Skip to main content
Log in

Revisiting High Development Theory to Explain Upgrading Prospects in Business Services Global Value Chains

  • Special Issue Article
  • Published:
The European Journal of Development Research Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

The article revisits two classical approaches to development and trade, and offers an alternative account of the emergence of global value chains (GVCs) involving business services (BS), to trade-in-tasks theory. Based on this account, we propose what we call the Hirschman–Linder hypothesis (HLH), which predicts the need for an adequate ‘representative domestic’ (intermediate) demand for BS for countries to enter and upgrade in BS GVCs. We review the quantitative and qualitative empirical evidence supporting the HLH and find two main results: (i) countries with a substantial manufacturing core are more likely to participate (and eventually to upgrade) in BS GVCs, and (ii) countries endowed or specialized in natural resource industry (NRI), either the primary or extractive sectors are also likely to be part of BS GVCs. If BS GVCs represent globalization’s third unbundling for developing countries, the HLH suggests that on the one hand a core manufacturing sector is essential for entering and upgrading in BS GVCs, and on the other hand that if countries can diversify into BS and upgrade in BS GVCs specialization in natural resources might not necessarily be a curse.

Résumé

L'article revisite deux approches classiques du développement et du commerce, et propose un autre récit de l'émergence des chaînes de valeur mondiales (CVM), qui comprend les services aux entreprises, à la théorie du commerce des tâches. En se basant sur ce récit, nous proposons ce que nous appelons l’hypothèse de Hirschman Linder, qui prédit la nécessité d’une demande « nationale représentative » (intermédiaire) adéquate des services aux entreprises pour que les pays entrent et se modernisent dans les CVM des services aux entreprises. Nous passons en revue les preuves empiriques quantitatives et qualitatives qui appuient l’hypothèse de Hirschman Linder et nous trouvons deux résultats principaux: (i) les pays qui ont un noyau manufacturier important sont plus susceptibles de prendre part (et en fin de compte, de se moderniser) aux CVM du service aux entreprises, et (ii) les pays qui disposent de ressources naturelles ou qui sont spécialisés dans l'industrie des ressources naturelles, que ce soit le secteur primaire ou le secteur extractif, sont également susceptibles de faire partie des CVM du service aux entreprises. Si les CVM du service aux entreprises représentent le troisième dégroupage de la mondialisation pour les pays en développement, l’hypothèse de Hirschman Linder suggère les points suivants: d'une part, un secteur manufacturier de base est essentiel pour entrer et se moderniser dans les CVM du service aux entreprises; d'autre part, si les pays peuvent se diversifier dans le service aux entreprises et se moderniser, la spécialisation des chaînes de valeur mondiales dans le domaine des ressources naturelles peut alors ne pas nécessairement être une malédiction.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. These are defined as knowledge intensive business services (KIBS) and are usually high in value added (Ciarli et al. 2012; Meliciani and Savona 2014).

  2. In terms of the International Standard Industry Classification, BS include parts of the sectors classified as sections I (Transport, Storage and Communication); J (Financial Intermediation) and K (Real Estate, Renting and Business Activities). They exclude non-intermediate services related to G (Trade), H (Hotel and Restaurants), L (Public Administration and Defence, Compulsory Social Security), M (Education), N (Health and Social Work), O (Other Community, Social and Personal Activities), P (Private Households with Employed Persons, and Q (Extra-territorial Organization and Bodies) none of which tend to be offshored.

  3. As mentioned earlier, in terms of the International Standard Industry Classification and the Inter-Country Input Output (ICIO), business services are intermediate inputs, and contribute to the production of final goods or services. Some BS (e.g. R&D or software) contribute to intangible capital formation within the ICIO. Within the Trade-in-Value-Added data, BS GVCs are measured by the business services value added content of gross exports of all industries. Hence, within the context of international fragmentation of production process, and from an accounting perspective, ‘BS GVCs’ can be included in any GVCs, and the term is used interchangeably with ‘GVCs involving BS’. When considering the opportunities for upgrading, here we intend both those offered by diversifying into BS from manufacturing and natural resource industries GVCs, which implies upgrading to higher value added BS content of these sectors, and those linked to moving up the ladder of value added creation within BS GVCs. For instance, moving from customer research management (CRM) to knowledge process outsourcing (KPO) represents a shift to higher value-added segments of BS GVCs, as mentioned in Gereffi and Fernandez-Stark (2010) and Gereffi et al. (2010), recalled in  “Business Services Global Value Chains: Globalization’s Third Unbundling?” section.

  4. This is not a new argument and resonates with Vernon’s (1979) product life cycle theory in an international context. It is argued that highly uncertain innovative activities tend initially to be performed at home, and are relocated abroad only after the products and processes have become standardized, and the decision to move them abroad responds to a cost reduction opportunity.

  5. Consoli et al. (2015) build on Autor, Levy, and Murnane’s (2003) task-based approach and empirically test competing explanations of the demand for non-routinized skills over the past decade. They find that technology, and in particular ICT, has become less of a driver than in the 1990s demand for non-routinized skills. Indeed trade, increased access to low skilled markets, and import competition are stronger determinants of increased demand for higher level skills domestically and have resulted in more polarization at the extremes of the skills distribution.

  6. Despite the exceptions in the trade-in-tasks literature mentioned earlier, we consider the applicability of the trade-in-tasks framework to services to be not easy. It would require conceptualization of the differences between an intermediate service input, a task and a service output which is far from straightforward. Although beyond the scope of this work, it would provide an interesting direction for trade and economics of service scholars (see the example in Consoli and Rentocchini 2014).

  7. The OECD Survey of Adult Skills (PIAAC) allows quantification of the links between GVC participation and employment although not an explicit quantification of trade-in-tasks. Marcolin et al. (2016) look at the relationship between the workforce composition (in terms of shares of routinized/non-routinized and skill/unskilled tasks) and level of participation in GVCs and find “complex interactions between the routine content of occupations, skills, technology, industry structure and trade, which do not allow for a neat identification of ‘winners’ and ‘losers’ in a GVC context” (Marcolin et al., p. 3).

  8. “The input-provision, derived demand, or backward linkage effects, i.e. every non primary economic activity, will induce attempts to supply through domestic production the inputs needed in that activity. The output-utilization or forward linkage effects, i.e., every activity that does not by its nature cater exclusively to final demands, will induce attempts to utilize its outputs as inputs in some new activities” (Hirschman 1958).

  9. Interestingly, Linder (1961, p. 90) states that: “We have now given three reasons which lend support to the assertion that a particular good will not be produced at a comparative advantage unless there is a domestic market for the good. We have argued (1) that it is unlikely that an entrepreneur will ever think of satisfying a need that does not exist at home; (2) that, even if this alien need was seen, the basically correct product to fill it might not be conceived of; and (3) that, even if the basically correct product was conceived of, it is still improbable that the product could be finally adapted to unfamiliar conditions without prohibitive costs being incurred. In all, what our arguments amount to is the proposition that production functions are not identical in all countries, but that the production functions of goods demanded at home are the relatively most advantageous ones. The necessity of ‘the support of the home market’ is probably stressed by active businessmen as a reflection of the importance of relationships emphasized here.”

  10. Note that the reference to Linder in this context departs slightly from the Linder Thesis i.e. the proposition that countries with similar levels of per capita GDP should trade more intensively. Rather, because of the increase in trade in intermediates referred to earlier, this is consistent with the Linder Thesis.

  11. López-Gonzalez et al. (2019) use WIOD for 40 economies (including the EU-27 countries, Australia, Brazil, Canada, China, India, Indonesia, Japan, Korea, Mexico, the Russian Federation, Chinese Taipei, Turkey, and the US) and a rest of world grouping of 35 sectors (20 service, 11 manufacturing, and 4 primary sectors) over a 15 year time horizon (yearly from 1995 to 2009). For more details on the data, indicators, and empirical analysis, we refer the reader to López-Gonzalez et al. (2019).

  12. The term ‘commodity’ generally refers to homogenous goods whose market cannot be easily fragmented. This most often, although not exclusively, applies to the case for the production of both renewable and non-renewable NR sectors. In this paper, commodity refers to both.

  13. In the case of diversifying away from NR, the linkages framework, and the argument of beneficiation (i.e. development of downstream, forward-linked manufacturing industries that process raw materials and NR) has been criticized. For instance, Hausmann et al. (2008) argue that policies aimed at beneficiation are misguided since diversification should be based on similarity of factor and technological capabilities intensities rather than vertical linkages, and especially in the context of NR. The argument prompted by the product space framework (Hidalgo et al. 2007; Hausmann et al. 2007), seems to be related only to beneficiation (i.e. forward-linked industries), and not backward-linked ones used by NRI as intermediate inputs.

  14. An attempt to examine the stages of development and participation in GVCs is Lee and Malerba (2017).

References

  • Acemoglu, D., G. Gancia, and F. Zilibotti. 2014. Offshoring and Directed Technical Change. American Economic Journal. https://doi.org/10.1257/mac.20130302.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Amiti, M., and S.-J. Wei. 2009. Services Offshoring and Productivity: Evidence from the US. World Economy 32: 2.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Andreoni, A., and H.-J. Chang. 2017. Bringing Production and Employment Back into Development. Cambridge Journal of Regions, Economy, and Society 10 (1): 173–187.

    Google Scholar 

  • Andreoni, A., and H.-J. Chang. (2021) Bringing Production Back into Development: An introduction. European Journal of Development Research, this special issue, forthcoming.

  • Antràs, P. 2020. Conceptual Aspects of Global Value Chains. In 2020 World Development Report. World Bank.

  • Antras, P., L. Garicano, and E. Rossi-Hansberg. 2006. Offshoring in a Knowledge Economy. The Quarterly Journal of Economics. https://doi.org/10.1093/qje/121.1.31.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Autor, D.H., and D. Dorn. 2013. The Growth of Low-Skill Service Jobs and the Polarization of the US Labor Market. American Economic Review 103 (5): 1553–1597. https://doi.org/10.1257/aer.103.5.1553.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Autor, D.H., F. Levy, and R.J. Murnane. 2003. The Skill Content of Recent Technological Change: An Empirical Exploration. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 118(4): 1279–1333. http://ideas.repec.org/a/tpr/qjecon/v118y2003i4p1279-1333.html.

  • Auty, R.M. 1987. Backward Versus Forward Integration in Resource-Based Industrialisation: Malaysia and Indonesia. Tijdschrift voor Economische en Sociale Geografie 78 (2): 82–93.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Auty, R.M. 1993. Sustaining Development in Mineral Economies. Abingdon: Taylor and Francis.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bah, E. 2011. Structural Transformation Paths Across Countries. Emerging Markets Finance and Trade 47 (2): 5–19.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bair, J. 2005. Global Capitalism and Commodity Chains: Looking Back, Going Forward. Competition and Change 9 (2): 153–180. https://doi.org/10.1179/102452905X45382.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baldwin, R. 2011. Trade and Industrialization After Globalization’s 2nd Unbundling: How Building and Joining a Supply Chain are Different and Why It Matters. In Globalization in an Age of Crisis: Multilateral Economic Cooperation in the Twenty-First Century, ed. R.C. Feenstra and A.M. Taylors. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Baldwin, R. 2012. Global Supply Chains: Why They Emerged: Why They Matter and Where They are Going. NBER.

  • Baldwin, R., and J. López-Gonzalez. 2015. Supply-Chain Trade: A Portrait of Global Patterns and Several Testable Hypotheses. The World Economy 38: 1682–1721.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baldwin, R., and F. Robert-Nicoud. 2014. Trade-in-Goods and Trade-in-Tasks: An Integrating Framework. Journal of International Economics 92 (1): 51–62. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jinteco.2013.10.002.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baldwin, R., and A.J. Venables. 2015. Trade Policy and industrialisation When Backward and Forward Linkages Matter. Research in Economics 69 (2): 123–131.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bontadini, F. 2019. Power and Export Sophistication in Buyer–Supplier Relationships: Insights from Colombian Customs Data. SPRU Working Paper Series (SWPS), 2019-11: 1–63. ISSN 2057-6668. www.sussex.ac.uk/spru/swps2019-11.

  • Bontadini, F., and M. Savona. 2019. Revisiting the Natural Resource ‘Curse’ in the Context of Trade in Value Added: Enclave or High-Development Backward Linkages? SPRU Working Paper Series (SWPS), 2019-15: 1-49. ISSN 2057-6668. www.sussex.ac.uk/spru/swps2019-15.

  • Burenstam Linder, S. 1961. An Essay on Trade and Transformation. Stockholm: Almqvist and Wicksell.

    Google Scholar 

  • Burenstam Linder, S. 1967. Trade and Trade Policy for Development. New York: Praeger.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chang, H.J. 2002. Kicking Away the Ladder: Development Strategy in Historical Perspective. London: Anthem Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chang, H.-J., J. Hauge, and M. Irfan. 2016. Transformative Industrial Policy for Africa. Addis Ababa: United Nations Economic Commission for Africa.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chiquiar, D., et al. 2019. Measuring and Understanding Trade in Service Tasks. International Labour Review 158 (1): 169–190.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ciarli, T., V. Meliciani, and M. Savona. 2012. Knowledge Dynamics, Structural Change and the Geography of Business Services. Journal of Economic Surveys 26 (3): 445–467.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ciarli, T., and M. Di Maio. 2014. Theoretical Arguments for Industrialization-Driven Growth and Economic Development. In African Industrial Development and European Union Co-operation. Prospects for a Reengineered Partnership, ed. F.A.S.T. Matambalya, 30–68. New York: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Consoli, D., and F. Rentocchini. 2014. A Taxonomy of Multi-industry Labour Force Skills. Research Policy. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.respol.2014.12.005.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Consoli, D., F. Rentocchini, and F. Vona. 2015. That was Then, This is Now. Skills and Routinization in the 2000s. Industrial and Corporate Change. https://doi.org/10.1093/icc/dtw030.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Corden, W.M. 1982. Booming Sector and De-industrialisation in a Small Open Economy. The Economic Journal 92 (368): 825–848.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Corden, W.M. 1984. Booming Sector and Dutch Disease Economics: Survey and Consolidation. Oxford Economic Papers 36: 359–380.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Costinot, A., J. Vogel, and S. Wang. 2013. An Elementary Theory of Global Supply Chains. Review of Economic Studies 80 (1): 109–144. https://doi.org/10.1093/restud/rds023.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cust, J., and S. Poelhekke. 2015. The Local Economic Impacts of Natural Resource Extraction. Annual Review of Resource Economics 7 (1): 251–268.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dasgupta, S., and A. Singh. 2005. Will Services Be the New Engine of Indian Economic Growth? Development and Change 36 (6): 1035–1057.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dasgupta, S., and A. Singh. 2006. Manufacturing, Services and Premature Deindustrialization in Developing Countries: A Kaldorian Analysis. Helsinki: UNU-WIDER. http://www.econstor.eu/handle/10419/63382.

  • De Backer, K., and S. Miroudot. 2013. Mapping Global Value Chains. OECD Trade Policy Papers 159: 1–46.

    Google Scholar 

  • De Ferranti, D., G. Perry, D. Lederman, and W.F. Maloney. 2002. From Natural Resources to the Knowledge Economy. Washington, DC: World Bank.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Di Meglio, G. 2017. Services and Growth in Developing Countries: A Kaldorian Analysis. In Globalisation and Services-Driven Economic Growth, ed. N. Beerepoot, B. Lambregts, and J. Kleibert, 38–54. New York: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Di Meglio, G., J. Gallego, A. Maroto, and M. Savona. 2018. Services in Developing Countries. The De-industrialisation Debate in Perspective. Development and Change 49 (6): 1495–1525.

    Google Scholar 

  • Durand, C., and W. Milberg. 2018. Intellectual Monopoly in Global Value Chains. Working Paper 18/07. The New School for Social Research.

  • Fagerberg, J., B. Lundvall, and M. Srholec. 2018. Global Value Chains, National Innovation Systems and Economic Development. European Journal of Development Research 30: 533–556.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Felipe, J., A. Mehta, and C. Rhee 2015. Manufacturing Matters, But It’s the Jobs that Count. ADB Economics Working Paper Series No. 420. Asian Development Bank. Available at SSRN: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2558904.

  • Felipe, J., and A. Mehta. 2016. Deindustrialization? A Global Perspective. Economics Letters 149: 148–151.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Feenstra, R., and G. Hanson. 1999. The Impact of Outsourcing and High-Technology Capital on Wages: Estimates for the US, 1972–1990. Quarterly Journal of Economics 114 (3): 907–940.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fleming, J.M. 1955. External Economies and the Doctrine of Balanced Growth. Economic Journal LXV (1955): 241–256.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Friedman, T. 2005. The World is Flat: A Brief History of the Twenty-First Century. New York: Farrar, Straus and Giroux.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fujita, M., P. Krugman, and A. Venables. 1999. The Spatial Economy. Cities, Regions and International Trade. Cambridge: MIT Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Gereffi, G. 1994. The Organization of Buyer-Driven Global Commodity Chains: How US Retailers Shape Overseas Production Networks. In Commodity Chains and Global Capitalism, ed. G. Gereffi and M. Korzeniewicz, 95–122. Westport: Praeger Publishers.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gereffi, G., J. Humphrey, and T. Sturgeon. 2005. The Governance of Global Value Chains. Review of International Political Economy 12: 78–104.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gereffi, G., P. Bamber, and K. Fernandez-Stark. 2010. The Offshore Services Global Value Chain. Economic Upgrading and Workforce Development. http://www.cggc.duke.edu/pdfs/2011-11-11_CGGC_Offshore-Services-Global-Value-Chain.pdf.

  • Gereffi, G., and K. Fernandez-Stark. 2010. The Offshore Services Value Chain: Developing Countries and the Crisis. Global Value Chains in a Postcrisis World. Policy Research Working Paper 5262. World Bank.

  • Gereffi, G., K. Fernandez-Stark, and P. Psilos. 2011. Skills for Upgrading: Workforce Development and Global Value Chains in Developing Countries, November: 285. http://www.cggc.duke.edu/pdfs/Skills-for-Upgrading-Workforce-Development-and-GVC-in-Developing-Countries_FullBook.pdf.

  • Grossman, G., and E. Rossi-Hansberg. 2006. The Rise of Offshoring: It is Not Wine for Cloth Any More. In The New Economic Geography: Effects and Policy Implications, Jackson Hole Conference Volume, 59–102.

  • Grossman, G., and E. Rossi-Hansberg. 2008. Trading Tasks: A Simple Theory of Off-shoring. American Economic Review 98: 1978–1997.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grossman, G., and E. Rossi-Hansberg. 2012. Trade Tasks between Similar Countries. Econometrica 80 (2): 593–629.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Harding, T., and A.J. Venables. 2016. The Implications of Natural Resource Exports for Nonresource Trade. IMF Economic Review 64 (2): 268–302.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hausmann, R., J. Hwang, and D. Rodrik. 2007. What You Export Matters. Journal of Economic Growth 12 (1): 1–25.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hausmann, R., B. Klinger, and R. Lawrence. 2008. Examining Beneficiation, 162. Centre for International Development Working Paper. http://www.hks.harvard.edu/content/download/69081/1249134/version/1/file/162.pdf.

  • Hernández, R.A., J.M. Martínez-Piva, and N. Mulder. 2014a. In Global Value Chains and World Trade: Prospects and Challenges for Latin America, ed. R.A. Hernandez, J.M. Martinez-Piva, and N. Mulder. Santiago: Economic Commission for Latin America and the Caribbeans.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hernández, R., N. Mulder, K. Fernandez-Stark, P. Sauvé, D. LópezGiral, and F. Muñoz Navia. 2014b. Latin America’s Emergence in Global Services. A New Driver of Structural Change in the Region? Santiago: Economic Commission for Latin America and the Caribbeans.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hidalgo, C.A., B. Klinger, A.-L. Barabasi, and R. Hausmann. 2007. The Product Space Conditions the Development of Nations. Science 317: 482–487.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hirschman, A.O. 1958. Strategy of Economic Development. London: Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jones, R.W., H. Kierzkowski, and C. Lurong. 2005. What Does Evidence Tell Us About Fragmentation and Outsourcing? International Review of Economics and Finance 14 (3): 305–316. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.iref.2004.12.010.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jones, R.W., and H. Kierzkowski. 1990. The Role of Services in Production and International Trade. In The Political Economy of International Trade, ed. R. Jones and A. Krueger. Oxford: Basic Blackwell.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jones, R.W., and H. Kierzkowski. 2005. International Fragmentation and the New Economic Geography. The North American Journal of Economics and Finance 16 (1): 1–10. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.najef.2004.11.005.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • López-Gonzalez, J., V. Meliciani, and M. Savona. 2019. When Linder Meets Hirschman. Inter-industry Linkages and GVCs in Services. Industrial and Corporate Change 28 (6): 1555–1586.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kaplinsky, R. 2013. Global Value Chain, Where They Came from, Where They are Going and Why This is Important. Mimeo, SPRU, University of Sussex.

  • Kaplinsky, R. 2000. Globalisation and Unequalisation: What Can Be Learned from Value Chain Analysis? The Journal of Development Studies 37 (2): 117–146.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kaplinsky, R., and M. Morris. 2015. Thinning and Thickening: Productive Sector Policies in the Era of Global Value Chains. European Journal of Development Research. https://doi.org/10.1057/ejdr.2015.29.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Koopman, R, W. Powers, Z. Wang, and S-J. Wei. 2010. Give Credit Where Credit is Due: Tracing Value Added in Global Production Chains. NBER Working papers, No. 16426.

  • Koopman, R., Z. Wang, and S.-J. Wei. 2014. Tracing Value-Added and Double Counting in Gross Exports. American Economic Review 104 (2): 459–494.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Krugman, P. 1994. The Fall and Rise of Development Economics. In Rethinking the Development Experience, ed. L. Rodwin and D.A. Schőm, 39–59. Washington, DC: The Brookings Institution and The Lincoln Institute of Land Policy.

    Google Scholar 

  • Leamer, E. 2007. A Flat World, a Level Playing Field, a Small World After All, or None of the Above? A Review of Thomas L. Friedman’s the World is Flat. Journal of Economic Literature 45 (1): 83–126.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lederman, D., and W.F. Maloney. 2006. Natural Resources Neither Curse Nor Destiny. Washington, DC: World Bank; Palo Alto: Stanford University Press. © World Bank. https://openknowledge.worldbank.org/handle/10986/7183.

  • Lee, K., and F. Malerba. 2017. Catch-up Cycles and Changes in Industrial Leadership: Windows of Opportunity and Responses for Firms and Countries in the Evolution of Sectoral Systems. Research Policy 46 (2): 338–351.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lin, J.Y. 2012. New Structural Economics. A Framework for Rethinking Development and Policy. World Bank. http://siteresources.worldbank.org/DEC/Resources/84797-1104785060319/598886-1104951889260/NSE-Book.pdf.

  • Lundahl, M. 2005. To Be an Independent Thinker: An Intellectual Portrait of StaffanBurenstam Linder. The European Journal of the History of Economic Thought 12 (4): 663–688. https://doi.org/10.1080/09672560500370375.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Marcolin, L., S. Miroudot, and M. Squicciarini. 2016. Routine Jobs, Employment and Technological Innovation in Global Value Chains. OECD Science, Technology and Industry Working Papers, 2016/01. Paris: OECD Publishing. https://doi.org/10.1787/5jm5dcz2d26j-en.

  • Marin, A. and L. Stubrin. 2015. Innovation in Natural Resources: New Opportunities and New Challenges. The Case of the Argentinian Seed Industry. Innovation 2015(31): 015. http://www.merit.unu.edu/publications/wppdf/2015/wp2015-015.pdf.

  • Matsuyama, K. 2009. Structural Change in an Interdependent World: A Global View of Manufacturing Decline. Journal of the European Economic Association 7 (2–3): 478–486.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mehlum, H., K. Moene, and R. Torvik. 2006. Institutions and the Resource Curse. The Economic Journal 116 (508): 1–20.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Meliciani, V., and M. Savona. 2014. The Determinants of Regional Specialisation in Business Services. Agglomeration Economies, Vertical Linkages and Innovation. Journal of Economic Geography 15 (2): 387–416.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Milberg, W., and D. Winkler. 2011. Economic and Social Upgrading in Global Production Network: Problems of Theory and Measurement. International Labour Review 150 (3–4): 341–365.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Milberg, W., and D. Winkler. 2013. Outsourcing Economics. Global Value Chains in Capitalist Development. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Miroudot, S., and C. Cadestin. 2017. Services in Global Value Chains: From Inputs to Value Creating Activities. OECD Trade Policy Papers 197. OECD Publishing.

  • OECD. 2007. Offshoring and Employment: Trends and Impact. Paris: OECD Publishing.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • OECD. 2013. Interconnected Economies: Benefiting from Global Value Chains. Synthesis Report. https://doi.org/10.1787/9789264189560-en.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • OECD. 2019. Guide to OECD’s Trade in Value Added (TiVA) Indicators, 2018 edition. Paris: OECD Publishing.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ottaviano, G. 2015. Offshoring and the Migration of Jobs. IZA World of Labor, 170.

  • Palma, G. 2005. Four Sources of “De-industrialization” and a New Concept of the “Dutch Disease.” In Beyond Reforms: Structural Dynamics and Macroeconomic Vulnerability, ed. J. Ocampo, 71–116. Palo Alto: Stanford University Press and The World Bank.

    Google Scholar 

  • Prebisch, R. 1950. The Economic Development of Latin America and Its Principal Problems. New York: United Nations Department of Economic Affairs, Economic Commission for Latin America (ECLA). http://archivo.cepal.org/pdfs/cdPrebisch/002.pdf.

  • Rodrik, D. 2015. Premature Deindustrialization. NBER Working Paper, No. 20935. http://www.nber.org/papers/w20935.

  • Rodrik, D. 2016. Premature Deindustrialization. Journal of Economic Growth 21 (1): 1–33.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rodrik, D. 2018. New Technologies, Global Value Chains, and the Developing Economies. Pathways for Prosperity Commission Background Paper Series, No. 1. Oxford.

  • Rosenstein-Rodan, P. 1943. Problems of Industrialisation of Eastern and South-Eastern Europe. The Economic Journal 53 (210–211): 202–211.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sachs, J.D., and A.M. Warner. 1995. Natural Resource Abundance and Economic Growth. NBER Working Paper Series, 5398.

  • Sachs, J.D., and A.M. Warner. 1999. The Big Rush, Natural Resource Booms and Growth. Journal of Development Economics 59 (1): 43–76.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schmitz, H., and S. Strambach. 2009. The Organisational Decomposition of Innovation and Global Distribution of Innovative Activities: Insights and Research Agenda. International Journal of Technological Learning, Innovation and Development 2 (4): 231. https://doi.org/10.1504/IJTLID.2009.026816.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Simonazzi, A., A. Ginzburg, and G. Nocella. 2013. Economic Relations Between Germany and Southern Europe. Cambridge Journal of Economics 37 (3): 653–675.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stiglitz, J.E., J.Y. Lin, and C. Monga. 2013. The Rejuvenation of Industrial Policy. Policy Research Working Paper 6628.

  • Timmer, M., B. Los, R. Stehrer, and G. de Vries. 2012. Slicing Up Global Value Chains. In Paper Presented at: Latin America’s Prospects for Upgrading in Global Value Chain, Mexico City, 1–38.

  • Timmer, M. 2013. Fragmentations, Income and Jobs: An Analysis of European Competitiveness. Economic Policy 20 (October): 613–661.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Torvik, R. 2001. Learning by Doing and the Dutch Disease. European Economic Review 45 (2): 285–306.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tregenna, F. 2011. Manufacturing Productivity, Deindustrialization, and Reindustrialization. UNU-WIDER Research Paper No. 2011/57. World Institute for Development Economic Research.

  • Urzúa, O. 2012. Emergence and Development of Knowledge Intensive Mining Services (KIMS). Working Papers in Technology Governance and Economic Dynamics, No. 41.

  • Venables, A.J. 2016. Using Natural Resources for Development: Why Has It Proven So Difficult? Journal of Economic Perspectives 30 (1): 161–184.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Vernon, R. 1979. The Product Cycle Hypothesis in an International Environment. Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics 41 (4): 255–267. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1468-0084.1979.mp41004002.x.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Vona, F., and D. Consoli. 2014. Innovation and Skill Dynamics: A Life-Cycle Approach. Industrial and Corporate Change. https://doi.org/10.1093/icc/dtu028.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Westkämper, E. 2014. Towards the Re-industrialization of Europe: A Concept for Manufacturing for 2030. Stuttgart: Springer.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Winkler, D. 2009. Services Offshoring and Its Impact on the Labour Market: Theoretical Insights, Empirical Evidence and Policy Recommendations. Heidelberg: Springer.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Winkler, D. 2010. Services Offshoring and Its Impact on Productivity and Employment: Evidence from Germany, 1995–2006. The World Economy. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1467-9701.2010.01269.x.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Maria Savona.

Ethics declarations

Conflict of interest

The author has no conflicts of interest to declare.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

This paper builds upon an earlier contribution titled “Global Structural Change and Value Chains in Services. A Reappraisal.” SPRU Working Paper Series (SWPS), 2015–19: 1–29. ISSN 2057-6668, by systematizing and articulating the background theory and empirics of the Hirschman–Linder hypothesis, empirically tested in López-Gonzalez et al. (2019) and Bontadini and Savona (2019). The author is grateful to the co-authors (Javier Lòpez-Gonzalez, Valentina Meliciani and Filippo Bontadini) for the lengthy and constructive discussions on the HLH. The author also wishes to thank two anonymous referees for the very constructive comments and the Guest Editors of this Special Issue for their excellent remarks.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Savona, M. Revisiting High Development Theory to Explain Upgrading Prospects in Business Services Global Value Chains. Eur J Dev Res 33, 206–226 (2021). https://doi.org/10.1057/s41287-021-00366-4

Download citation

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1057/s41287-021-00366-4

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation