Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Home market effect, land rent, and welfare

  • Spatial Analysis and Modeling
  • Published:
Asia-Pacific Journal of Regional Science Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper develops a general-equilibrium model which features the Home Market Effect and land use for production in the sector of increasing returns to scale. The land rent in the larger region is higher. Meanwhile, the larger region holds a more-than-proportionate share of firms, the so called HME in terms of firm share. These two aspects of spatial inequalities are shown to be equivalent. Moreover, the industrial distribution in the larger region and the land rent differential form bell-shaped patterns in economic integration. We demonstrate that the welfare in the larger region is higher and both regions may benefit from trade liberalization.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. It was then empirically tested by Wang and Xu (2015) using Chinese panel data 1980–2012.

  2. See Gaspar (2018) for a more complete review.

  3. Source: Statistisches Bundesamt 2008, http://www.destatis.de.

  4. Nevertheless, land actually has been included as production factor in addition to labor in constant returns sector in trade literature: Leamer (1984), Fujita and Krugman (1995) and Puga (1999), ect., and in urban economics: Fujita and Ogawa (1982) and Lucas and Rossi-Hansberg (2002), to name a few.

  5. Source from European Quarterly, 2017,http://www.knightfrank.co.uk.

  6. The assumption of mobile capital and immobile labor origins from Martin and Rogers (1995). Immobile labor is also assumed in a number of regional studies including, e.g., Baldwin and Okubo (2006) and Ottaviano and Thisse (2004).

  7. Land use only for consumption (housing) is considered by Helpman (1998), showing that agglomeration of economic activity is strongest at high trade costs, successively lower as trade costs are reduced and completely dispersed when trade costs are low enough. If land use for both consumption and production is considered, as in PT, for limited range of parameters, a bell-shaped curve emerges.

  8. The land is assumed to be equally owned by jurisdictional residents in this paper. In some of the literature, land is owned by absentee landlords (e.g., Tabuchi 1998), which are criticized by PT on the grounds that it is not a general equilibrium one.

  9. Strictly speaking, in the short-run, the capital income in region i should be \(K \lambda _i [c_i r_i+(1-c_i) r_j]\) where \(c_i\) is the share of capital employed domestically. However, since the capital return rate equals in equilibrium, we denote it as \(r_i\) to simplify the notation.

  10. The Cobb–Douglas function is used in, e.g., Beckman (1972) and Lucas and Rossi-Hansberg (2002) in which land is a variable factor and enters the variable costs along with labor. For the cases of land use in the IRS sector, WY assume a variable input of Cobb–Douglas composite of land and labor. PT allow land to enter not only the variable costs, but also the fixed costs. Wrede (2013) assumes land enters the production along with labor and intermediate good in Cobb–Douglas form.

  11. Alternatively, we can also assume a Leontief production technology which combines labor and land as inputs. However, adoption of such assumption does not change our main results on the role of land use in manufacturing production and its impacts on industrial agglomeration and welfare, but makes the expressions complicated. To keep the model simple but without loss of intuitions, we focus on land use in manufacturing and treat the homogeneous good production technology as simple as possible.

  12. By normalizing the units of capital and land, we let \(K=S=L\) to reduce the mathematical expressions. Please note that the normalizations in the Dixit–Stiglitz sector do not reduce the generalities of the model (See Baldwin et al. 2003, Chapter 2, p. 14).

References

  • Amiti M (1998) Inter-industry trade in manufactures: does country size matter? J Int Econ 44(2):231–255

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baldwin RE, Okubo T (2006) Heterogeneous firms, agglomeration and economic geography: spatial selection and sorting. J Econ Geogr 6:323–346

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baldwin RE, Forslid R, Martin P, Ottaviano GIP, Robert-Nicoud F (2003) Economic geography and public policy. Princeton University Press, Princeton

    Google Scholar 

  • Beckman MJ (1972) Von Thunen revisited: a neoclassical land use model. Swed J Econ 74:1–7

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chen C, Zeng D-Z (2018) Mobile capital, variable elasticity of substitution, and trade liberalization. J Econ Geogr 18(2):461–494

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Crozet M, Trionfetti F (2008) Trade costs and the home market effect. J Int Econ 67:309–321

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Davis D (1998) The home market, trade, and industrial structure. Am Econ Rev 88:1264–1276

    Google Scholar 

  • Forslid R, Ottaviano GIP (2003) An analytically solvable core-periphery model. J Econ Geogr 3:229–240

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fujita M, Krugman P (1995) When is the economy monocentric? Von Thünen and Chamberlin unified. Reg Sci Urban Econ 25:505–528

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fujita M, Krugman P, Venables AJ (1999) The spatial economy: cities, regions, and international trade. The MIT Press, Cambridge

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Fujita M, Ogawa H (1982) Multiple equilibria and structural transition of non-monocentric urban configurations. Reg Sci Urban Econ 12:161–196

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gaspar JM (2018) A prospective review on new economic geography. Ann Reg Sci 61(2):237–272

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Head K, Mayer T (2004) Market potential and the location of Japanese investment in the European Union. Rev Econ Stat 86(4):959–972

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Head K, Mayer T (2006) Regional wage and employment responses to market potential in the EU. Reg Sci Urban Econ 36(5):573–594

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Helpman E (1998) The size of regions. In: Pines D, Sadka E, Zilcha I (eds) Topics in public economics. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, pp 33–54

    Google Scholar 

  • Helpman E, Krugman P (1985) Market structure and foreign trade. MIT Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Krugman P (1980) Sale economies, product differentiation, and the pattern of trade. Am Econ Rev 70:950–959

    Google Scholar 

  • Krugman P (1991) Increasing returns and economic geography. J Polit Econ 99:483–499

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Krugman P, Venables A (1990) Integration and the competitiveness of peripheral industry. In: Bliss C, de Macedo J (eds) Unity with diversity in the European economy: the community’s Southern frontier. Cambridge University Press, New York, pp 56–75

    Google Scholar 

  • Krugman P, Venables A (1995) Globalization and the inequality of nations. Q J Econ 11:857–880

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Laussel D, Paul T (2007) Trade and the location of industries: some new results. J Int Econ 71:148–166

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Leamer E (1984) Sources of international comparative advantage: theory and evidence. The MIT Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Lucas R, Rossi-Hansberg E (2002) On the internal structure of cities. Econometrica 70:1445–1476

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Martin P, Rogers CA (1995) Industrial location and public infrastructure. J Int Econ 39:335–351

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ottaviano GIP, Tabuchi T, Thisse J-F (2002) Agglomeration and trade revisited. Int Econ Rev 43:409–435

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ottaviano GIP, Thisse J-F (2004) Agglomeration and economic geography. In: Henderson JV, Thisse J-F (eds) Handbook of regional and urban economics 4, chapter 58. Elsevier, Amsterdam, pp 2563–2608

  • Pflüger M, Sudekum J (2008) Integration, agglomeration and welfare. J Urban Econ 63:544–566

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pflüger M, Tabuchi T (2010) The size of regions with land use for production. Reg Sci Urban Econ 40:481–489

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Picard P, Zeng D-Z (2005) Agricultural sector and industrial agglomeration. J Dev Econ 77:75–106

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Puga D, Venables A (1997) Preferential trading arrangements and industrial location. J Int Econ 43:347–368

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Puga D (1999) The rise and fall of regional inequalities. Eur Econ Rev 43:303–334

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tabuchi T (1998) Urban agglomeration and dispersion: a synthesis of Alonso and Krugman. J Urban Econ 44:333–351

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tabuchi T, Thisse J-F (2002) Taste heterogeneity, labor mobility and economic geography. J Dev Econ 69:155–177

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Takahashi T, Takatsuka H, Zeng D-Z (2013) Spatial inequality, globalization and footloose capital. Econ Theory 53:213–238

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Takatsuka H, Zeng D-Z (2012a) Trade liberalization and welfare: differentiated-good versus homogeneous-good markets. J Jpn Int Econ 26:308–325

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Takatsuka H, Zeng D-Z (2012b) Mobile capital and the home market effect. Can J Econ 45:1062–1082

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Samuelson P (1954) The transfer problem and transport costs, II: analysis of trade impediments. Econ J 64:264–289

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Suedekum J (2006) Agglomeration and regional costs of living. J Reg Sci 46(3):529–543

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Venables AJ (1996) Equilibrium location of vertically linked industries. Int Econ Rev 37:341–359

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • von Thünen JH (1826) Der Isolierte Staat in Beziehung auf Landwirtschaft und Nationalökonomie. Perthes, Hamburg [English translation (1966): The Isolated State. Oxford: Pergammon Press]

  • Wang J, Xu J (2015) Home market effect, spatial wages disparity: an empirical reinvestigation of China. Ann Reg Sci 55(2):313–333

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wang AM, Yang C (2013) The price effect on spatial structure: revisiting the new economic geography model. Spat Econ Anal 8(4):519–539

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Williamson J (1965) Regional inequality and the process of national development. Econ Dev Cult Change 14:3–45

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wrede M (2013) Heterogeneous skills and homogeneous land: segmentation and agglomeration. J Econ Geogr 13:767–798

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zhou Y (2017) Urban wage inequality and economic agglomeration. Ann Reg Sci 59(2):475–494

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zhou Y (2018) Spatial inequality and urban costs: revisiting the home market effect. J Reg Sci. https://doi.org/10.1002/jors.12414

Download references

Acknowledgements

The idea of studying the productive role of land in the IRS sector and its impacts on economic agglomeration was first generated during my doctoral study. The author is grateful to Asao Ando, Tatsuhito Kono, Dao-Zhi Zeng and other committee members. The author thanks the editor and two anonymous referees for helpful comments and suggestions. The usual caveat applies. Financial support from National Natural Science Foundation of China (71663023, 71773042, 71863011, 71863010) is acknowledged.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Yiming Zhou.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Appendices

Appendices

1.1 Appendix 1: Proof of Proposition 1

By dividing Eq. (6) with Eq. (7) and plugging Eqs. (1), (3), (5) and (11) into it, we derive an equation which can be defined as

$$\begin{aligned} \mathcal{F}_1(s_1, s_2, k, \phi )\equiv \mathcal{C}_2 \phi ^2+\mathcal{C}_1 \phi +\mathcal{C}_0=0, , \end{aligned}$$
(15)

where

$$\begin{aligned} \mathcal{C}_2&\equiv (s_1s_2)^{\beta (1-\sigma )-\gamma } \left[ (1-k) (1-\lambda )s_2^{\gamma } (1+r+s_2) -k \lambda s_1^{\gamma } (1+r+s_1) \right] ,\\ \mathcal{C}_1&\equiv (s_1s_2)^{-\gamma } (1+r+s_2+s_1 \lambda -s_2 \lambda )\left[ k s_1^{-2 \beta (\sigma -1)} s_2^{\gamma }-(1-k) s_2^{-2 \beta (\sigma -1)}s_1^{\gamma } \right] ,\\ \mathcal{C}_0&\equiv (s_1s_2)^{\beta (1-\sigma )-\gamma } \left[ (1-k) \lambda (1+r+s_1) s_2^{\gamma } -k(1-\lambda )s_1^{\gamma } (1+r+s_2)\right] , \end{aligned}$$

which is a quadratic function in \(\phi \). Remember that r is a linear function of \(s_1\) and \(s_2\), solved in Eq. (12). Meanwhile, we can solve N from Eqs. (8) and (9):

$$\begin{aligned} N=\frac{S}{[(\sigma -1)\beta +\gamma ]}+\left( \frac{\lambda }{r_1^{1-\gamma }s_1^{\gamma -1}}+\frac{1-\lambda }{r_2^{1-\gamma }s_2^{\gamma -1}} \right) . \end{aligned}$$

Plugging the expression of N together with Eqs. (11) and (12) into Eq. (10) generates another equation defined as

$$\begin{aligned} \mathcal{F}_2(s_1, s_2, k)\equiv s_1^{\gamma }k+s_2^{\gamma }(1-k)-\frac{ r[ (\sigma -1)\beta + \gamma ]}{(1-\gamma )\left[ (1-\lambda )s_2^{1-\gamma }+\lambda s_1^{1-\gamma }\right] }=0. \end{aligned}$$

On ther other hand, by dividing Eq. (8) by Eq. (9), we define

$$\begin{aligned} \mathcal{F}_3(s_1, s_2, k)\equiv \left( \frac{s_1}{s_2}\right) ^{1-\gamma }-\left( \frac{k}{1-k}\right) \Big /\left( \frac{\lambda }{1-\lambda }\right) =0. \end{aligned}$$

Three endogenous variables, \(s_1\), \(s_2\) and k, are implicitly determined by three equations \(\mathcal{F}_1(s_1, s_2, k, \phi )=0\), \(\mathcal{F}_2(s_1, s_2, k)=0\) and \(\mathcal{F}_3(s_1, s_2, k)=0\). At \(\phi =0\) and \(\phi =1\), we solve

$$\begin{aligned} s\equiv s_1=s_2=\frac{(1-\alpha ) [\gamma +\beta (\sigma -1)]}{(\sigma -1)(1-\beta )+\alpha [1+\beta (\sigma -1)]}, \quad k=\lambda . \end{aligned}$$

With these solutions, we derive

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial k}{\partial \phi }\biggr |_{\phi =0}=\frac{(2 \lambda -1)(1-\gamma ) \sigma }{\sigma -(1-\alpha ) \gamma -(1-\alpha ) \beta (\sigma -1)}>0 , \end{aligned}$$
(16)

and

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial k}{\partial \phi }\biggr |_{\phi =1}=-\frac{(1-\gamma ) (1-\lambda ) \lambda (2 \lambda -1)}{\gamma +\beta (\sigma -1)}<0, \end{aligned}$$
(17)

where the inequalities come from \(\sigma >1\), \(1>\gamma >0\), \(1>\alpha >0\) and \(1>\lambda >1/2.\)

For given k, variables \(s_1\) and \(s_2\) are simultaneously determined by \(\mathcal{F}_2(s_1, s_2, k)=0\) and \(\mathcal{F}_3(s_1, s_2, k)=0\). Note that the parameter \(\phi \) is independent of functions \(\mathcal{F}_2(s_1, s_2, k)\) and \(\mathcal{F}_3(s_1, s_2, k)\). For simplicity, we do not consider the possibility of multiple solutions. Therefore, we can rewrite equation \(\mathcal{F}_1(s_1, s_2, k, \phi )=0\) as \(\mathcal{F}_1(s_1(k), s_2(k), k, \phi )=0,\) which is a quadratic function in terms of \(\phi \). For any \(k^\sharp \), equation \(\mathcal{F}_1(s_1(k^\sharp ), s_2(k^\sharp ), k^\sharp ,\phi )=0\) has at most two solutions of \(\phi \). In the \(\phi \)-k plane, the curve \(k(\phi )\) crosses any horizontal line \(k=k^\sharp \) at most twice. Together with inequalities (16), (17) and \(k=\lambda \) at \(\phi =0\) and \(\phi =1\), we conclude that \(k>\lambda \) and \(k(\phi )\) evolves in a bell-shaped pattern in terms of \(\phi \in (0,1)\). \(\square \)

1.2 Appendix 2: Proof of Proposition 2

Differentiating \(s_1/s_2\) w.r.t. \(\phi \) generates

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial (s1/s2)}{\partial \phi }=\frac{\partial (s1/s2)}{\partial k}\frac{\partial k}{\partial \phi }. \end{aligned}$$

On the other hand, by Eq. (13), we have

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial (s1/s2)}{\partial k}=\frac{(s_1/s_2)^{\gamma } (1-\lambda )}{(1-k)^2 (1-\gamma ) \lambda }>0, \end{aligned}$$

where the inequality comes from \(\lambda <1\) and \(\gamma <1\). It implies that the sign of \(\partial (s_1/s_2)/\partial \phi \) is identical to that of \(\partial k/\partial \phi \). Because k evolves in a bell-shaped pattern in terms of \(\phi \), as shown by Appendix 1. Meanwhile, at \(\phi =0\) and \(\phi =1\), Appendix 1 indicates \(s_1/s_2=1\). Therefore, we have \(s_1/s_2>1\) and \(s_1/s_2\) evolves in a bell-shaped pattern in \(\phi \in (0,1)\).

On the other hand, by equations \(\mathcal{F}_1(s_1, s_2, k, \phi )=0\), \(\mathcal{F}_2(s_1, s_2, k)=0\) and \(\mathcal{F}_3(s_1, s_2, k)=0\), at \(\phi =0\), we solve

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial s_1}{\partial \phi }\biggr |_{\phi =0}&=\frac{\sigma (2 \lambda -1) s}{\lambda [\sigma -(1-\alpha ) \gamma -(1-\alpha ) \beta (\sigma -1)] }>0,\\ \frac{\partial s_2}{\partial \phi }\biggr |_{\phi =0}&=-\frac{\sigma (2 \lambda -1) s }{(1-\lambda ) [\sigma -(1-\alpha ) \gamma -(1-\alpha ) (\sigma -1)\beta ] }<0, \end{aligned}$$

whereas at \(\phi =1\), we have

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial s_1}{\partial \phi }\biggr |_{\phi =1}&=-\frac{(1-\alpha ) (1-\lambda ) (2 \lambda -1)}{(\sigma -1)(1-\beta )+\alpha [1+\beta (\sigma -1)]}<0,\\ \frac{\partial s_2}{\partial \phi }\biggr |_{\phi =1}&=\frac{(1-\alpha ) \lambda (2 \lambda -1)}{(\sigma -1)(1-\beta )+\alpha [1+\beta (\sigma -1)]}>0, \end{aligned}$$

where the inequalities above come from \(\alpha , \gamma , \beta \in (0,1)\), \(\lambda \in (1/2,1)\) and \(\sigma >1\).

Moreover, for given \(s_1\) (resp. \(s_2\)), variables \(s_2\) (resp. \(s_1\)) and k are simultaneously determined by \(\mathcal{F}_2(s_1, s_2, k)=0\) and \(\mathcal{F}_3(s_1, s_2, k)=0\). Note that the parameter \(\phi \) is independent of functions \(\mathcal{F}_2(s_1, s_2, k)\) and \(\mathcal{F}_3(s_1, s_2, k)\). Therefore, we can rewrite equation \(\mathcal{F}_1(s_1, s_2, k, \phi )=0\) as \(\mathcal{F}_1(s_1, s_2(s_1), k(s_1), \phi )=0\) (resp. \(\mathcal{F}_1(s_1(s_2), s_2, k(s_2), \phi )=0\)) which is a quadratic function in terms of \(\phi \). For any \(s_1^\sharp \) (resp. \(s_2^\sharp \)), equation \(\mathcal{F}_1(s_1^\sharp , s_2(s_1^\sharp ), k(s_1^\sharp ),\phi )=0\) (resp. \(\mathcal{F}_1(s_1(s_2^\sharp ), s_2^\sharp , k(s_2^\sharp ),\phi )=0\)) has at most two solutions of \(\phi \). In the \(\phi \)-\(s_1\) (resp. \(\phi \)-\(s_2\)) plane, the curve \(s_1(\phi )\) (resp. \(s_2(\phi )\)) crosses any horizontal line \(s_1=s_1^\sharp \) (resp. \(s_2=s_2^\sharp \)) at most twice. Together with inequalities \(\frac{\partial s_1}{\partial \phi }|_{\phi =0}>0\), \(\frac{\partial s_1}{\partial \phi }|_{\phi =1}<0\), \(\frac{\partial s_2}{\partial \phi }|_{\phi =0}<0\) and \(\frac{\partial s_2}{\partial \phi }|_{\phi =1}>0\), we conclude that \(s_1\) evolves in a bell-shaped pattern, while \(s_2\) evolves in a U-shaped pattern in \(\phi \in (0,1)\). \(\square \)

1.3 Appendix 3: Proof of Lemma 1

By Eq. (15), we have \(\mathcal{C}_2<0\) and \(\mathcal{C}_0<0\) where the first inequality comes from \(k>\lambda >1/2\) and \(s_1>s_2,\) while the second inequality is generated by using Eq. (13) and

$$\begin{aligned} (1-k) \lambda (1+r+s_1) s_2^{\gamma } -k(1-\lambda )s_1^{\gamma } (1+r+s_2)=-\lambda (1-k)s_2^{\gamma -1}(1+r) (s_1-s_2)<0. \end{aligned}$$

We therefore have

$$\begin{aligned} \mathcal{C}_1\equiv k s_1^{-2 \beta (\sigma -1)} s_2^{\gamma }-(1-k) s_2^{-2 \beta (\sigma -1)}s_1^{\gamma }>0, \quad {\text {and}}\quad k s_1^{-2 \beta (\sigma -1)}>(1-k) s_2^{-2 \beta (\sigma -1)}, \end{aligned}$$

where the second inequality comes from \(\mathcal{C}_1>0\) and \(s_2^{\gamma }<s_1^{\gamma }\). It further derives

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{k}{1-k}>\left( \frac{s_1}{s_2} \right) ^{2\beta (\sigma -1)}>\left( \frac{s_1}{s_2} \right) ^{\beta (\sigma -1)}, \end{aligned}$$

where the second inequality comes from \(s_1/s_2>1\). We therefore have \(k s_1^{(1-\sigma )\beta }>(1-k)s_2^{(1-\sigma )\beta }. \)\(\square \)

1.4 Appendix 4: Proof of Proposition 4

Lemma 1 implies that the price index in the larger region is lower. Meanwhile, individual income in the larger region is higher because \(r_1>r_2\). Therefore, the welfare in the larger region is always higher. On the other hand, with total differentiate \(\omega _i\) w.r.t. \(\phi \) at \(\phi =0\), we obtain

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial \omega _1}{\partial \phi }\biggr |_{\phi =0}&=\mathcal{J}\lambda ^{\left( \frac{1-\alpha }{\sigma -1}\right) }\left\{ \alpha (1-\lambda ) [\gamma +\beta (\sigma -1)]+\lambda [\sigma -\gamma -\beta (\sigma -1)]\right\} \cdot \frac{\partial s_1}{\partial \phi }\biggr |_{\phi =0}>0,\\ \frac{\partial \omega _2}{\partial \phi }\biggr |_{\phi =0}&=-\mathcal{J}(1-\lambda )^{\left( \frac{1-\alpha }{\sigma -1}\right) }\{ (\lambda +\alpha \lambda -1)[\gamma +\beta (\sigma -1)]+\sigma (1-\lambda )\} \cdot \frac{\partial s_2}{\partial \phi }\biggr |_{\phi =0}>0, \end{aligned}$$

where

$$\begin{aligned} \mathcal{J}\equiv \frac{(1-\alpha ) s^{-\beta (1-\alpha )}}{(\sigma -1)(2 \lambda -1) [\gamma +\beta (\sigma -1)] }\left\{ \frac{S (1-\gamma )^{(\gamma -1)}}{[\gamma +\beta (\sigma -1)]^{\gamma }}\right\} ^{\left( \frac{1-\alpha }{\sigma -1}\right) }>0. \end{aligned}$$

In particular, the second inequality comes from the fact that, if \(\lambda +\alpha \lambda -1<0\), we have

$$\begin{aligned} (\lambda +\alpha \lambda -1)(\gamma +\beta (\sigma -1))+\sigma (1-\lambda )&=\left[ (1-\lambda )-\gamma (1-\lambda -\alpha \lambda )\right] \\&\quad +(\sigma -1)\left[ (1-\lambda )-\beta (1-\lambda -\alpha \lambda )\right] \\&>\alpha \lambda +(\sigma -1)\alpha \lambda \\&>0.\end{aligned}$$

On the other hand, at \(\phi =1\), we have

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial \omega _1}{\partial \phi }\biggr |_{\phi =1}&=\frac{(1-\alpha ) (1-\lambda ) [2 \sigma (1-\lambda )+2\lambda -1]}{[\gamma +\beta (\sigma -1)] (\sigma -1)s^{\beta (1-\alpha )-1}} \\&\quad \times \left\{ \frac{S (1-\gamma )^{(\gamma -1)}}{[\gamma +\beta (\sigma -1)]^{\gamma }}\right\} ^{\left( \frac{1-\alpha }{\sigma -1}\right) }>0,\\ \frac{\partial \omega _2}{\partial \phi }\biggr |_{\phi =1}&=\frac{(1-\alpha )^2 \lambda [1+2 \lambda (\sigma -1)]}{(\sigma -1) [(\sigma -1)(1-\beta )+ \alpha +\alpha \beta (\sigma -1)]s^{\beta (1-\alpha )}} \\&\quad \times \left\{ \frac{S (1-\gamma )^{(\gamma -1)}}{[\gamma +\beta (\sigma -1)]^{\gamma }}\right\} ^{\left( \frac{1-\alpha }{\sigma -1}\right) }>0. \end{aligned}$$

\(\square \)

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Zhou, Y. Home market effect, land rent, and welfare. Asia-Pac J Reg Sci 3, 561–580 (2019). https://doi.org/10.1007/s41685-018-00103-6

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s41685-018-00103-6

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation