Skip to main content
Log in

Reciprocity: theory and facts

Introduction to the special issue

  • Published:
International Review of Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

The importance of reciprocity is not new in economics. Contractual market exchanges and long-run interactions are both situations based on self-interested reciprocal behaviour. However, reciprocity is not only a behaviour but also a motive that sometimes appears to be inconsistent with self-interest. This fact produces a tension between those who try to explain reciprocal behaviour within the standard framework and those who aim at enlarging it with the introduction of additional behavioural principles. This special issue collects a selection of papers presented at the International Conference “Reciprocity. Theory and facts” were the two perspectives were compared and discussed. In this Introduction note we provide first a broad view of the role of reciprocity in economics and then a quick introduction to each of the contributions enclosed in this special issue.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Notes

  1. On the differences between behavioural and experimental economics, both developed in the 1970s, see Bruni and Sugden (2007).

  2. Elster (1989) and Hollis (1998) both aim at establishing a kind of social rationality different from economic rationality, in order to explain the rise of cooperation in a market context.

  3. For a recent and convincing review, see also Sobel (2005), while among the first economists to study reciprocity in economics was Kolm (1984).

  4. See for example Attanasi and Nagel (2007), Battigalli and Dufwenberg (2005), Dufwenberg and Gneezy (2000), Dufwenberg and Kirchsteiger (2004), Guerra and Zizzo (2004), Kolpin (1992).

  5. The key element in Rabin’s theory is the existence of a “psychological” pay-off in addition to the monetary pay-off when the player plays kind (whereas in monetary terms she would be better off by not trusting the other). The idea of the psychological payoff has been disputed by those who, like Binmore for example, endorse a “revealed preferences” approach (if an agent has chosen a strategy, this reveals, ex post, what she prefers). As a matter of fact, if we interpret payoffs not in monetary terms but in utility terms, the distinction between material and psychological loses its analytical meaning (although it conserves a hermeneutical value). On this topic see also Battigalli and Dufwenberg (2005), Pelligra (2005).

  6. Fehr and Schmidt (1999) and Bolton and Ockenfels (2000).

  7. .The two authors particularly stress one innovative aspect of their theory (partly deviating from Rabin’s), as they claim that it «explains the relevant stylized facts of a wide range of experimental games. [...] Further, the theory explains why subjects behave differently in treatments where they experience the actions of real persons compared to treatments where they face “actions” caused by a random device. [...] Finally, the theory explains why in bilateral interactions outcomes tend to be “fair” whereas in competitive [and anonymous] markets even extremely unfair distributions may arise» (Falk and Fischbacher 2006, p. 293).

  8. They also make a point on the differences between reciprocity and inequality aversion.

  9. Many among the strong reciprocity models are set in the context of public good games (see Bowles and Gintis 2004).

  10. Fehr and Gächter (2000) have carried out several experiments in the attempt to explain and verify reciprocating behaviours. In particular they have come to the following significant conclusions: (1) reciprocity has been observed also in one-shot games and in contexts in which it is “costly” to implement; (2) reciprocating behaviours are displayed also when agents ignore the identity of the subjects they are interacting with (anonymity); (3) reciprocity has also been ascertained when players are guaranteed that their behaviour cannot be observed;(4) reciprocating behaviours have also been reported when monetary payoffs are particularly high. For a review see Sobel (2005) and Bowles and Gintis (2004). Pointedly, the key question arising from these experiments is: what kind of reciprocity are we talking about?

References

  • Andreoni J (1988) Why free ride? Strategies and learning in public goods experiments. J Public Econ 37:291–304

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Andreoni J (1990) Impure altruism and donations to public goods: a theory of warm-glow. Econ J 100:464–477

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Attanasi G, Nagel R (2007) Psychological games: theoretical findings and experimental evidence. In: Innocenti A, Sbriglia P (eds) Games, rationality and behaviour: essays on behavioural game theory and experiments. Palgrave McMillan, Houndmills/New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Bacharach M (1999) Interactive team reasoning: a contribution to the theory of co-operation. Res Econ 53:117–147

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Battigalli P, Dufwenberg M (2005) Dynamic psychological games. IGIER Working Paper No. 287

  • Bowles S, Gintis H (2004) The evolution of strong reciprocity: cooperation in heterogeneous populations. Theor Popul Biol 65:17–28

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bolton G, Ockenfels A (2000) ERC: a theory of equity, reciprocity and competition. Am Econ Rev 90:166–93

    Google Scholar 

  • Bruni L, Sugden R (2007) The road not taken. How psychology was removed from economics and how it could be brought back. Econ J 117:146–173

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dufwenberg M, Gneezy U (2000) Measuring beliefs in an experimental lost wallet game. Games Econ Behav 30:163–182

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dufwenberg M, Kirchsteiger G (2004) A theory of sequential reciprocity . Games Econ Behav, 47:268–298

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Elster J (1989) The cement of society. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Falk A, Fischbacher U (2006) A theory of reciprocity. Games Econ Behav 54:293–315

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fehr E, Gächter S (2000) Cooperation and punishment in public goods experiments. Am Econ Rev 90:980–999

    Google Scholar 

  • Fehr E, Schmidt KM (1999) A theory of fairness, competition and cooperation. Q J Econ 114:817–868

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gächter S, Thöni C (2005) Social learning and voluntary cooperation among like-minded people. J Eur Econ Assoc 3:303–314

    Google Scholar 

  • Gauthier D (1986) Morals by agreement. Oxford University Press, Oxford

    Google Scholar 

  • Geneakoplos J, Pearce D, Stacchetti E (1989) Psychological games and sequential rationality. Games Econ Behav 1:60–79

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gintis H (2000) Beyond homo economicus: evidence from experimental economics. Ecol Econ 35:311–322

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Guerra G, Zizzo DJ (2004) Trust responsiveness and beliefs. J Econ Behav 55:25–30

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hollis M (1998) Trust within reason. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Kolm SC (1984) Théorie de la réciprocité et du choix des systèmes économiques. Revue Econ 35:871–910

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kolpin V (1992) Equilibrium refinements in psychological games. Games Econ Behav 4:218–231

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pelligra V (2005) Under trusting eyes: the responsive nature of trust. In: Sugden R, Gui B (eds) Economics and social interaction: accounting for the interpersonal relations. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Rabin M (1993) Incorporating fairness in game theory. Am Econ Rev 83:1281–1301

    Google Scholar 

  • Samuelson L (2005) Foundations of human sociality. A review essay. J Econ Lit 43:488–497

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sobel J (2005) Interdependent preferences and reciprocity. J Econ Lit 43:392–436

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sugden R (1984) Reciprocity: the supply of public goods through voluntary contributions. Econ J 94:772–787

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sugden R (1993) Thinking as a team. towards an explanation on non-selfish behaviour. Soc Philos Policy 10:69–89

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

We would like to thank Matteo Rizzolli for his invaluable research assistance, Pier Luigi Porta, Robert Sugden, Stefano Zamagni, and all the participants to the “Reciprocity: Theory and Facts” Conference, for providing numberless intellectual stimuli, new ideas and all the ingredients for a fruitful interdisciplinary dialogue.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Luigino Bruni.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Bruni, L., Gilli, M. & Pelligra, V. Reciprocity: theory and facts. Int. Rev. Econ. 55, 1–11 (2008). https://doi.org/10.1007/s12232-008-0042-9

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s12232-008-0042-9

Keywords

JEL Classifications

Navigation