab World kept fluctuating with a remarkable tendency to grow.

Such remarkable deterioration of the trade gap is explained neither by traditional trade theories nor by the gravity model unless governance indicators are accounted for as a factor affecting productivity and trade flows. The period witnessing the highlighted widening trade gap has coincided with a major deterioration in governance performance of Arab countries, as discussed later.

On an individual country basis, Table 3 shows that the United Arab Emirates (UAE) is the major Arab receiver of German exports. It ranks 20 globally. UAE is followed by: Saudi Arabia (32nd world rank); Egypt (40th); Qatar (51th); and Algeria (54th). Of more interest are the five major Arab countries in terms of contributing to German imports (major five Arab countries exporting to Germany). These are respectively: Tunisia (49th); Algeria (56th); Egypt (59th); Morocco (60th); and UAE (62nd). In other words, they are predominantly North African countries except for the UAE. Given the geographical proximity of North African countries to Germany, one could say that German importing behavior concerning the Arab world tends to follow the logic of the gravity model. If we excluded oil imports, Algeria would be no longer in the top five exporters and it would be replaced by Qatar.

Table 3 Share of different Arab countries of German imports in 2016

Comparing the trading levels of individual Arab countries with Germany through time, the growth of German imports from the UAE between 1991 and 2016 is quite remarkable. The same applies to Egypt. However, more remarkable are the sharp decreases in imports coming from Saudi Arabia, Libya, and Algeria (see Fig. S5 in Supplementary Appendix). Again, such decreases in imports from Algeria and Libya could not be explained by the gravity model or traditional trade theories unless governance variables are accounted for.

The five main imported goods by Germany from the main five Arab exporters to the country are listed in Tables 4 and 5 (and shown in Fig. S6 in Supplementary Appendix). The most important goods are:

  • “Electrical machinery and equipment and parts thereof, sound recorders and reproducers, television image and sound recorders and reproducers parts and accessories of such articles" (Code 85): is a major imported good for Germany from four of these five countries: Egypt (4.5% of German total imports from Egypt); Morocco (15.36%); Tunisia (46.91%); and the United Arab Emirates (6.91%).

  • “Mineral fuels mineral oils and products of their distillation, bituminous substances mineral waxes"(Code 27): is a major import of three out of the five countries: Algeria (94.81%); Egypt (45.78%); and Tunisia (8.64%).

  • “Vegetables and certain roots and tubers edible” (Code 7): is among the leading imports that originate from Egypt (6.15% of total imports from Egypt) and Morocco (10.04%).

  • “Apparel and clothing accessories knitted or crocheted” (Code 61): is a major import from Egypt (5.09%) and Morocco (13.74%).

  • “Apparel and clothing accessories, not knitted or crocheted” (Code 62): is a major import from Morocco (16.16%) and Tunisia (20.33%).

  • “Footwear gaiters and the like parts of such articles” (Code 64): from Morocco (12.26%) and Tunisia (7.35%).

Table 4 Major exported goods of the major five Arab exporters to Germany in 2016
Table 5 Average volume and share of German commodity imports from the leading five Arab exporting countries

Some of the mentioned goods imported by Germany from Arab countries match the theoretical expectations of the Heckscher-Ohlin model given their labor-intensive nature in labor-abundant Arab countries. This is the case, for instance, for agricultural products such as codes 7 and 8, and light industries related to the textiles sector such as codes 61 and 62. However, code 39 for plastics and code 85 for electrical machinery and equipment contradicts this theoretical perspective.

Good Governance as an Explanatory Factor

Could the performance of Arab countries in various governance indicators have a significant effect on their export performance to Germany? The previous theoretical and statistical sections suggested that this could be possible, but an empirical investigation is still needed.

The literature on Arab countries seems to suggest that institutions (see Méon and Sekkat 2004) and especially governance institutions (see Karam and Zaki 2019 and Martinez-Zarzoso et al. 2016) do harm the region’s general export performance. Martinez-Zarzoso et al. (2016) found that governance indicators significantly affect the regions’ exports and imports. All the six governance indicators, except for regulatory quality, affected MENA exports positively; and, in a comparative sense, their effects were bigger than for exports from the rest of the world. The Arab Spring has been responsible for shifting more emphasis on V&A as a factor boosting the MENA region’s exports.

Statistically, the poor export performance of the Arab region correlates with its bad performance in the governance indicators. As Table 6 (and Fig. S7 in Supplementary Appendix) shows, the Arab average percentile rank in 2010 and 2015 is always below the 40 percentile in all studied governance indicators (V&A does not even reach the 20 percentile rank). A clear deterioration is even witnessed between the two years for most of the studied governance indicators.

Table 6 Average Arab performance in governance indicators

The region’s unfavorable regulatory quality is reflected in “high and complex tariffs” (see Behar and Freund 2011, p. 4), which is anticipated to hinder the region’s integration into “production sharing” and “processing-type of trade” (Chauffour 2011, p. 13). Non-tariff measures (NTMs) are even a bigger obstacle for Arab trade (Chauffour 2011, pp. 13–14). This includes “excessive delays” attributed to long processes of inspection and clearance, the various needed documents and signatures for every trade transaction, and frequent problems encountered with state authorities. Bhattacharya and Wolde (2010, p. 16) found empirical evidence that “efficiency of customs clearance” explained why the region underperforms in trade. Having a poor business climate was held responsible for the unsatisfactory exporting performance of the MENA region, either through its unfavorable effect on competitiveness (Ahmed 2010) or SME startups (Nabli 2007a,b, and Bhattacharya and Wolde 2010, p. 6).

The low levels of control of corruption and V&A support the usual arguments made in the literature on state-business relations (SBR) in the region. This literature points to the dominance of informal forms of SBR (relations based on social and political relations) and cronyism as well as the weakness of formal SBR (e.g.: public–private dialogues) and broad-based business associations’ lobbying (see Sabry 2018; Hertog 2013; Nabli 2007b). As suggested by the theoretical section of this paper, such SBR typology should have its effect on the economic performance of the region, including its export performance. The same applies with regard to the weak performance of the region in the rule of law and government effectiveness indicators.

The previous discussion suggests that, for economic reasons, a higher performance of Arab countries in the governance indicators should increase their exports to Germany. Yet, additional reasons are supporting this assumption. An important one is specific to German developmental policy objectives. The EU proclaims the adoption of a “developmental friendly” trade policy, where its generalized scheme of preferences-plus (GSP)+ offers high reductions of tariffs on exports from developing countries provided that they abide by good governance (among others) principles (see BMZ, Global Trade). This is added to the German developmental cooperation commitment, stated in the BMZ 2030 Reform Strategy, to induce partner developing countries to fight corruption and involve their civil society. Strong business associations supported by higher levels of V&A should help in realizing such a developmental objective. Hence, a good performance particularly in control of corruption and V&A should be expected to boost chances of exporting to Germany.

Methodology

In this section, an empirical investigation using regression analysis is conducted to tackle the research question. We start with a discussion on which regression model should be used.

It is common in studies on trade relations to use OLS regressions with the specifications of the gravity model. Three major concerns, however, arise. The first is about zero trade flows that would make the use of OLS estimators inconsistent when using the logarithmic transformation of the dependent variables (see Yotov et al. 2016). Luckily, despite having many missing data, the used dataset, Comtrade, does not report any zero trade flows in the dependent variables of interest. The second concern is on the possible endogeneity of institutions (see Karam and Zaki 2019). This calls for the use of the two-stage least squares (TSLS) model. The final concern is about heteroskedasticity that usually characterizes the data on trade (Yotov et al. 2016). The results of the White’s test have shown that heteroscedasticity might be of concern (see Table 13 in Appendix 2). Santos Silva and Tenreyro (2006) suggested the use of the Poisson pseudo maximum likelihood (PPML) regression model to address this concern (see Yotov et al. 2016). We assume that addressing the endogeneity concern takes precedence over addressing heteroscedasticity. Accordingly, the results of the TSLS are used in the following analysis, while those of the PPML model are used to test for the robustness of the obtained results.Footnote 4 The regressions conducted by the TSLS and PPML models are reported in Appendix 2.

The conducted regressions cover the period between 1990 and 2017, are done on a global scale, and have different specifications. The most general form is the following:

$$\left( {{\text{Im}}\;{\text{p}}} \right)_{{{\text{Gi}}}} = \alpha + \beta_{1} \left( {{\text{Arab}}} \right)_{{\text{i}}} + \beta_{2} \left( {{\text{Governance}}} \right)_{{\text{i}}} + \beta_{3} \left( {{\text{Arab}}} \right)_{{\text{i}}} \left( {{\text{Governance}}} \right)_{{\text{i}}} + \beta_{4} \left( {{\text{Control}}\;{\text{Variables}}} \right)$$
(1)

Four sets of regressions are conducted, each of which with a different dependent variable. The dependent variable in Set {A} Regressions is German imports (G) from country (i) and in sets {B}, {C}, and {D} regressions the dependent variable is German imports from country (i) of codes 85, 61, and 62 respectively. These products were suggested earlier to be among the major non-oil industrial exports of Arab countries to Germany. The used control variables are inspired by the gravity model and other variables specific to the German case. Thus, the weighted distance between Germany and a studied country and the differences in population sizes and GDP per capita (both in absolute terms) are used as control variables. Another control variable is the EU dummy, which is used to account for the special trading position of the EU with Germany. Moreover, since we are more interested in non-oil exports of Arab countries (German imports from Arab countries), two additional control variables are used. The first is the German fuel imports (code 27) and the other is the interaction of this variable with the Arab dummy. These two variables are, however, excluded in regression sets B, C, and D.

As conventional in gravity model regressions, the regressions conducted by TSLS use the logs of the highlighted dependent variables as well as logs of the weighted distance, population differences, GDP per capita differences, and German fuel imports. Regressions conducted by PPML, however, use level values of the mentioned variables, as suggested by (Yotov et al. 2016). For the TSLS regressions, several instruments are used. These are variables on legal origins (British, French, and German, excluding Scandinavian to avoid multicollinearity), percentage of adherents to various religions (Catholic, Protestant, Orthodox, Muslim, and Buddhist), ethnic fractionalization, and colonial heritage. The data is obtained from Sabry (2013), which in its turn collected and refined data from different sources.Footnote 5

The variables of interest are: the Arab dummy; the performance of an exporting country in the five governance indicators of V&A, government effectiveness, regulatory quality, rule of law, and control of corruption; and the interaction between each of these governance indicators and the Arab dummy.

Running the variance inflation factors (VIF) test has shown that the concern that is often suggested in the literature (see Karam and Zaki 2019) on the presence of multicollinearity between the different considered governance indicators is justified (see Table 14 in Appendix 2). Thus, the above-mentioned five governance indicators are introduced simultaneously to the regressions. Thus, in every conducted set of regressions (A, B, C, and D), five different regressions are conducted each having a different governance indicator among the dependent variables and a sixth regression having the average of the studied five governance indicators.

German total imports and its imports of different products are obtained from the United Nations Comtrade dataset. The weighted distance variable, which is used to measure distances between Germany and the studied countries, is obtained from the dataset of the “Centre d’Etude Prospectives et d’Informations Internatinales” (CEPII) GeoDist dataset (the distw indicator, see Mayer and Zignago 2011, p. 11). The governance indicators are obtained from the worldwide governance indicators (WGI) dataset. To facilitate the analysis done in the following section, the governance indicators are rescaled to a percentage scale running from 0 to 100 in ascending order (instead of the original order running between -2.5 and + 2.5). Population and GDP per capita figures are obtained from the World Bank’s world development indicators (WDI) dataset. Finally, the Arab and EU dummies are created from the available data as explained in the theoretical section. Descriptive statistics of the used variables are reported in Table 7 and the results obtained from the various regressions using the TSLS model and PPML models are reported in Appendix a.

Table 7 Summary statistics

To facilitate the analysis done in the next section, calculating the effect of various governance variables on different dependent variables is calculated for Arab countries and non-Arab countries. This is done as follows:

For the function: Y = β0 + β1Govj + β2(Govj × Arab), where Govj is a governance indicator in country (j).

  • When an exporting country is Arab:

    $${\text{Overall}}\;{\text{Effect}}\;{\text{of}}\;{\text{Gov}}\;{\text{on}}\;Y = \beta_{1} + \beta_{2} \left( 1 \right) = \beta_{1} + \beta_{2}$$
    (2)
  • When an exporting Country is non-Arab:

    $${\text{Overall}}\;{\text{Effect}}\;{\text{of}}\;{\text{Gov}}_{j} \;{\text{on}}\;Y = \beta_{1} + \beta_{2} \left( 0 \right) = \beta_{1}$$
    (3)

The results obtained by using these equations are reported in Table 8. Only statistically significant variables are used in calculating these results. The reported figures are calculated from the TSLS regressions. The figures written in the bold and Italic scripts are the ones whose signs are confirmed by the regressions conducted by the PPML model. The figures written in the bold script are both matching in sign and statistically significant using both regression models. The figures are written in Italic, however, are matching in sign but are statistically significant in the TSLS regressions and insignificant in the PPML ones. Given the use of logs for the dependent variables in all the conducted regressions, the magnitude of the effects of the governance indicators is showing the effect of an increase of 0.01% in these indicators on the dependent variables.

Table 8 The effect of a 0.01% increase in Governance indicators on German imports (using TSLS model)

Results and Discussion

The results of the TSLS regressions (reported in Table 11 in Appendix 2) show that concerns on endogeneity, and specifically reverse causality, were justified. The Hausmann test shows that for most conducted regressions OLS is inconsistent and TSLS is preferred.

The results of the TSLS model regressions mostly show the expected signs for the used control variables. The logs of weighted distance, population differences, GDP per capita differences have mostly a negative effect on the different studied dependent variables, while the EU dummy has a positive effect. These coefficients of the four control variables, however, have sometimes unexpected signs and are often statistically insignificant.

Using Table 8, all the considered governance indicators of the exporting countries, whether Arab or non-Arab, have a positive and statistically significant effect on German imports. The effect is comparatively stronger for Arab countries (in comparison to non-Arab countries) for every indicator. Among the considered six governance variables, the strongest effect for Arab countries on German imports is caused by regulatory quality followed by V&A then Control of Corruption, average governance, rule of law, and finally government effectiveness. For non-Arab countries, the corresponding order is V&A, regulatory quality, average governance, government effectiveness, rule of law, and control of corruption.

This straightforward positive relation between exporting countries’ governance indicators and German imports from these countries is less evident for the studied specific products. Generally speaking, the various governance indicators seem to affect German imports from Arab countries more than they do for non-Arab countries. For non-Arab countries, only V&A, rule of law, and control of corruption have a positive effect on German imports of code 85 products. Codes 61 and 62 imports seem not to be boosted by better governance performance of exporting non-Arab countries. For Arab countries, however, three governance indicators positively affect German imports of the studied three codes’ products (codes 85, 61, and 62). Ranked according to the strength of their effect, these are: regulatory quality (strongest effect on codes 85 and 62 and second strongest on code 61 imports); government effectiveness (strongest effect on code 61 and the second strongest on codes 85 and 62 imports); and rule of law.

Surprisingly, V&A of the exporting countries, whether Arab or non-Arab, has a negative effect on German imports of the three studied products. The only exception is the positive effect of V&A of non-Arab countries on German imports of code 85 products. The negative effect of this governance indicator on imports of the three products is stronger for Arab countries than for non-Arab countries, standing in contrast to the effect of the indicator on overall German imports. Another indicator that has a negative effect on imports is control of corruption, but the effect is only on code 62 imports and only for non-Arab countries.

Using the results of the PPML regressions as a robustness check (see Table 12 in Appendix 2), only a few of the results reported in Table 8 have the sign of their effect confirmed and are statistically significant (the results written in bold script). These results are predominantly representing the effects of different governance indicators on imports from non-Arab countries. For non-Arab countries, both the TSLS and PPML regressions yield the same sign of the effect of government effectiveness, rule of law, regulatory quality, and average governance on total German imports (positive effect), rule of law on code 85 imports (positive effect), control of corruption on code 62 imports (negative effect), and V&A on codes 61 and 62 imports (negative effect). For Arab countries, only the positive effect of government effectiveness on code 62 imports is confirmed. The results yielding the same sign for both regression models but which are only statistically significant in the TSLS regressions (written in Italic) are the positive effect of Arab countries’ V&A, control of corruption, government effectiveness, and average governance on German total imports, as well as government effectiveness on code 85 German imports.

The results, thus, suggest that the two governance indicators that are more directly related to exporting activities- that is to say, regulatory quality and government effectiveness- are responsible for increasing different countries’ exports to Germany. The same applies to rule of law which indirectly affects exporting activities. This is true for Arab and non-Arab countries with regard to German total imports, and true for Arab countries in the studied three non-oil industrial products that are among the most remarkable Arab exports to Germany. Better performance in these three governance indicators is crucial for the exporting activity of Arab countries to Germany both in absolute terms and in a comparative sense relative to non-Arab exporting countries. The positive effect of government effectiveness and regulatory quality, in both Arab and non-Arab countries, is matching the theoretical reasoning introduced earlier in this paper. Better export performance should be realized from having a better-equipped and independent bureaucracy that is more capable of formulating and implementing export-promoting policies and regulations. The same is true for rule of law that should indirectly foster exporting by encouraging investment.

For V&A and control of corruption, the results are, however, mixed. These are the two governance indicators that, arguably, are relatively lesser connected to efficiency and (mostly) indirectly affecting exporting. However, they are the most related governance indicators to German trade and developmental policy (as stated in the BMZ 2030 Reform Strategy). While both indicators have a positive effect on exporting in terms of their effect on German total imports, V&A seems to have a negative effect on exporting to Germany for the textile industry (codes 61 and 62) whether from Arab or non-Arab countries. Counter-intuitively, V&A also negatively affects Arab countries’ exports to Germany of the more sophisticated code 85 product. Control of corruption, on the other hand, seems to negatively affect non-Arab countries’ exports of code 62 to Germany. Such results raise doubts on the German proclaimed commitment to fostering good governance and the possibility that it directs its trading policies towards this objective, knowing that these two governance indicators are at the core of this commitment. Thus, this seems to discredit German developmental (pro-governance promotion) trade policy as a possible explanatory factor, especially with regard to the textile industry.

For non-Arab exporters to Germany, these results could be attributed to the East Asian model of crony capitalism, characterized by high cronyism and corruption (especially after excluding the effect of EU countries on German imports). It might suggest how government crony privileges in the textile industry enable connected businesspersons to be more export competitive at the expense of the non-connected who are denied much independent lobbying power. For Arab countries, lower V&A is more relevant while crony privileges do not seem to foster exports from this industry. The Arab exporters in this industry seem to benefit from the restrictions put on independent lobbying of non-connected businesspeople; but it is also possible that they benefit from hindering any opposing societal independent action, with labor union activism being a possible candidate. Nevertheless, putting things into perspective, it was suggested earlier that the Arab World suffers from a poor export performance that is lower than the region’s potential. The connected and privileged who are shielded from opposing societal activities could have more access to German markets in this industry. But this does not mean that they are the most efficient and the export performance of Arab countries might have been better with higher V&A.

Conclusion

This paper investigated the effect of good governance indicators on Arab countries’ exports to Germany, which is a leading world economy, a country bound by trade agreements with the countries of the region, and one which is committed to promoting good governance. The theoretical discussion suggested the presence of such a link between the region’s governance institutions and its export performance, widely claimed in the literature to be rather below potential. The link flows directly through the effect of factors such as regulatory quality on export performance as well as indirectly through the effect of most of the governance indicators on private investment, innovation, and competitiveness.

The implications of the obtained empirical results were double-folded. On one hand, governance indicators are generally suggested to foster Arab exports to Germany even more than they do to non-Arab countries’ exports to Germany. This is especially true for governance indicators that are more directly related to export activities, such as government effectiveness and regulatory quality, but also for rule of law. This is evident in the effect of these indicators on total exports to Germany and exports of the three studied products (codes 61, 62, and 85). On the other hand, the results raised doubts on German commitment to promoting good governance, especially concerning the countries from which it imports textiles, an industry that is of much importance to many developing countries.

This research, thus, suggests that Arab countries should conduct major institutional reform and especially in the fields of government effectiveness, regulatory quality, and rule of law. That does not mean disregarding the need for a major reform in V&A where the region’s performance is very poor. Government effectiveness and regulatory quality should benefit tremendously from more government engagement in policy consultation with broad-based business associations as partners in formal SBR. Furthermore, improving accountability and fostering formal state-business consultation would diminish the need for informal SBR and crony networks as means for encouraging investment and general economic activity. This could consequently turn the efforts for controlling corruption and improving regulatory quality into favorable endeavors that would yield better economic outcomes and foster export competitiveness. On the other hand, Germany should keep up to its developmental goals and provide incentives for the better application of good governance principles especially in sectors that are of much importance for developing countries.

Despite the useful insights provided by this research, we have to point to its limitations. These are mainly data-related limitations and match the general comment on the literature on the Arab world. A more detailed dataset having information on the channels through which various governance indicators affect Arab exports to Germany would be a breakthrough in investigating the topic. For instance, information on business associations, their interactions with the state in public–private dialogues, and the effectiveness of such a mechanism would have helped in precisely identifying which components of voice and accountability are responsible for the region’s performance. The same is also true for the rest of the studied governance indicators. Nevertheless, rather than providing conclusive evidence on the issue, the purpose of this paper is to open a discussion and invite research on these aspects. We hope that the collection of more detailed data on many Arab countries and even on the sectoral level inside each country could help future research and further investigation of this important topic.