Skip to main content
Log in

Advertising Originality Decisions in Competition

  • Research Article
  • Published:
Customer Needs and Solutions Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Originality is a critical determinant of advertising success. However, firms frequently opt to launch unoriginal advertising campaigns. Why would firms opt for unoriginal ads when originality is considered as the “pinnacle”? In this paper, the authors investigate advertising originality decisions for market leaders and followers. They first establish empirically that unoriginal advertising, and more specifically copycat advertising, is a common option across diverse markets even for leading brands. Then, they develop an analytical framework to investigate the optimality of originality decisions. They model creative advertising themes as a “best-shot” type of public good, where a firm’s originality decision is influenced by market structure as well as market growth. The authors then examine whether a firm creates an original ad or opts for an unoriginal one, either by copycatting a competitor or by remaking an existing ad theme. The findings suggest that there is no oversupply of original ads. An original ad can be created by either the leading firm or its follower to boost the valuation of its loyal consumers and profit from higher prices or to attract switchers.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Owing to the proprietary nature of this report, we cannot disclose the name of the company.

  2. Creative costs include, but are not limited to, costs of contracting qualified advertising agencies, marketing research to measure competitive advertising effectiveness, searching for a concept, and copy-testing the effectiveness of different advertising ideas.

References

  1. Abernethy AM, Franke GR (1996) The information content of advertising: a meta-analysis. J Advert 25(2):1–17. https://doi.org/10.1080/00913367.1996.10673496

    Article  Google Scholar 

  2. Arden P (2003) It’s not how good you are, its how good you want to be. Phaidon Press, New York

    Google Scholar 

  3. Bass FM, Bruce N, Majumdar S, Murthi BPS (2007) Wearout effects of different advertising themes: a dynamic Bayesian model of the advertising-sales relationship. Mark Sci 26(2):179–195. https://doi.org/10.1287/mksc.1060.0208

    Article  Google Scholar 

  4. Batra R, Keller KL (2016) Integrating marketing communications: new findings, new lessons, and new ideas. J Mark 80(6):122–145

    Article  Google Scholar 

  5. Baye MR, Kovenock D, Devries CG (1992) It takes 2 to tango—equilibria in a model of sales. Games Econom Behav 4(4):493–510

    Article  Google Scholar 

  6. Bergh V, Reid L, Schorin G (1983) How many creative alternatives to generate. J Advert 12(4):46–49

    Article  Google Scholar 

  7. Bulow JI, Geanakoplos JD, Klemperer PD (1985) Multimarket oligopoly—strategic substitutes and complements. J Polit Econ 93(3):488–511

    Article  Google Scholar 

  8. Chandiramani R (2003) Doing battle with copycat ads. Marketing, Published on May 8th, 2003

  9. Chen YX, Joshi YV, Raju JS, Zhang ZJ (2009) A theory of combative advertising. Mark Sci 28(1):1–19. https://doi.org/10.1287/mksc.1080.0385

    Article  Google Scholar 

  10. Dasgupta P, Maskin E (1986) The existence of equilibrium in discontinuous economic games. 1. Theory Rev Econ Stud 53(1):1–26

    Article  Google Scholar 

  11. Davidson R, MacKinnon JG (2004) Econometric theory and methods, vol 5. Oxford University Press, New York

    Google Scholar 

  12. Elliott S (2007) Imitation hits the marketing business. Again. The New York Times. Available at https://www.nytimes.com/2007/11/20/business/media/20adco.html. Accessed 1 Jan 2008

  13. Fisher EO, Wilson CA (1995) Price-competition between 2 international firms facing tariffs. IJIO 13(1):67–87

    Google Scholar 

  14. Folklore.com (2004) The famous 1984 commercial almost got canceled. https://www.folklore.org/StoryView.py?project=Macintosh&story=1984.txt. Accessed March 16 2019

  15. Gabszewicz JJ, Laussel D, Sonnac N (2004) Programming and advertising competition in the broadcasting industry. J Econ Manag Strateg 13(4):657–669

    Article  Google Scholar 

  16. Gal-Or E, Dukes A (2003) Minimum differentiation in commercial media markets. J Econ Manag Strateg 12(3):291–325

    Article  Google Scholar 

  17. Garfinkel L (2005) Creative best spots. Adweek, p 21

  18. Goldenberg J, Mazursky D, Solomon S (1999) The fundamental templates of quality ads. Mark Sci 18(3):333–351

    Article  Google Scholar 

  19. Gross I (1972) Creative aspects of advertising. Sloan Manag Rev 14(1):83–109

    Google Scholar 

  20. Harrison GW, Hirshleifer J (1989) An experimental evaluation of weakest link/best shot models of public goods. J Polit Econ 97(1):201–225

    Article  Google Scholar 

  21. Hirshleifer J (1983) From weakest-link to best-shot: the voluntary provision of public goods. Public Choice 41(3):371–386

    Article  Google Scholar 

  22. Iyer G, Soberman D, Villas-Boas JM (2005) The targeting of advertising. Mark Sci 24(3):461–476. https://doi.org/10.1287/mksc.1050.0117

    Article  Google Scholar 

  23. Lin Y, Narasimhan C (2008) Persuasive advertising and product design. SSRN Working Paper:available at SSRN: http://ssrn.com/abstract=900642. Accesssed 1 Jan 2009

  24. Lodish LM, Abraham M, Kalmenson S, Livelsberger J, Lubetkin B, Richardson B, Stevens ME (1995) How TV-advertising works—a metaanalysis of 389 real-world split cable TV-advertising experiments. J Mark Res 32(2):125–139

    Article  Google Scholar 

  25. MSI (2008) Research priorities: 2008–2010 guide to MSI research programs and procedures. Available at http://www.msi.org/pdf/MSI_RP08-10.pdf. Accesssed 1 Jan 2012

  26. Naik PA, Raman K (2003) Understanding the impact of synergy in multimedia communications. J Mark Res 40(4):375–388

    Article  Google Scholar 

  27. Narasimhan C (1988) Competitive promotional strategies. J Bus 61(4):427–449

    Article  Google Scholar 

  28. Nelson P (1974) Advertising as information. J Polit Econ 82(4):729–754

    Article  Google Scholar 

  29. Ogilvy D (1983) Ogilvy on advertising. Crown Publishers, New York

    Google Scholar 

  30. Pieters R, Warlop L, Wedel M (2002) Breaking through the clutter: benefits of advertisement originality and familiarity for brand attention and memory. Manag Sci 48(6):765–781

    Article  Google Scholar 

  31. Piga CA (1998) A dynamic model of advertising and product differentiation. Rev Ind Organ 13(5):509–522. https://doi.org/10.1023/a:1007743111299

    Article  Google Scholar 

  32. Raj SP (1982) The effects of advertising on high and low loyalty consumer segments. J Consum Res 9(1):77–89

    Article  Google Scholar 

  33. Raju JS, Srinivasan V, Lal R (1990) The effects of brand loyalty on competitive price promotional strategies. Manag Sci 36(3):276–304

    Article  Google Scholar 

  34. Ramsey LP (2006) Intellectual property rights in advertising. Michigan Telecommunications and Technology Law Review 12(2):189–263

    Google Scholar 

  35. Reporter (2011) Why did Samsung use Apple’s little girl to model their new tablet? Daily Mail. Available at https://www.dailymail.co.uk/news/article-2080831/Why-did-Samsung-use-Apples-little-girl-model-new-tablet.html. Accesssed 1 Jan 2012

  36. Review HL (1932) The imitation of advertising. Harvard Law Review 45(3):542–548

    Article  Google Scholar 

  37. Schmalensee R (1983) Advertising and entry deterrence: an exploratory model. J Polit Econ 91(4):636–653

    Article  Google Scholar 

  38. Schultz D, Schultz H (2003) IMC, the next generation: five steps for delivering value and measuring returns using marketing communication, 1st edn. McGraw-Hill, USA

    Google Scholar 

  39. Schweidel DA, Bradlow ET, Williams P (2006) A feature-based approach to assessing advertisement similarity. J Mark Res 43(2):237–243

    Article  Google Scholar 

  40. Shilony Y (1977) Mixed pricing in oligopoly. J Econ Theory 14(2):373–388

    Article  Google Scholar 

  41. Slade ME (1995) Product rivalry with multiple strategic weapons: an analysis of price and advertising competition. J Econ Manag Strateg 4(3):445–476. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1430-9134.1995.00445.x

    Article  Google Scholar 

  42. Smith RE, MacKenzie SB, Yang XJ, Buchholz LM, Darley WK (2007) Modeling the determinants and effects of creativity in advertising. Mark Sci 26(6):819–833. https://doi.org/10.1287/mksc.1070.0272

    Article  Google Scholar 

  43. Tellis GJ (1988) Advertising exposure, loyalty, and brand purchase: a two-stage model of choice. J Mark Res 25(2):134–144

    Article  Google Scholar 

  44. Tellis GJ (2009) Generalizations about advertising effectiveness in markets. J Advert Res 49(2):240–245. https://doi.org/10.2501/s0021849909090357

    Article  Google Scholar 

  45. Till BD, Priluck RL (2000) Stimulus generalization in classical conditioning: an initial investigation and extension. Psychol Mark 17(1):55–72. https://doi.org/10.1002/(sici)1520-6793(200001)17:1<55::aid-mar4>3.0.co;2-c

    Article  Google Scholar 

  46. Verbauwhede L (2005) Intellectual property issues in advertising. World Intellectual Property Organization. Available at http://www.wipo.int/export/sites/www/sme/en/documents/pdf/ip_advertising.pdf. Accesssed 1 Jan 2008

  47. Villas-Boas JM (2004) Consumer learning, brand loyalty, and competition. Mark Sci 23(1):134–145. https://doi.org/10.1287/mksc.1030.0044

    Article  Google Scholar 

  48. Visentin M, Colucci M, Luca Marzocchi G (2013) Brand measurement scales and underlying cognitive dimensions. Int J Mark Res 55(1):43–57. https://doi.org/10.2501/IJMR-2013-006

    Article  Google Scholar 

  49. Wells W, Burnett J, Moriarty S (2003) Advertising, principles and practice, 6th edn. Prentice-Hall, Upper Saddle River, NJ

    Google Scholar 

  50. Wernerfelt B (1990) Advertising content when brand choice is a signal. J Bus 63(1):91–98

    Article  Google Scholar 

  51. Wernerfelt B (1991) Brand loyalty and market equilibrium. Mark Sci 10(3):229–245

    Article  Google Scholar 

  52. West D, Ford J (2001) Advertising agency philosophies and employee risk taking. J Advert 30(1):77–91. https://doi.org/10.1080/00913367.2001.10673633

    Article  Google Scholar 

  53. Xie Y, Kuksov D (2010) Pricing, frills, and customer ratings. Mark Sci 29(5):925–943

    Article  Google Scholar 

  54. Zhao H (2000) Raising awareness and signaling quality to uninformed consumers: a price advertising model. Mark Sci 19(4):390–396

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

This research was partially supported by Social Sciences and Humanities Research Council of Canada (SSHRC) Insight Grant 435-2016-0250. The authors would like to thank the editor and the three reviewers for their comments, which greatly improved the manuscript during the review process.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Chun (Martin) Qiu.

Electronic Supplementary Material

ESM 1

(DOCX 259 kb)

Appendices

Appendix 1

Table 7 Survey items

Appendix 2. Proofs of Propositions

Derivation of Originality Thresholds

Define absas the most effective (the best-shot) ad available prior to Period 1. We first consider the market leader’s ad decision. Specifically, a firm j will create an original ad if and only if:

$$ \underset{a_M^j}{\max}\left\{\mathbbm{E}\left({\varPi}_M^j\left({a}_M^j\right)\right)-k{\left({a}_M^j\right)}^2/2\right\}>\mathbbm{E}\left({\varPi}_M^j\left({a}^{bs}\right)\right), $$
(6)

where \( \mathbbm{E}\left({\varPi}_M^j\left({a}^{bs}\right)\right) \)for j = {L, F} and M = {LC, FC} given in Table 2. We then solve for the optimal ajM for j = {L, F} under two different market scenarios,

$$ {a}_M^{j\ast }=\underset{a_M^j}{\mathrm{argmax}}\left(\mathbbm{E}\left({\varPi}_M^j\left({a}_M^j\right)\right)-k{\left({a}_M^j\right)}^2/2\right\}\Big). $$
(7)

We substitute \( {a}_M^{j\ast } \) back to right-hand side of (6), and one can verify that the left-hand side of (6) is increasing inabs. Thus, we can use (6) to define the two firms’ originality thresholds under two different market scenarios, respectively.

$$ {\overset{\frown }{a}}_M^j=\left\{a|\underset{a^j}{\max}\left[\mathbbm{E}\left({\varPi}_M^j\left({a}^j\right)\right)-k{\left({a}^j\right)}^2/2\right]=\mathbbm{E}\left({\varPi}_M^j(a)\right)\right\}. $$
(8)

\( {\overset{\frown }{a}}_M^j \)are given in Table 5 for j = {L, F} and M = {LC, FC}.

Proof of Proposition 1

The comparison of the two originality thresholds can be expressed as follows:

$$ {\overset{\frown }{a}}_M^L-{\overset{\frown }{a}}_M^F=\frac{\left[2\alpha -1-\left(1-2\alpha -2\beta \right)\theta \right]v}{2k}. $$
(9)

Let f(θ= \( {\overset{\frown }{a}}_M^L \) − \( {\overset{\frown }{a}}_M^F \) and differentiate w.r.t. θ, we have:

$$ f'\left(\theta \right)=\frac{\left(2\alpha +2\beta -1\right)v}{2k}. $$
(10)

We also solve for f(θ) = 0, where the critical value is given as \( {\theta}_1=\frac{1-2\alpha }{2\alpha +2\beta -1} \).

When α > 1/2, we haveα + β > 1/2, suggesting that f’(θ) > 0. Hence, f(θ) is monotonically increasing in θ; α > 1/2 also suggests that θ1 < 0. Therefore, f(θ ≥ 0) > f(θ1) = 0. That is, for any positive value of θ, the market leader always has a higher originality threshold than firm F.

When 1/2 − β < α < 1/2, we haveα + β > 1/2 suggesting that f’(θ) > 0. Hence, f(θ) is still monotonically increasing in θ and1 − 2α > 0, which means that θ1 > 0. Therefore, f(θ) > 0 for any positive value of θ > θ1 , suggesting that the market leader has a higher originality threshold, and vice versa for 0 < θ< θ1.

When α < 1/2 − β, we haveα + β < 1/2 suggesting that f’(θ) < 0. Hence, f(θ) is now monotonically decreasing in θ. It also suggests that1 − 2α > 0 which means that θ1 < 0. Therefore, for any positive value of θ> θ1 , f(θ) < 0, suggesting that the market leader always has a lower originality threshold than firm F.

Proof of Proposition 2

We first write down the mathematical results for Proposition 2, which are as follows:

  1. (a)

    When abs > max{\( {\overset{\frown }{a}}_M^L \),\( {\overset{\frown }{a}}_M^F \)}, neither firm will originate.

  2. (b)

    When min{ \( {\overset{\frown }{a}}_M^L \) , \( {\overset{\frown }{a}}_M^F \) } < a bs max{ \( {\overset{\frown }{a}}_M^L \) , \( {\overset{\frown }{a}}_M^F \) }, and \( {\overset{\frown }{a}}_M^L \) > \( {\overset{\frown }{a}}_M^F \) ,only firm L will originate.

  3. (c)

    When min{\( {\overset{\frown }{a}}_M^L \),\( {\overset{\frown }{a}}_M^F \)} < abs < max{\( {\overset{\frown }{a}}_M^L \),\( {\overset{\frown }{a}}_M^F \)}, and\( {\overset{\frown }{a}}_M^L \)<\( {\overset{\frown }{a}}_M^F \),only firm F will originate.

  4. (d)

    When abs < min{\( {\overset{\frown }{a}}_M^L \),\( {\overset{\frown }{a}}_M^F \)}, only one firm will originate.

  1. 1.

    The result where abs is greater than \( {\overset{\frown }{a}}_M^L \)and \( {\overset{\frown }{a}}_M^F \) comes directly from its definition. Neither firm has the incentive to create its own ad as the best-shot ad theme is effective enough.

  2. 2.

    When abs lies between the \( {\overset{\frown }{a}}_M^L \) and \( {\overset{\frown }{a}}_M^F \), we assume that \( {\overset{\frown }{a}}_M^L \) > \( {\overset{\frown }{a}}_M^F \), and hence, we have \( {\overset{\frown }{a}}_M^F \) < abs < \( {\overset{\frown }{a}}_M^L \). This inequality suggests that the best-shot ad theme is good enough for firm F but not for firm L. Firm F has no incentive to originate, and it only chooses the best available ad theme. For firm L, abs > \( {\overset{\frown }{a}}_M^L \) suggests that it has the incentive to originate, even if firm F eventually copycats its creative. For illustration purposes, we pick one sub-scenario from where \( {\overset{\frown }{a}}_M^L \) > \( {\overset{\frown }{a}}_M^F \). This corresponds to Proposition 1, Part 1, where α > 1/2.

We can then compute the two firms’ expected profits to form the following payoff matrix:

  

Firm L

Originate

Not originate

Firm F

Originate

{\( {\pi}_O^L\left({a}^{L\ast },{a}^{F\ast}\right) \), \( {\pi}_O^F\left({a}^{L\ast },{a}^{F\ast}\right) \)}

{\( {\pi}_{NO}^L\left({a}^{F\ast}\right) \), \( {\pi}_O^F\left({a}^{F\ast}\right) \)}

Not originate

{\( {\pi}_O^L\left({a}^{L\ast}\right) \), \( {\pi}_{NO}^F\left({a}^{L\ast}\right) \)}

{\( {\pi}_{NO}^L\left({a}^{bs}\right) \), \( {\pi}_{NO}^F\left({a}^{bs}\right) \)}

where \( {\pi}_O^j \)=\( \mathbbm{E}\left({\varPi}_M^j\left({a}^{j\ast}\right)\right)-k{\left({a}^{j\ast}\right)}^2/2 \), and \( {\pi}_{NO}^j \) = \( {\varPi}_M^j\left(\max \left\{{a}^{bs},{a}^{-j\ast}\right\}\right) \), where aj is firm j’s competitor’s creative ad.

By the definition of the originality threshold, when \( {\overset{\frown }{a}}_M^F \) < abs < \( {\overset{\frown }{a}}_M^L \), we have\( {\pi}_{NO}^F\left({a}^{bs}\right) \) > \( {\varPi}_O^F\left({a}^{F\ast}\right) \), and \( {\pi}_O^L\left({a}^{L\ast}\right) \) > \( {\pi}_{NO}^L\left({a}^{bs}\right) \). Firm L is strictly better off by originating its own ad instead of using the best-shot theme abs. On the other hand, Firm L’s creative decision leads to aL* > abs. Since \( {\pi}_{NO}^F \) is monotonically increasing in a, we have \( {\pi}_{NO}^F\left({a}^{L\ast}\right)>{\pi}_{NO}^F\left({a}^{bs}\right) \). That is, firm F is strictly better off by copycatting aL*. Consequently, neither firm wants to deviate from the outcome {originate, not originate}. Hence, {originate, not originate} constitutes a Nash equilibrium.

  1. 1.

    The proof for the cases where \( {\overset{\frown }{a}}_M^L \) < \( {\overset{\frown }{a}}_M^F \)is the same. {not originate, originate} constitutes a Nash equilibrium.

  2. 2.

    Finally, when abs < min{\( {\overset{\frown }{a}}_M^L \), \( {\overset{\frown }{a}}_M^F \)}, we first assume that \( {\overset{\frown }{a}}_M^L \) > \( {\overset{\frown }{a}}_M^F \), and hence, abs < \( {\overset{\frown }{a}}_M^F \) < \( {\overset{\frown }{a}}_M^L \). Either firm has motivations to originate. Firm L is strictly better off by originating its own ad instead of using the best-shot theme abs\( {\pi}_O^L\left({a}^{L\ast}\right) \) > \( {\pi}_{NO}^L\left({a}^{bs}\right) \). On the other hand, firm L’s creative decision leads to aL* > abs. Since \( {\pi}_{NO}^F \) is monotonically increasing in a, \( {\pi}_{NO}^F\left({a}^{L\ast}\right)>{\pi}_{NO}^F\left({a}^{bs}\right) \). That is, firm F is strictly better off by copycatting aL*.

Will firm F also originates given that firm L is originating? The answer is no. Since \( {\overset{\frown }{a}}_M^L \) > \( {\overset{\frown }{a}}_M^F \), we have aL* > aF*. Thus, for firm F, if it originates, it ends up with a less effective ad, and at the same time, incurs non-negative creative costs. Hence, firm F will not originate. Consequently, neither firm wants to deviate from the outcome {originate, not originate}, which constitutes a Nash equilibrium.

We now examine the case where \( {\overset{\frown }{a}}_M^L \) < \( {\overset{\frown }{a}}_M^F \), and hence, abs < \( {\overset{\frown }{a}}_M^L \) < \( {\overset{\frown }{a}}_M^F \). In this case, firm F is strictly better off by originating because \( {\pi}_O^F\left({a}^{F\ast}\right) \) > \( {\pi}_{NO}^F\left({a}^{bs}\right) \).

Will firm L deviates to “originate” given that firm F is originating? The answer is also no. To see this, when firm L copycatsaF, its profit is given by

$$ {\pi}_{NO}^L\left({a}^{F\ast}\right)=\frac{\left(\alpha +\alpha \theta +\beta \theta \right)\left(3\alpha +3\alpha \theta +3\beta \theta -2-2\theta \right){v}^2}{2k}. $$
(11)

When firm L originates, its profit is given by.

$$ {\pi}_O^L\left({a}^{L\ast}\right)=\frac{\left(\alpha +\alpha \theta +\beta \theta \right)\left(3\alpha +3\alpha \theta +3\beta \theta -2-2\theta \right){v}^2}{2k}. $$
(12)

By Proposition 1, abs < min{\( {\overset{\frown }{a}}_M^L \), \( {\overset{\frown }{a}}_M^F \)}, this suggests that \( \theta >\frac{1-2\alpha }{2\alpha +2\beta -1} \), for which the comparison of (11) and (12) \( {\pi}_O^L\left({a}^{L\ast}\right)-{\pi}_{NO}^L\left({a}^{F\ast}\right) \) < 0. Thus, firm L will not originate, and {not originate, originate} constitutes an equilibrium. To sum up, at most one firm originates.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Qiu, C.(., Vakratsas, D. & Dall’Olio, F. Advertising Originality Decisions in Competition. Cust. Need. and Solut. 6, 13–25 (2019). https://doi.org/10.1007/s40547-019-00095-0

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s40547-019-00095-0

Keywords

Navigation