Skip to main content
Log in

How fractionalisation and polarisation explain the level of government turn-over

  • Original Article
  • Published:
Acta Politica Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This article seeks to explain to what extent government composition changes in cabinet formations: it examines why some party systems tend to see wholesale turn-over (where all government parties were previously in opposition) and others only see partial turn-over (where some of the government parties were previously in government). This distinction has been described by many prominent political scientists. Yet there is limited research into the underlying causes. This article examines the importance of both party system characteristics and conditions specific to the cabinet formation: it finds that specifically the interaction between number of parties in a party system and their distribution over the political space matters for the level of party turn-over in government.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. An alternative understanding of government turn-over is ideological alternation. This has been used by Tsebelis (2002), Tsebelis and Chang (2002), Zucchini (2010) and Angelova (2017). These measures compare the ideological ideal points of successive cabinets. As two successive cabinets are further apart ideological alternation is greater. This is substantially different from the measure examined in this article as it concerns the ideological distance between cabinets, while this article looks changes in partisan composition. A government turn-over and an ideological alternation measure are conceptually and empirically different: when two centrist parties alternate in office, the government turn-over measure see this as wholesale alternation, while an ideological alternation measure sees very limited change. If a party makes a major ideological transition while it continues in government, when it switches prime ministers, an ideological alternation measure sees a marked change, while there would be zero turn-over in terms of government turn-over measure. These two variables speak to different theoretical questions: ideological alternation is a useful explanatory variable for those trying to explain changes in government policies, while government turn-over, as we will argue in greater detail in the conclusion maybe of more interest to those would want to study the performance of democracy institutions in terms of accountability for instance. The Appendix examines the relevance of the hypotheses formulated in this paper for this kind of alternation, they indicate that polarisation has direct effect on ideological alternation, while fractionalisation does not. The direct effect of polarisation is reasonable: when parties are not polarised, there cannot be a large difference between the ideal points of governments. This shows that this is a substantially different phenomenon.

  2. Lundell (2011) offers a different argument for the same phenomenon. He draws on Sartori (1976) to argue that systems with differing numbers of political parties have different patterns of turn-over: two-party and moderate pluralist systems tend to see wholesale turn-over. Systems with higher levels of pluralism, what Sartori (1976) has characterised as polarised pluralism, see more partial turn-over. He argues that 'since these systems usually consists of the bilateral opposition of highly ideological parties and anti-system parties, the number of potential governing parties becomes smaller' (Lundell 2011, p. 151). The number of parties and polarisation are not the same (the Pearson’s r between polarisation and the ENPP in this data set is 0.14, significant at the 0.01-level). It might be the case that systems with a high number of parties have anti-systems parties that can never participate in the government, but this is not necessarily the case: post-Cold War Finland, for instance, has consistently had a high effective number of parties but no anti-system opposition.

  3. For instance, consider the French 1993 elections in which the RPR and UDF won a 82% majority in the Assemblée Nationale with 40% of the votes. There a Government–Opposition Differential measure based on seats would give them a comfortable + 0.66, while the Government–Opposition Differential measure based on votes is − 0.20. Such a comfortable majority in seats can be beaten in the electoral arena, as the PS, PCF, LV and allies showed in the 1997 elections, winning the elections by expanding their votes with only 7%. One should note that in systems with disproportional electoral systems a party can win a majority of the seats despite having a minority of the vote. So a score of − 0.20 puts the RPR/UDF cabinet on the same level as the minority cabinet in a proportional electoral system where the opposition parties only need to band together in parliament to replace the government. So where the Government–Opposition Differential measure based on seats overestimates how difficult it is to change the change the government, the Government–Opposition Differential measure based on votes is likely to overestimate how easy it is to replace the government. Government–Opposition Differential measure based on seats is considered in the Appendix and yields generally similar results. The suggestion to examine vote share was gratefully taken over from one of the anonymous reviewers.

  4. The Appendix shows that cases of zero change are not only conceptually and theoretically different from the different kinds of cases that have some change, but also empirically different: if one were to include all cases (including those in which there was no turn-over), the same substantive patterns are not present, in particular the relations with fractionalisation and polarisation are no longer present. The explanation for this is while a larger effective number of parties weakens the level of government turn-over, it appears to be the case that the effective number of political parties strengthens the likelihood of any change in government composition opposed to no change in government composition. Together these two tendencies cancel out any substantive effect of fractionalisation (including the interaction effect). A ‘zero-inflated’ model shows that the mechanism that supplies the zero values and the other values is indeed empirically different. The interaction between fractionalisation and polarisation matters for the other values but does not matter for the zero values, which are predicted mainly by electoral volatility and whether the government was the first formed after elections.

  5. Beta regression requires data to be bounded between 0 and 1. Therefore the value 1 was assigned the highest possible value that Beta regression could still deal with (0.9999).

  6. Figure 3 in the Appendix provides an alternative visualisation, it supports the same substantive conclusion.

References

  • Angelova, M.H. Bäck, W.C. Müller, and D. Strobl. 2017. Veto Player Theory and Reform Making in Western Europe. European Journal of Political Research published online ahead of print.

  • Anthonsen, M., and J. Lindvall. 2009. Party Competition and the Resilience of Corporatism. Government and Opposition 44 (2): 167–187.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bakker, R., C. De Vries, E. Edwards, L. Hooghe, S. Jolly, G. Marks, J. Polk, J. Rovny, M. Steenbergen, and M. Vachudova. 2015. Measuring Party Positions in Europe: The Chapel Hill Expert Survey Trend File 1999–2010. Party Politics 21 (1): 143–152.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bale, T. 2003. Cinderella and Her Ugly Sisters: The Mainstream and The Extreme Right in Europe’s Bipolarising Party System. West European Politics 26 (3): 67–90.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Benoit, K., and M. Laver. 2006. Party Policy in Modern Democracies. London: Routledge.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Buis, M.L., N.J. Cox, and S.P. Jenkins. 2011. Betafit.

  • Casal Bértoa, F., and Z. Enyedi. 2014. Party System Closure and Openness: Conceptualization, Operationalization and Validation. Party Politics. https://doi.org/10.1177/1354068814549340.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Castles, F.G., and P. Mair. 1984. Left-Right Political Scales: Some Expert Judgments. European Journal of Political Research 12 (1): 73–88.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cheibub, J.A., J. Gandhi, and J.R. Vreeland. 2009. Democracy and Dictatorship Revisited. Public Choice 143 (1–2): 67–101.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dalton, R.J. 2008. The Quantity and Quality of Party Systems. Party System Polarization, its Measurement, and its Consequences. Comparative Political Studies 41 (7): 899–920.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • De Giorgi, E., and F. Marangoni. 2015. Government Laws and Opposition Parties’ Behaviour in Parliament. Acta Politica 50: 64–81.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • De Swaan, A. 1973. Coalition Theories and Coalition Formations. PhD-thesis: University of Amsterdam, Amsterdam.

  • Döring, H., and P. Manow. 2016. Parliament and Government Composition Database (ParlGov). An Infrastructure for Empirical Information on Parties, Elections and Governments in Modern Democracies.

  • Dumont, P., L. De Winter, and R.B. Andeweg. 2011. From Coalition Theory to Coalition Puzzles. In Puzzles of Government Formation. Coalition Theory and Deviant Cases, eds. Andeweg, R.B., De Winter, L. and Dumont, P., 1–15, Abingdon: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Green-Pedersen, C. 2002. The Politics of Justification. Party Competition and Welfare-State Retrenchment in Denmark and the Netherlands from 1982 to 1988. Amsterdam: Amsterdam University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Green-Pedersen, C. 2004. The Implosion of Party Systems: A Study of Centripetal Tendencies in Multiparty Systems. Political Studies 52 (2): 324–341.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hooghe, L., R. Bakker, A. Brigevich, C. De Vries, E. Edwards, G. Marks, J. Rovny, M. Steenbergen, and M. Vachudova. 2010. Reliability and Validity of Measuring Party Positions: The Chapel Hill Expert Surveys of 2002 and 2006. European Journal of Political Research 49 (4): 684–703.

    Google Scholar 

  • Huber, J., and R. Inglehart. 1995. Expert Interpretations of Party Space and Party Locations in 42 Societies. Party Politics 1 (1): 73–111.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ieraci, G. 2012. Government Alternation and Patterns of Competition in Europe: Comparative Data in Search of Explanations. West European Politics 35 (3): 530–550.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kaiser, A., M. Lehnert, B. Miller, and U. Sieberer. 2002. The Democratic Quality of Institutional Regimes: A Conceptual Framework. Political Studies 50 (2): 313–331.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Laver, M. 1998. Models of Government Formation. Annual Review of Political Science 1 (1): 1–25.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Laver, M., and N. Schofield. 1990. Multiparty Government. The Politics of Coalition in Europe. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Laakso, M., and R. Taagepera. 1979. ‘Effective’ Number of Parties: A Measure with Application to West Europe. Comparative Political Studies 12 (1): 3–27.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Leiserson, M.A. 1966. Coalitions in Politics: A Theoretical and Empirical Study. PhD-thesis, New Haven, Yale University.

  • Lijphart, A. 1999. Patterns of Democracy. Government Forms and Performance in Thirty-Six Countries. New Haven: Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Louwerse, T., S. Otjes, D.M. Willumsen, and P. Öhberg. 2016. Reaching Across the Aisle Explaining Government–Opposition Voting in Parliament. Party Politics. https://doi.org/10.1177/1354068815626000.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lundell, K. 2011. Accountability and Patterns of Alternation in Pluralitarian, Majoritarian and Consensus Democracies. Government and Opposition 46 (2): 145–167.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mair, P. 1997. Party System Change: Approaches and Interpretations. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mair, P. 2001. The Green Challenge and Political Competition: How Typical is the German Experience? German Politics 10 (2): 99–116.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mair, P. 2008. Electoral Volatility and the Dutch Party System: A Comparative Perspective. Acta Politica 43 (2–3): 235–253.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Martin, L.W., and R.T. Stevenson. 2001. Government Formation in Parliamentary Democracies. American Journal of Political Science 45 (1): 33–50.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Meyer-Sahling, J.H., and T. Veen. 2012. Governing the Post-communist State: Government Alternation and Senior Civil Service Politicisation in Central and Eastern Europe. East European Politics 28 (1): 4–22.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Otjes, S., and A. Rasmussen. 2015. Collaboration Between Interest Groups and Political Parties in Multi-party Democracies: Party System Dynamics and the Effect of Power and Ideology. Party Politics, online first.. https://doi.org/10.1177/1354068814568046.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pedersen, M.N. 1979. Electoral Volatility in Western Europe, 1948-1977. European Journal of Political Research 7 (1): 1–26.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rokkan, S. 1970. Citizens, Elections, Parties. Oslo: Universitetsforlaget.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rose, R., and T.T. Mackie. 1983. Incumbency in Government: Asset or Liability? In Western European Party Systems: Continuity and Change, ed. H. Daalder and P. Mair, 115–137. London: Sage.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sartori, G. 1976. Parties and Party Systems: A Framework for Analysis. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Steenbergen, M., and G. Marks. 2007. Evaluating Expert Judgments. European Journal of Political Research 46 (3): 347–366.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Strøm, K. 1990. Minority Government and Majority Rule. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Strøm, K., and T. Bergman. 2011. Parliamentary Democracy under Siege. In The Madisonian Turn, ed. T. Bergman and K. Strøm, 3–35. Political Parties and Parliamentary Democracy in Nordic Europe: University of Michigan Press, Ann Arbour.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Tsebelis, G. 2002. Veto Players: How Political Institutions Work. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Tsebelis, G., and E.C. Chang. 2002. Veto Players and the Structure of Budgets in Advanced Industrialized Countries. European Journal of Political Research 43 (3): 449–476.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Verzichelli, L., and M. Cotta. 1999. Italy: From ‘Constrained’ Coalitions to Alternating Governments? In Coalition Governments in Western Europe, ed. S. Müller and K. Strøm. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Zucchini, F. 2010. Government Alternation and Legislative Agenda Setting. European Journal of Political Research 50 (6): 749–774.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Simon Otjes.

Appendix

Appendix

This Appendix examines four issues:

  1. (1)

    a different visualisation of the main interaction relationship (see footnote 6 in the article);

  2. (2)

    an alternative operationalisation of the Government–Opposition Vote Differential (see footnote 3 in the article);

  3. (3)

    an alternative operationalisation of the GTI (see footnote 4);

  4. (4)

    and an alternative operationalisation of turn-over that incorporates the ideological difference between the government and the opposition (see footnote 1).

First, we examine Fig. 3 in Appendix. It shows the marginal effect of polarisation on the GTI for increasing effective numbers of political parties. It supports the same substantive conclusion as Fig. 2 in the paper: when the effective number of political parties is low, polarisation has a significant negative effect on the Government Turn-over Index. In the mid-range there is no significant effect of polarisation. When the number of political parties is high, polarisation positively affects the Government Turn-over Index. This effect becomes significant when the effective number of political parties is greater than seven. Substantially, the conclusions are the same as those described in the paper, although the level of uncertainty is greater for these marginal effects.

Fig. 3
figure 3

Marginal effect of polarisation as the effective number of political parties increases. Based on Model 1 in Table 3 (in the article)

Second, we examine the Government–Opposition Seat Differential. Where the Government–Opposition Vote Differential looks at the difference in votes between the previous government and opposition, this measure looks at their seats.

$$\Delta_{s} = \mathop \sum \limits_{i = 1}^{n} S_{i,t - 1} \cdot G_{i, t - 1} - \mathop \sum \limits_{i = 1}^{n} S_{i,t - 1} \cdot (1 - G_{i, t - 1} )$$
(A.1)

where Si,t−1 is the share of the seats the respective party got in the previous election.

Models 1, 2 and 3 in Table 4 in Appendix show the results. They are quite similar to those in Table 3 (in the paper). As shown in Models 1 and 2, there is a significant effect of the effective number of parties on the level of government turn-over in the model without and with polarisation. As Model 2 shows, polarisation in itself does not affect the level of alternation. The coefficients for the interaction are almost identical (and statistically indistinguishable) to those in Model 3 in Table 3 (in the paper). The key differences are in the size of the effect of the government–opposition differential; the seat differential (Δs) appears to have a weaker effect than the vote differential (Δv). At the same time, electoral volatility has a stronger effect in these models than in the paper. It seems likely that the vote differential (Δv) picks up on some of the variance that in the Models in Table 3 Electoral Volatility picked up. All in all, the alternative operationalisation of the Government–Opposition Differential does not markedly change the conclusions.

Table 4 Alternative operationalisations (beta and logistic regressions)

Next, we examine an alternative operationalisation of the dependent variable, the GTI. In the paper, all cases where the government composition did not change (where the GTI was zero) were excluded from the analysis. The reason for this is that the expectations that apply to different levels of government turn-over does not apply to why government stay in power. Models 4, 5 and 6 look at GTIAll, that is at alternative operationalisation, which does not exclude the cases where GTI did not change. This more than doubles the number of cases. This means that a large share of the variance is between the cases where there is no change and where there is some change. These analyses support the expectation that different patterns apply here: only the Post-election Dichotomy and Electoral Volatility have significant effects in Models 4, 5 and 6: the higher the electoral volatility the higher government turn-over is and the government formed after an election have a higher level of government turn-over, compared to governments formed during the term (which includes government change where for instance only the PM changes). The key variables of the paper (polarisation and its interaction with fractionalisation) do not affect this new variable at all. Model 7 provides an explanation for this pattern. It looks at GTIAny, that is a measure that looks at whether there is any kind of alternation for all cases. In other words, it checks whether the GTIAll is equal to zero, if it has, it has value zero, if not, it has value one. These results are strikingly similar to those for GTIAll. Note that here logistic regression is employed so the coefficients are not directly comparable to other models presented in the paper or the appendix: here we also find significant effects for the Post-election Dichotomy and Electoral Volatility. What is also interesting is that there is a positive effect for fractionalisation, which is significant in Model 7. This implies that government turn-over at all is more likely in multiparty systems as opposed to two-party systems, while in the paper the finding is that fractionalisation leads to lower levels of government turn-over (in terms of the GTI). In two-party systems if there is alternation, which is marginally less likely than in multiparty systems, it is wholesale alternation, while in multiparty systems alternation occurs more often but then it is partial alternation. Wholesale alternation is the only option two-party systems, but it requires a change in the composition of parliament, while partial alternation can occur in a multiparty system if one junior government party is traded in for the other. Combining these results explain why in Model 4 fractionalisation has no effect on the GTIAll. Models 8 and 9 also show no effect of polarisation (other than reducing the N and weakening the effect of fractionalisation), which means that change of government is not more likely to occur in systems where parties stand far apart.

It appears to be the case that while the hypotheses discussed in the paper can explain the variance between 0.01 and 1, it cannot explain cases where the GTIall is zero. There appears to be a different mechanism beneath the zero values and the other values. A zero-inflated negative binomial model is specifically meant for a situation where the theoretical mechanism beneath the generation of the zero values is different from the mechanism that generates the other values and where the distribution of the other values is not normal. There is one drawback, however, is that it is not meant for values bounded between zero and one. We address this by multiplying GTIAll with 10 into GTI10. Models 10, 11 and 12 (in Table 5 in Appendix) show clearly that the mechanisms behind the generation of the zero values (lower half) and the other values (upper half) is different. Note that the signs in the lower half of the table are flipped compared to Models 7, 8 and 9, because it now predicts whether the value is zero: it decreases the likelihood of both non-alternation and wholesale alternation. Model 10 shows the same pattern for fractionalisation we observed above. The models indicate that electoral volatility makes non-alternation less likely: when the distribution of seats is similar to the outcome where the previous government was formed, it staying in power is more likely. Changing a government just after elections also makes non-alternation less likely: the only time non-alternation is picked up as a government changes is after elections. The mechanism for non-zero values shown in Table 5 in Appendix completely conforms to findings elsewhere in the paper, including the significant interaction between polarisation and the effective number of political parties.

Table 5 Alternative operationalisations (zero-inflated negative binomial regressions)
Table 6 Alternative operationalisations (OLS regressions)

Finally, we look at an alternative way to approach alternation, namely by looking at the ideological distance between the current and the previous government. The IA, which is employed by Tsebelis (2002), Tsebelis and Chang (2002) and Zucchini (2010), looks at the absolute difference between the ideological position of governments on basis of the average position of their most extreme parties in the government:

$$IA = \left| {\frac{{\hbox{max} \left( {LR_{G,t} } \right) - \hbox{min} \left( {{\text{LR}}_{G,t} } \right)}}{2} - \frac{{\hbox{max} \left( {LR_{G,t - 1} } \right) - \hbox{min} \left( {{\text{LR}}_{G,t - 1} } \right)}}{2}} \right|,$$
(A.2)

where LRG is the set of left right positions of the parties in government (at t and t − 1). The seat-weighted IA is the same idea but it looks at the average position of all parties in the government, weighted by their seat total. In terms of the variables introduced in the paper,

$$IA_{sw} = \left| {\frac{{\mathop \sum \nolimits_{i = 1}^{n} S_{i,t} \cdot LR_{i,t} \cdot G_{i, t} }}{{\mathop \sum \nolimits_{i = 1}^{n} S_{i,t} \cdot G_{i, t} }} - \frac{{\mathop \sum \nolimits_{i = 1}^{n} S_{i,t - 1} \cdot LR_{i,t - 1} \cdot G_{i, t - 1} }}{{\mathop \sum \nolimits_{i = 1}^{n} S_{i,t - 1} \cdot G_{i, t - 1} }}} \right|.$$
(A.3)

This is another way of thinking about government turn-over. In the theory section, we essentially considered four cases:

  1. (1)

    when polarisation is high and the number of parties is high, the GTI would be high;

  2. (2)

    when polarisation is low and the number of parties is high, the GTI would be low;

  3. (3)

    when polarisation is high and the number of parties is low, the GTI would be high;

  4. (4)

    and when polarisation is low and the number of parties is low, the GTI would be high.

The expectation would need to be different for situation four when it comes to IA and the IAsw: if polarisation is low, the IA cannot be high, because the government would be formed by the parties that, given the polarisation, stand close together. Consider the situation in Malta where the Labour Party and the National Party are very close together and therefore the polarisation is very low. In this situation one cannot expect a high IA, while one can expect a high GTI. There is no sound basis to expect an interaction relationship, it is still included in the model for consistency’s sake.

The analyses for the IA and IAsw (Table 6 in Appendix) support broadly the same conclusions: ideological alternation is higher when a government is formed after an election (as opposed to during the parliament’s term), when Government–Opposition Vote Differential is lower and when electoral volatility is higher. As expected but contrary to the findings for the GTI, polarisation has a strong direct effect on the level of ideological alternation and the effective number of parties does not affect the level of ideological alternation. The interaction for the IAsw is visualised in Fig. 4 in Appendix. It shows that at low levels of fractionalisation, low polarisation is associated with low levels of ideological alternation; while for the same levels of fractionalisation, high polarisation is associated with high levels of polarisation are associated with high levels of ideological alternation. When the number of parties becomes higher the uncertainty becomes such that the two are no longer distinguishable. That is when the number of parties is high the polarisation matters less, contrary to the pattern for the GTI.

Fig. 4
figure 4

Seat-weighted ideological alternation as a function of the effective number of parliamentary parties at different levels of polarisation. Notes Black lines are the predicted level of alternation for different effective numbers of parliamentary parties for non-polarised systems (Polarisation at 0.23) and the grey lines are the predicted level of alternation for different levels of the effective numbers of parliamentary parties for polarised systems (Polarisation at 7.35). Based on Model 12 in Table 6 in Appendix. The dashed lines are 90% confidence intervals

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Otjes, S. How fractionalisation and polarisation explain the level of government turn-over. Acta Polit 55, 41–66 (2020). https://doi.org/10.1057/s41269-018-0098-9

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1057/s41269-018-0098-9

Keywords

Navigation