Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

A new estimate of Lithuanian GDP for 1937: How does interwar Lithuania compare?

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
Cliometrica Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Utilizing archival data from the Lithuanian Central Bureau of Statistics, we piece together the most complete gross domestic product (GDP) figure during the interwar period for Lithuania in accordance with the System of National Accounts (SNA 2008). Lithuania and the other Baltic states have largely been ignored by economic historians due to the short time spans of their independence in the interwar period (1918–1940), their relatively small sizes, and the scarcity of data—we attempt to fill this gap in the historical record. As a practical application of our new GDP estimate for 1937, we convert our estimate into 1990 Geary–Khamis dollars so that we can test the hypothesis that Lithuanian economic growth under communism was below average when compared to its European neighbors using data from the Maddison Project. We find that the economic growth rate in Lithuania was above average from 1937 to 1973, even when compared to other communist economies. Alternatively, from 1973 to 1990, growth collapsed and was below average. Using a difference-in-difference strategy we also find a significant GDP per capita penalty for communist countries in Europe over the studied time periods.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1

Sources: from Statistical Yearbook of Lithuania of the Central Bureau of Statistics (1931, 1932, 1933, 1934, 1935, 1936, 1937, 1938a, b, 1939, 1940). Note: Between 1913 and 1924, data were unavailable

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. For a deeper discussion of the methodology for deriving Geary–Khamis dollars please see Deaton and Heston (2010).

  2. For some of the price data we also used archival newspaper “Lietuvos Aidas” from 1937.

  3. When using the nominal exchange rate to calculate Lithuania’s GDPpc, the Growth factor is 6.23 and the annual growth rate is 3.51%.

  4. In Table 35 of Appendix 3 a difference-in-difference regression is run with the same result, providing the standard errors. In Table 36 we also run a regression comparing Soviet Satellite countries with the Soviet Union but the results are not statistically significant, and not reported in the main text.

References

  • Allen RC (2003) Farm to factory: a reinterpretation of the Soviet industrial revolution. Princeton University Press, Princeton

    Google Scholar 

  • Andersson FN, Lennard J (2018) Irish GDP between the famine and the first world war: estimates based on a dynamic factor model. Eur Rev Econ His 23(1):50–71. https://doi.org/10.1093/ereh/hey003

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Anušauskas A, Banionis J, Bauža Č, Brandišauskas V et al (2015) Lithuania in 1940–1991: the history of occupied Lithuania. Genocide and Resistance Research Centre of Lithuania, Vilnius

    Google Scholar 

  • Axenciuc V, Voineagu V (2012) Produsul intern brut al României: 1862–2000: serii statistice seculare şi argumente metodologice. Editura Economică

  • Bank of England (2018) Industrial production index in the United Kingdom. https://www.fredstlouisfedorg/series/IPIUKM. Accessed 4 Mar 2018

  • Berend IT (2006) An economic history of twentieth-century Europe. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Berzin AA (2008) The truth about soviet whaling. Mar Fish Rev 702:4–59

    Google Scholar 

  • Bolt J et al (2018) Maddison project database, version 2018. Maddison project working paper 10

  • Broadberry SN (1994) Technological leadership and productivity leadership in manufacturing since the industrial revolution: implications for the convergence debate. Economic Journal 104:291–302

    Google Scholar 

  • Broadberry SN (2003) Relative per capita income levels in the United Kingdom and the United States since 1870: reconciling time-series projections and direct-benchmark estimates. J Econ His 63(3):852–863. https://doi.org/10.1017/S0022050703542012

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Broadberry SN, Klein A (2011) When and why did eastern European economies begin to fail? Lessons from a Czechoslovak/UK productivity comparison, 1921–1991. Explor Econ Hist 48(1):37–52

    Google Scholar 

  • Bubnys A (2017) Damage caused by the Soviet Union in Lithuania—depopulation of 1940–1941 and 1944–1953. Damage caused by the Soviet Union in the Baltic States. Publisher Ltd., E-forma, Riga, pp 22–30

    Google Scholar 

  • Central Bureau of Statistics (1929) Statistical yearbook of Lithuania (1927–1928). Central Bureau of Statistics, Kaunas

    Google Scholar 

  • Central Bureau of Statistics (1930) Lithuanian agricultural census. Central Bureau of Statistics, Kaunas

    Google Scholar 

  • Central Bureau of Statistics (1931) Statistical yearbook of Lithuania (1929–1930). Central Bureau of Statistics, Kaunas

    Google Scholar 

  • Central Bureau of Statistics (1932) Statistical yearbook of Lithuania (1931). Central Bureau of Statistics, Kaunas

    Google Scholar 

  • Central Bureau of Statistics (1933) Statistical yearbook of Lithuania (1932). Central Bureau of Statistics, Kaunas

    Google Scholar 

  • Central Bureau of Statistics (1934) Statistical yearbook of Lithuania (1933). Central Bureau of Statistics, Kaunas

    Google Scholar 

  • Central Bureau of Statistics (1935) Statistical yearbook of Lithuania (1934). Central Bureau of Statistics, Kaunas

    Google Scholar 

  • Central Bureau of Statistics (1936) Statistical yearbook of Lithuania (1935). Central Bureau of Statistics, Kaunas

    Google Scholar 

  • Central Bureau of Statistics (1937) Statistical yearbook of Lithuania (1936). Central Bureau of Statistics, Kaunas

    Google Scholar 

  • Central Bureau of Statistics (1938a) Statistical bulletin no 7. Central Bureau of Statistics, Kaunas

    Google Scholar 

  • Central Bureau of Statistics (1938b) Statistical yearbook of Lithuania (1937). Central Bureau of Statistics, Kaunas

    Google Scholar 

  • Central Bureau of Statistics (1939) Statistical yearbook of Lithuania (1938). Central Bureau of Statistics, Kaunas

    Google Scholar 

  • Central Bureau of Statistics (1940) Statistical yearbook of Lithuania (1939). Central Bureau of Statistics, Vilnius

    Google Scholar 

  • Cheremukhin A, Golosov M, Guriev S, Tsyvinski A (2013) Was Stalin necessary for Russia’s economic development? NBER working paper 19425

  • Čiegis R (2012) Makroekonomika. Vilniaus universiteto leidykla, Vilnius

    Google Scholar 

  • Clark C (1938) Internationaler vergleich der volkseinkommen weltwirtschaftliches archiv, pp 51–76

  • Costanza R, Hart M, Posner S, Talberth J (2009) Beyond GDP: the need for new measures of progress. The parade papers 4

  • Crafts NFR, Toniolo G (2008) European economic growth, 1950–2005: an overview. Discussion paper 686. Centre for Economic Policy Research, London

  • Dargis L (1974) Ko buvo vertas nepriklausomos Lietuvos ūkis. Naujoji Viltis 7:67–77

    Google Scholar 

  • Dargis L (1975) Bendrinės tautinės Lietuvos pajamos 1937 metais. Naujoji Viltis 8:48–68

    Google Scholar 

  • Dargis L (1976) Nepriklausomos Lietuvos 1937 metų tautinės pajamos. Naujoji Viltis 9:25–39

    Google Scholar 

  • Dargis L (1978) Nepriklausomos Lietuvos 1937 ir 1938 metų tautinės ir bendrinės tautinės pajamos. Naujoji Viltis 11:78–97

    Google Scholar 

  • Deaton A, Heston A (2010) Understanding PPPs and PPP-based national accounts. Am Econ J Macroecon 2:1–35

    Google Scholar 

  • Eckstein A (1955) National income and capital formation in Hungary, 1900–1950. Rev Income Wealth 5:152–223

    Google Scholar 

  • Edquist C, Jacobson S (1988) Flexible automation: the global diffusion of technology in the engineering industry. Blackwell, Oxford

    Google Scholar 

  • Edvinsson R (2013) Swedish GDP 1620–1800: stagnation or growth? Cliometrica 7(1):37–60. https://doi.org/10.1007/s11698-012-0082-y

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Edvinsson R (2018) Main page. http://www.historicalstatisticsorg. Accessed 1 July 2018

  • Eichengreen B (1996) Institutions and economic growth: Europe after world war II. In: Crafts N, Toniolo G (eds) Economic growth in Europe since 1945. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, pp 38–72

    Google Scholar 

  • Eichengreen B (2007) The European economy since 1945: coordinated capitalism and beyond. Princeton University Press, Princeton

    Google Scholar 

  • Eurostat (2017) Consolidated supply, use and input-output tables Eurostat: statistics explained. https://ec.europa.eu/eurostat/statistics-explained/index.php/Consolidated_supply,_use_and_input-output_tables. Accessed 20 Mar 2018

  • Frankema E, Smits JP, Woltjer P (2010) Comparing productivity in the Netherlands, France, UK and US, ca 1910: a new PPP benchmark and its implications for changing economic leadership. GGDC working papers 113

  • Fridbergas Š (1988) Buržuazinės Lietuvos pramonė. Mintis, Vilnius

    Google Scholar 

  • Gregory PR (1976) 1913 Russian national income–some insights into Russian Economic Development. Q J Econ 445–459

  • Harrison M (2002) Coercion, compliance, and the collapse of the Soviet command economy. Econ His Rev 55(3):397–433

    Google Scholar 

  • Hjerppe R (1996) Finland’s historical national accounts 1860–1994: calculation methods and statistical tables. Jyväskylän Yliopisto, Jyväskylä

    Google Scholar 

  • Jakniūnaitė D (2015) A small state in the asymmetrical bilateral relations: Lithuania in Lithuanian–Russian relations since 2004. Balt J Polit Sci 4:70–94

    Google Scholar 

  • Jakštas J (1968) Nepriklausomybės laikai. Lietuvių enciklopedija, vol 15. Lietuvių enciklopedijos leidykla, Boston, pp 338–344

    Google Scholar 

  • Johnson DG, Brooks KM (1983) Prospects for Soviet agriculture in the 1980s. Indiana University Press, Bloomington

    Google Scholar 

  • Kalnins J, Pinke G (2017) Determining the damage of occupation: hypothetical evaluation of the development path of Latvia, had it not been occupied. Damage caused by the Soviet Union in the Baltic States. Publisher Ltd., E-forma, Riga, pp 59–64

    Google Scholar 

  • Kirzner IM (1988) The economic calculation debate: lessons for Austrians. Rev Aust Econ 2(1):1–18

    Google Scholar 

  • Krantz O, Schön L (2007) Swedish historical national accounts 1800–2000. Almqvist and Wiksell International, Lund

    Google Scholar 

  • Lange O (1936) On the economic theory of socialism I. Rev Econ Stud 4(1):53–71. https://doi.org/10.2307/2967660

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lechner M (2011) The estimation of causal effects by difference-in-difference methods. Found Trends Econom 43:165–224. https://doi.org/10.1561/0800000014

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Levy DM, Peart SJ (2011) Soviet growth and American textbooks: an endogenous past. J Econ Behav Organ 78(1–2):110–125

    Google Scholar 

  • McDermott G (2002) Embedded politics: industrial networks and institutional change in postcommunism. University of Michigan Press, Ann Arbor

    Google Scholar 

  • Meškauskas K (1960) Tarybų Lietuvos industrializavimas. Politinės ir mokslinės literatūros leidykla, Vilnius

    Google Scholar 

  • Ministry of Transport and Communications of the Republic of Lithuania (1938) Susisiekimo ministerijos 1937 metų metraštis. Ministry of Transport and Communications of the Republic of Lithuania, Kaunas

    Google Scholar 

  • Miškų departamentas (1940) Miškų departamento metraštis 1918–1938. Miškų departamentas, Kaunas

    Google Scholar 

  • Norkus Z (2016) Apie pirmuosius nacionalinių pajamų skaičiavimus tarpukario Lietuvoje ir Albino Rimkos juose padarytas klaidas, pagreitinusias demokratijos žlugimą. Lietuvos istorijos studijos 38:42–71

    Google Scholar 

  • North DC (1993) The new institutional economics and development. Econ Hist 9309002

  • Nove A (1962) Was Stalin Really Necessary? Encounter 18(4):86–92

    Google Scholar 

  • OECD (2018) Industrial production. https://www.dataoecdorg/industry/industrial-productionhtm. Accessed 20 Mar 2018

  • Ofer G (1987) Soviet economic growth: 1928–1985. J Econ Lit 25(4):1767–1833

    Google Scholar 

  • Official Statistics of Sweden (1961) Consumer prices and index computations 1931–1959. The Swedish Social Welfare Board, Stockholm

    Google Scholar 

  • Paltarokas J (1968) Žemės ūkis. Lietuvių enciklopedija, vol 15. Lietuvių enciklopedijos leidykla, Boston, pp 180–192

    Google Scholar 

  • Prados de la Escosura L (2017) Spanish economic growth, 1850–2015. Palgrave Mcmillan, Basingstoke

    Google Scholar 

  • Pryor FL, Pryor ZP, Stadnik M, Staller GJ (1971) Czechoslovak aggregate production in the interwar period. Rev Income Wealth 17(1):35–59. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1475-4991.1971.tb00766.x

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rimka A (1926a) Tautos pelnas ir metodai jam surasti. Lietuvos ūkis 43:105–110

    Google Scholar 

  • Rimka A (1926b) Tautos pelnas ir metodai jam surasti. Lietuvos ūkis 44:141–146

    Google Scholar 

  • Schön L, Krantz O (2015) New Swedish historical national accounts since the 16th century in constant and current prices. Lund Papers in Economic History 140, Lund

  • Staehr K (2013) Austerity in the Baltic states during the global financial crisis. Intereconomics 485:293–302

    Google Scholar 

  • Stankiewicz WJ, Montias JM (1955) Institutional changes in the postwar economy of Poland. Mid-European Studies Center, Free Europe Committee, New York, p 125

    Google Scholar 

  • Šulga A, Tininis V (2007) Lietuva politinio atšilimo ir stagnacijos laikotarpiu (1953–1987). In: Visuotinė lietuvių enciklopedija. Mokslo ir enciklopedijų leidybos institutas, Vilnius, vol 12, p 550

  • Tamulevičius J (1939) Kiek savarankiškų amatininkų turime kaime? Amatininkas 1531:246–248

    Google Scholar 

  • Tautos ūkis (1937) Akcinių bankų pajamos ir išlaidos 1936 m. Tautos ūkis 44:907

    Google Scholar 

  • Vaišnys J (1938) Žalienų gerinimo baras jau toli nuvarytas. Ūkininko patarėjas 5:5

    Google Scholar 

  • Valančius G (1956) The economic development and foreign trade of Lithuania. Lituanus. http://www.lituanus.org/1956/56_1_04Valancius.html. Accessed 10 Feb 2019

  • Valge J (2003a) Uue majanduse lätteil Eesti sisemajanduse kogutoodang aastatel 1923–1938. Akadeemia 10:2202–2228

    Google Scholar 

  • Valge J (2003b) Uue majanduse lätteil Eesti sisemajanduse kogutoodang aastatel 1923–1938. Akadeemia 11:2443–2487

    Google Scholar 

  • Valge J (2003c) Uue majanduse lätteil Eesti sisemajanduse kogutoodang aastatel 1923–1938. Akadeemia 12:2712–2735

    Google Scholar 

  • Valstybės kontrolė (1938) 1937 metų Valstybės biudžeto vykdymo apyskaita. Ministry of Finance, Kaunas

    Google Scholar 

  • Vaskela G (2007) Darbo užmokestis ir darbininkų bei tarnautojų šeimų gyvenimo lygis Lietuvoje, Latvijoje ir Estijoje 1938–1940 metais. Lituanistica 4:19–35

    Google Scholar 

  • Vaskela G (2014) Tautiniai aspektai Lietuvos ūkio politikoje 1919–1940 metais. Lietuvos istorijos instituto leidykla, Vilnius

    Google Scholar 

  • Vaskela G (2015) Ekonomika. In: Lietuvos Istorija, vol 10, Nepriklausomybė (1918–1940 m). Lietuvos istorijos instituto leidykla, Vilnius, pp 239–327

  • Viet VQ (2009) GDP by production approach: a general introduction with emphasis on an integrated economic data collection framework. United Nations Statistics Division, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • von Hayek FA, Pierson NG, von Mises L, Halm G, Barone E (1935). Collectivist economic planning

  • Ward M, Devereux J (2004) Relative UK/US output reconsidered: a reply to professor Broadberry. J Econ His 64:879–891

    Google Scholar 

  • Žemės ūkio rūmai (1940) Žemės ūkio sąskaitybos rezultatai: 1937/38 ūkio metai. Žemės ūkio rūmai, Kaunas

    Google Scholar 

  • Žiugžda J (1965) Liteuvos TSR istorija, vol 3: nuo 1917 iki 1940 metų. Valstybinė Politinės ir Mokslinės Literatūros Leidykla, Vilnius

  • Zunde P (1963) Soviet industrial policy in Lithuania. Lituanus. http://www.lituanus.org/1963/63_2_02.htm Accessed 10 Feb 2019

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Aras Zirgulis.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Appendices

Appendix 1—Breakdown of Leonardas Dargis NNI and GNI figures

See Table 6.

Table 6 Breakdown of Dargis’s 1937 NNI and GNI estimates into sources of income.

Appendix 2—Statistical details of 1937 Lithuanian GDP calculation

In Table 7 the calculations of total agricultural land are presented. Agricultural land consists of the land used for crops, animal husbandry, and private forests.

Table 7 Total agricultural land in Lithuania in 1937, ha.

In Table 8 the calculations of GVA from agriculture are presented. The total amount of agricultural land was calculated and is given in Table 7; GVO and IC per hectare were taken from the Agricultural accounts and the subsidies for agricultural products taken from “Ūkininko patarėjas”. It was assumed that there were no taxes on products as there is no separate indication of them. Final GVO and IC values were calculated by multiplying GVO and IC per hectare by the amount of agricultural land.

Table 8 Calculations of GVA from agriculture, LT.

In Table 9 the calculations of GVA from forestry are presented. The GVO at basic prices was calculated by multiplying physical output of logs and firewood by the corresponding basic price quoted by Dargis (1975). The IC of forestry was taken from the Forestry department yearbook; it includes office, inventory expenses, forest growing and forest cleaning expenses. The Forestry department figures only account for Lithuania Major. (Lithuania Minor is the Klaipėda region, and Lithuania Major is the rest of the country.) Therefore, the values for the Klaipėda region and private forests under state supervision are calculated by multiplying the IC per hectare ratio by the area of the Klaipėda region and private forests.

Table 9 Calculations of GVA from forestry, LT.

In Table 10 the calculations of GVA from fishing are presented. The GVO at basic prices was taken from Statistical Yearbook of Lithuania. To calculate IC and GVA, average value-added-to-output ratio from sector A was used. It was obtained by dividing GVA from agriculture and forestry by corresponding GVO. This ratio was then multiplied by GVO from fishing to obtain GVA. Intermediate consumption was then calculated by subtracting value-added from output.

Table 10 Calculations of GVA from fishing, LT.

In Table 11 the calculations of GVA from unaccounted large industrial enterprises are presented. The GVO was taken from Dargis’s article. To calculate IC and GVA, average value-added-to-output ratio from accounted large industrial enterprises was used. It was obtained by dividing GVA from large industrial enterprises by corresponding GVO. This ratio was then multiplied by GVO from Dargis’s article to obtain GVA. Intermediate consumption was then calculated by subtracting value-added from output.

Table 11 Calculations of GVA from unaccounted large industrial enterprises, LT.

In Table 12 the calculations of GVA from small industrial enterprises and crafts are presented. The procedure of calculating output was used from Fridbergas’s book, and gross value-added and intermediate consumption were both calculated using GVA-to-GVO ratio obtained in Table 9. According to the Statistical yearbook and magazine called “Amatininkas”, there were 5207 small industrial enterprises (VIII patent category), 7789 urban craftsmen and 19,661 rural craftsmen in Lithuania Major (Central Bureau of Statistics 1938) (Tamulevičius 1939). Numbers for rural craftsmen are for the year 1938, but it is assumed that the number was the same in 1937. In Klaipėda region, according to Fridbergas, there were 742 small industrial enterprises and 906 urban craftsmen (Fridbergas 1988). Number of rural craftsmen in Klaipėda region was obtained by calculating the ratio of urban craftsmen in Klaipėda region to urban craftsmen in Lithuania Major. Adding the numbers together, the total amounts of enterprises and craftsmen were obtained. According to Fridbergas’s procedure, then these numbers should be multiplied by average number of workers in these enterprises to obtain the final numbers of workers. Fridbergas used the average number of workers without including the owner as a productive worker. In small craft companies the owner worked no less than his assistants (Dargis 1975). Therefore, the average number of workers used by Fridbergas for small industrial enterprises was raised by one (Fridbergas 1988). Then the figures are multiplied by assumed output per worker ratio to obtain final GVO value (Fridbergas 1988). Output per worker for rural craftsmen was assumed to be the same as for urban craftsmen.

Table 12 Calculations of GVA from small industrial enterprises and crafts, LT.

In Table 13 the calculations of GVO from private construction are presented. As repair expenses were not mentioned anywhere in the yearbook, Dargis suggests adding 10% for repair expenses (Dargis 1976).

Table 13 Calculations of GVO from private construction, LT.

In Table 14 the calculations of GVO from public construction are presented. These construction activities include railway construction works, land drying, etc. As repair expenses for public residential buildings were not mentioned anywhere in the yearbook, Dargis suggests adding 10% for repair expenses (Dargis 1976).

Table 14 Calculations of GVO from public construction, LT.

Table 15 represents the separation of enterprises that were considered “Trade in broad meaning” during the interwar years into economic sectors of origin ruled by ISIC.

Table 15 Lithuanian trade enterprises in 1937, distributed among the ISIC economic sectors.

In Table 16 the calculations of other taxes less subsidies paid by enterprises of the “Trade in broad meaning” are presented. The separation of these enterprises into modern economic sectors is presented in Table 15. Other taxes less subsidies on production are the taxes levied on firms regardless of the amounts of production sold or produced. These taxes include license fees, labor taxes, etc. These taxes and subsidies were taken from the Budget execution account. However, job income tax paid by the enterprises was not separated on the basis of sectors the firms operated in. This was overcome by taking the share of population working in “Trade in broad meaning” as a percentage of all working population as a proxy indicator for the share of taxes payable. Such use of working population was extensively used by authors of Czechoslovak aggregate production in the interwar period (Pryor et al. 1971) and was discussed in the review of literature.

Table 16 Calculations of taxes paid by Lithuanian “Trade in broad meaning” enterprises, LT.

In Table 17 the calculations of gross value-added from sector G are provided. The percentage of value that comes from sector G in the “Trade in broad meaning” is taken from Table 15. Information on the number of enterprises, number of employees, average yearly salary, and net operating surplus (NOS) was taken from Dargis’s article. Compensation of employees (CE) was calculated by multiplying number of workers by average salary. It is assumed that profits indicated by Dargis are equal to NOS. Other taxes less subsidies on production (other production (t − s)) figure are taken from Table 16. Values for sector G only were obtained by multiplying values for “Trade in broad meaning” by 79.7% from Table 15. Consumption of fixed capital (CFC) norm for interwar Lithuania was taken from “Makroekonomika” by R. Čiegis.

Table 17 Calculations of GVA from sector G, LT.

In Table 18 the calculations of gross value-added from railway and land transportation are provided. It was assumed that revenues of transportation services in the sources were presented at producer’s prices. GVO at basic prices was obtained by subtracting taxes less subsidies on products. Figures of GVA were obtained by subtracting IC from GVO at basic prices. For private railways and land transportation, only output figures were available; therefore, a GVA-to-GVO ratio and taxes (less subsidies) on products ratio from public railways were calculated and used.

Table 18 Calculations of GVA from railways and land transportation, LT.

In Table 19 the calculations of gross value-added from postal, telegraph, telephone, and radio services are provided. It was assumed that revenues in the sources were presented at producer’s prices. GVO at basic prices was obtained by subtracting taxes less subsidies on products. Figures of GVA were obtained by subtracting IC from GVO at basic prices. IC components of postal services, which are attributable to sector H in Ministry of Transport and Communications yearbook, were presented in yearbooks together with telephone, telegraph, and radio services which are attributable to sector J. The separation was done by taking the percentage of output from postal services to total output and using this ratio to split the intermediate consumption between postal services and telegraph and telephone services. Then the obtained IC was subtracted from GVO and separate GVA values thus calculated.

Table 19 Calculations of GVA from postal, telegraph, telephone, and radio services, LT.

In Table 20 the calculations of gross value-added from distribution of trade goods and water transportation are provided. The calculations were done using the component of GVA approach, used in sector G calculations. For distribution of trade goods, the percentage of value that comes from sector H in the “Trade in broad meaning” is taken from Table 15. Information on the number of enterprises, number of employees, average yearly salary, and net operating surplus (NOS) was taken from Dargis’s article. Compensation of employees (CE) was calculated by multiplying number of workers by average salary. It is assumed that profits indicated by Dargis are equal to NOS. Other taxes less subsidies on production (other production (t − s)) figure are taken from Table 16. Values for sector H only were obtained by multiplying values for “Trade in broad meaning” by 8.8% from Table 15. Consumption of fixed capital (CFC) norm for interwar Lithuania was taken from “Makroekonomika” by R. Čiegis. For water transportation, the CE figures indicated by Dargis were used. It was assumed that there were no profits and no taxes in water transportation as there is no information on this.

Table 20 Calculations of GVA distribution of trade goods and water transportation, LT.

In Table 21 the calculations of gross value-added from sector I (accommodation and food service activities) are provided. The calculations were done using the component of GVA approach, used in sector G calculations. The percentage of value that comes from sector I in the “Trade in broad meaning” is taken from Table 15. Information on the number of enterprises, number of employees, average yearly salary, and net operating surplus (NOS) was taken from Dargis’s article. Compensation of employees (CE) was calculated by multiplying number of workers by average salary. It is assumed that profits indicated by Dargis are equal to NOS. Other taxes less subsidies on production (other production (t − s)) figure are taken from Table 16. Values for sector I only were obtained by multiplying values for “Trade in broad meaning” by 9.4% from Table 15. Consumption of fixed capital (CFC) norm for interwar Lithuania was taken from “Makroekonomika” by R. Čiegis.

Table 21 Calculations of GVA from sector I, LT.

In Table 22 the calculations of gross value-added from financial (banking) activities are provided. The GVO at basic prices of banking is calculated by taking the difference between the total interest revenues and total interest expenses in Lithuania in 1937 which was done by Dargis in 1978. The intermediate consumption (IC) and gross value-added (GVA) were estimated by calculating the GVO, IC, and GVA of largest Lithuanian banks in 1936 from their published income statements and using the same GVA-to-GVO ratio for the whole Lithuanian banking sector in 1937. The ratio was then multiplied by the total GVO of Lithuanian credit sector estimated by Dargis to obtain GVA. The difference between these two figures is IC.

Table 22 Calculations of GVA from financial activities (banking), LT.

In Table 23 the calculations of gross value-added from insurance activities are provided. The GVO was calculated by taking the difference between the total premiums received and total benefits paid in 1937. IC and GVA were calculated using the GVA-to-GVO ratio obtained in Table 22 as there are no separate indications of IC of insurance activities. Data on activities by non-Lithuanian insurance companies were only available for the year 1936, so it was assumed that the figures were the same in 1937.

Table 23 Calculations of GVA from insurance activities, LT.

In Table 24 the calculations of gross value-added from all real estate activities in Lithuania in 1937 are provided. The total real estate taxes amount was obtained from the Budget execution account for treasury taxes and from Statistical Yearbook of Lithuania for municipal taxes. Revenues from government real estate activities were also taken from the budget. GVO at producer’s prices was obtained by dividing the total tax amounts by the real estate tax rate provided by Dargis and adding the governmental real estate revenues. GVO at basic prices was obtained by subtracting real estate tax amounts (taxes on products) from the GVO at producer’s prices. Ratio of GVA to GVO was taken from the European commission’s database. Multiplying the ratio by GVO at basic prices the GVA was obtained and the difference between the two produced the IC figure.

Table 24 Calculations of GVA from total real estate activities, LT.

In Table 25 the calculations of gross value-added from real estate activities that are part of sector T are provided. The only information on activities of households as real estate lenders is provided in the Agricultural accounts. GVO at producer’s prices was obtained by multiplying the total amounts of agricultural land, presented in Table 7 by the leasing output per hectare as recorded in the Agricultural accounts. GVO at basic prices was obtained by subtracting real estate tax amounts (taxes on products) from the GVO at producer’s prices. Ratio of GVA to GVO was taken from the European commission’s database. Multiplying the ration by GVO at basic prices the GVA was obtained and the difference between the two produced the IC figure.

Table 25 Calculations of GVA from total real estate activities of sector T, LT.

In Table 26 the calculations of gross value-added from sector M (professional, scientific and technical activities) are provided. All activities that were included in this sector in interwar Lithuania were non-market, meaning that the prices charged for the services provided by these activities were insignificant and did not cover the costs of service production. Therefore, the components of value-added approach had to be used. For non-market activities net operating surplus (NOS) is zero. The GVA of sector M is therefore the sum of CE, other taxes less subsidies on production and CFC. The compensation of employees (CE) and other taxes less subsidies on production were taken from the Budget execution account. Consumption of fixed capital (CFC) norm for interwar Lithuania was taken from “Makroekonomika” by R. Čiegis.

Table 26 Calculations of GVA from sector M, LT.

In Table 27 the calculations of gross value-added from sector N (administrative and support service activities) are provided. The calculations were done using the component of GVA approach, used in sector G calculations. The percentage of value that comes from sector N in the “Trade in broad meaning” is taken from Table 15. Information on the number of enterprises, number of employees, average yearly salary, and net operating surplus (NOS) was taken from Dargis’s article. Compensation of employees (CE) was calculated by multiplying number of workers by average salary. It is assumed that profits indicated by Dargis are equal to NOS. Other taxes less subsidies on production (other production (t − s)) figure are taken from Table 16. Values for sector N only were obtained by multiplying values for “Trade in broad meaning” by 0.38% from Table 15. Consumption of fixed capital (CFC) norm for interwar Lithuania was taken from “Makroekonomika” by R. Čiegis.

Table 27 Calculations of GVA from sector N, LT.

In Table 28 the calculations of gross value-added from sector R (arts, entertainment, and recreation) are provided. The calculations were done using the component of GVA approach, used in sector G. The percentage of value that comes from sector R in “Trade in broad meaning” is taken from Table 15. Information on the number of enterprises, number of employees, average yearly salary, and net operating surplus (NOS) was taken from Dargis (1976). Compensation of employees (CE) was calculated by multiplying the number of workers by the average salary. It is assumed that the profits indicated by Dargis (1976) are equal to NOS. Other taxes less subsidies on production are taken from Table 16. Values for sector R were obtained by multiplying values for “Trade in broad meaning” by 0.43% from Table 15. In addition, some activities in sector R were non-market (meaning zero profit or insignificant prices). These activities were recorded in the Budget execution account and in the Statistical Yearbook of Lithuania. Separate compensation of employees for municipal recreation services was not available. This issue was solved by taking the average municipal salary-to-ordinary expenses ratio (35.7% of 6,519,400.6 LT of ordinary recreation expenses) from the municipal accounts (in the Statistical yearbook) and using it to calculate the CE of municipal activities. The consumption of fixed capital (CFC) norm for interwar Lithuania was taken from “Makroekonomika” by R. Čiegis.

Table 28 Calculations of GVA from sector R, LT.

In Table 29 the calculations of gross value-added from sector S (other service activities) are provided. The calculations were done using the component of GVA approach. The percentage of value that comes from sector S in “Trade in broad meaning” is taken from Table 15. Information on the number of enterprises, number of employees, average yearly salary, and net operating surplus (NOS) was taken from Dargis (1976). Compensation of employees (CE) was calculated by multiplying the number of workers by the average salary. It is assumed that the profits indicated by Dargis are equal to NOS. Other taxes less subsidies on production are taken from Table 14. Values for sector R only were obtained by multiplying values for “Trade in broad meaning” by 0.62% from Table 13. In addition, some activities in sector S were non-market (meaning zero profit). These activities were recorded in the Budget execution account and were also calculated here. Consumption of fixed capital (CFC) norm for interwar Lithuania was taken from “Makroekonomika” by R. Čiegis.

Table 29 Calculations of GVA from sector S, LT.

In Table 30 the calculations of gross value-added from sector O (public administration and defense; compulsory social security) are provided. All activities that were included in this sector in interwar Lithuania were non-market, meaning that the prices charged for the services provided by these activities were insignificant and did not cover the costs of service production. Therefore, the components of value-added approach had to be used. For non-market activities net operating surplus (NOS) is zero. The GVA of sector O is the sum of CE, other taxes less subsidies on production and CFC. The compensation of employees (CE) and other taxes less subsidies on production were taken from the Budget execution account for treasury expenses and from Statistical Yearbook of Lithuania for municipal expenses. Separate compensation of employees for the Klaipėda region and the Lithuanian municipalities was not available. This issue was solved by taking the average salary-to-total ordinary expense ratio from the Budget execution account and using it to calculate CE of Klaipėda region activities, and by taking the average salary-to-total ordinary expense ratio from the municipal accounts (from the yearbook) and using it to calculate CE of municipal activities. Compensation of employees also includes non-monetary salary, like social benefits, etc. As there were not enough data on military activities, an estimation of CE received by soldiers made by Dargis was used. Consumption of fixed capital (CFC) norm for interwar Lithuania was taken from “Makroekonomika” by R. Čiegis.

Table 30 Calculations of GVA from sector O, LT.

In Table 31 the calculations of gross value-added from sector P (Education), are provided. Because there were no data on private education, only public education GVA was calculated here. As public education is a non-market activity, the components of value-added approach had to be used. For non-market activities net operating surplus (NOS) is zero. The GVA of sector P is therefore the sum of CE, other taxes less subsidies on production and CFC. The compensation of employees (CE) and other taxes less subsidies on production were taken from the Budget execution account for treasury expenses and from the Statistical Yearbook of Lithuania for municipal expenses.

Table 31 Calculations of GVA from sector P, LT.

In Table 32 the calculations of gross value-added from sector Q (human health and social work activities) are provided. Because there were no monetary data on social work activities and private health institutions, only public hospitals’ GVA was calculated here. As public human health activities are non-market, the components of value-added approach had to be used. For non-market activities net operating surplus (NOS) is zero. The GVA of sector Q is therefore the sum of CE, other taxes less subsidies on production and CFC. The source for hospital expenditures was the Statistical Yearbook of Lithuania. Consumption of fixed capital (CFC) norm for interwar Lithuania was taken from “Makroekonomika” by R. Čiegis.

Table 32 Calculations of GVA from sector Q, LT.

In Table 33 the Lithuanian gross value-added figures of all ISIC sectors A–U for the year 1937 are presented together and aggregated into one GDP at factor cost figure.

Table 33 Sectorial breakdown of GVA figures and calculation of GDP at factor cost, LT.

In Table 34 Lithuanian gross domestic product at market prices figure is obtained by adding taxes less subsidies on products to GDP at factor cost. Taxes less subsidies on products are the ones already presented in Tables 8, 18, 19, and 24 plus total excise taxes from the Budget execution account.

Table 34 Sectorial breakdown of GVA figures and calculation of GDP at factor cost, LT.

Appendix 3—Difference-in-difference regressions

In Table 35 we run a regression to find the difference-in-difference estimator for the effect of communism on economic growth from 1937 to 1990. Regression was run in order to provide estimates of the standard errors and p-values for the coefficients. The diff-in-diff estimator is the interaction term: 1990*Communism.

Table 35 Difference-in-difference regression.
Table 36 Difference-in-difference regression.

We also attempted to find the diff-in-diff estimator for the communist countries in Europe which were not a part of the Soviet Union to use as a comparison. However, the results of the regression are not statistically significant (Table 36).

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Klimantas, A., Zirgulis, A. A new estimate of Lithuanian GDP for 1937: How does interwar Lithuania compare?. Cliometrica 14, 227–281 (2020). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11698-019-00189-8

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11698-019-00189-8

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation