Skip to main content
Log in

North and south: long-run social mobility in England and attitudes toward welfare

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
Cliometrica Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

In this paper, we examine the long-run social mobility experience in England. We present evidence for surprisingly constant levels of social mobility over the period 1550–1749, despite huge structural changes. Examining regional differences, we show that the North of England exhibited higher rates of social mobility than the South. We link this to the hypothesis that historically high levels of social mobility can lead to a culture of non-acceptance of redistribution and welfare provision. Taking advantage of the fact that welfare provision was determined at the local level at the time, we are able to compare social mobility rates and welfare spending within a single country. Consistent with the hypothesis, we find evidence for historically higher levels of social mobility as well as lower welfare spending and less acceptance of redistribution in the North.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3

Source: Marshall (1834)

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. We have also run the analysis excluding Gainsborough, and though not significant because we lose a lot of observations, our results are otherwise unaffected.

  2. And indeed relatively highly skilled (see for example Abramitzky 2009).

  3. See Xie and Killewald (2013) for a discussion on potential biases in the data used in Long and Ferrie (2013a). See also Long and Ferrie’s reply (2013b).

  4. This was made very much easier by the availability of the Stata program for performing the analysis in the appendix of Altham and Ferrie (2007).

  5. One could also argue that people will only be able to observe social mobility not adjusted for occupational structures and that this should matter for the formation of the sort of beliefs and attitudes toward welfare we discuss in the following section. In our case, differences between the North and the South are in fact larger when comparing unadjusted mobility.

  6. The method has been criticized for not being able to decompose total mobility into structural and exchange mobility (Hout and Guest 2013). We choose this method to be able to compare our results to those of Long and Ferrie (2013a) and due to the advantages of the method, discussed above and in Long and Ferrie (2013a, b).

  7. Note that M’ uses marginal frequencies adjusted to the period 1850–1880, but this measure does not give a significance level. D(X,I) gives a significance level, but measures the difference of the mobility matrix in one period to independence and is thus not adjusted to the period 1850–1880. The choice of the base period does therefore not affect significance levels here.

  8. The difference is statistically insignificant according to the Altham statistics for the different periods.

  9. Results for other countries and other time periods suggest considerable diversity across time and space. Long and Ferrie (2013a) find an Altham statistic of around 12 for the US in the late nineteenth century, increasing to almost 21 one century later. Modalsli (2015) finds an Altham statistic of around 22 for Norway in the period 1960–1980. At the other extreme, it is around 100 in India for cohorts after the Second World War (Azam 2013).

  10. The size of the intergenerational elasticity of earnings is dependent on the standard deviations in the earnings distributions of fathers and sons, i.e., the earnings inequality. It has therefore been suggested to look at the intergenerational correlation (see Blanden et al. 2004), which adjusts for the ratio of the standard deviations. In general, the intergenerational correlation will be larger than the intergenerational elasticity when inequality increases from fathers to sons. Here, we are interested in differences between North and South rather than the absolute size of the association between fathers’ and sons’ earnings. We therefore estimate the intergenerational elasticity, also for easier comparison with previous studies.

  11. It should be noted here that including the southwest of England, Devon and Cornwall, which also had low levels of Poor Law spending, in the ‘North’ makes no difference to our results, since there are few observations from Devon, and none from Cornwall.

  12. ‘Crop suitability index (class) for low input level rain-fed cereals’, from GAEZ, Global Agro-Ecological Zones, at the Food and Agriculture Organization of the United Nations.

  13. See http://www.europeanvaluestudy.eu for a full list of the questions.

References

  • Abramitzky R (2009) The effect of redistribution on migration: evidence from the Israeli kibbutz. J Public Econ 93:498–511

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Alesina A, Giuliano P, Nunn N (2013) On the origins of gender roles: women and the plough. Q J Econ 128(2):469–530

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Altham PME (1970) The measurement of association of rows and columns for an r × s contingency table. J R Stat Soc Ser B (Methodological) 32(1):63–73

    Google Scholar 

  • Altham PME, Ferrie JP (2007) Comparing contingency tables. Tools for analyzing data from two groups cross-classified by two characteristics. Hist Methods 40(1):3–16

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Azam M (2013) Intergenerational occupational mobility in India. IZA discussion paper 7608

  • Billinge M (2012) Divided by a common language: North and South, 1750–1830. Chapter 5. In: Baker ARH, Billinge M (eds) Geographies of England: the North–South divide, material and imagined. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Blanden J, Goodman A, Gregg P, Machin S (2004) Changes in intergenerational mobility in Britain. Chapter 6. In: Corak M (ed) Generational income mobility in North America and Europe. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Blaug M (1963) The myth of the old poor law and the making of the new. J Econ Hist 23(2):151–184

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blaug M (1964) The poor law report reexamined. Journal of Economic History 24(2):229–245

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Boberg-Fazlić N, Sharp P (2017) Does welfare spending crowd out charitable activity? Evidence from historical england under the poor laws. Econ J 127:50–83. doi:10.1111/ecoj.12251

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Boberg-Fazlić N, Sharp P, Weisdorf J (2011) Survival of the richest? Social status, fertility and social mobility in England, 1541–1824. Eur Rev Econ Hist 15:365–392

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Boyer GR (1990) An economic history of the english poor law, 1750–1850. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Buckatzsch EJ (1950) The geographical distribution of wealth in England, 1086–1843: an experimental study of certain tax assessments. Econ Hist Rev New Ser 3(2):180–202

    Google Scholar 

  • Chetty R, Kline P, Hendren N, Saez E (2014) Where is the land of opportunity? The geography of intergenerational mobility in the United States. Q J Econ 129(4):1553–1623

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Clark P (1979) Migration in England during the late seventeenth and early eighteenth centuries. Past Present 83:57–90

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Clark G (2014) The son also rises: surnames and the history of social mobility. Princeton University Press, Princeton

    Google Scholar 

  • Clark G, Cummins N (2015) Intergenerational wealth mobility in England, 1858–2012: surnames and social mobility. Econ J 125:61–85

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Corak M (2004) Generational income mobility in North America and Europe—an introduction. Chapter 1. In: Corak M (ed) Generational income mobility in North America and Europe. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Corak M (2006) Do poor children become poor adults? Lessons from a cross country comparison of generational earnings mobility. Res Econ Inequal 13:143–188

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Easterly W (2007) Inequality does cause underdevelopment: insights from a new instrument. J Dev Econ 84(2):755–776

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Engerman SL, Sokoloff KL (2002) Factor endowments, inequality, and paths of development among new world economies. Econ J Lat Am Caribb Econ Assoc 3(1):41–88

    Google Scholar 

  • Feinstein C (1988) The rise and fall of the Williamson curve’. J Econ Hist 48:699–729

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fong C (2001) Social preferences, self-interest, and the demand for redistribution. J Public Econ 82(2):225–246

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gaskell E (1855) North and South, vol 193. Chapman and Hall, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Hout M, Guest AM (2013) Intergenerational occupational mobility in Great Britain and the United States since 1850: comment. Am Econ Rev 103(5):2021–2040

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hunt EH (1986) Industrialization and regional inequality: wages in Britain, 1760–1914. J Econ Hist 46(4):935–966

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jackson RV (1987) The structure of pay in nineteenth-century Britain. Econ Hist Rev 40:561–570

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jewell HM (1994) The North–South divide: the origins of northern consciousness in England. Manchester University Press, Manchester

    Google Scholar 

  • King S (2000) Poverty and welfare in England, 1700–1850: a regional perspective. Manchester University Press, Manchester

    Google Scholar 

  • Lindahl M, Palme M, Massih SS, Sjögren A (2012) Long-term intergenerational persistence of human capital: an empirical analysis of four generations. J Hum Resour 50(1):1–33

    Google Scholar 

  • Lindert PH, Williamson JG (1982) Revising England’s social tables, 1688–1812. Explor Econ Hist 19(4):385–408

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Linos K, West M (2003) Self-interest, social beliefs, and attitudes to redistribution. Re-adressing the issue of cross-national variation. Eur Sociol Rev 19(4):393–409

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Long J (2013) The surprising social mobility of Victorian Britain. Eur Rev Econ Hist 17:1–27

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Long J, Ferrie J (2012) Grandfathers. Matter (ed) Occupational mobility across three generations in the US and Britain, 1850–1910. http://www.aeaweb.org/aea/2013conference/program/retrieve.php?pdfid=229. Accessed 25 Nov 2015

  • Long J, Ferrie J (2013a) Intergenerational occupational mobility in Great Britain and the United States since 1850. Am Econ Rev 103(4):1109–1137

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Long J, Ferrie J (2013b) Intergenerational occupational mobility in Great Britain and the United States since 1850: reply. Am Econ Rev 103(5):2041–2049

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Malthus T (1798) An essay on the principle of population, 1st edn. J. Johnson, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Marshall J (1834) A digest of all the accounts. J. Hadden, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Marx K (1852) Der Achtzehnte Brumaire des Louis Napoleon. J. Weydemeyer, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Modalsli J (2015) Estimating occupational mobility with covariates. Econ Lett 133:77–80

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nicholas S, Shergold PR (1987) Internal migration in England, 1818–1839. J Hist Geogr 13(2):155–168

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Owen D (1964) English philandthrophy, 1660–1960. The Belknap Press of Harvard University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Piketty T (1995) Social mobility and redistributive politics. Q J Econ 110(3):551–584

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ricardo D (1821) On the principles of political economy and taxation, 3rd edn. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Ruggles S (1999) The limitations of English family reconstitution: English population history from family reconstitution, 1580–1837. Contin Change 14(1):105–130

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schofield RS (1965) The geographical distribution of wealth in England, 1334–1649. Econ Hist Rev New Ser 18(3):483–510

    Google Scholar 

  • Slack P (1990) The English poor law, 1531–1782. Macmillan, London

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Solon G (1992) Intergenerational income mobility in the United States. Am Econ Rev 82(3):393–408

    Google Scholar 

  • Tocqueville AD (1835) De la démocratie en Amérique, 1st edn. Librairie de Charles Gosselin, Paris

  • van Leeuwen MHD, Maas I (2011) Hisclass: a historical international social class scheme. Leuven University Press, Leuven

    Google Scholar 

  • van Leeuwen MHD, Maas I, Miles A, Edvinsson S (2002) HISCO: historical international standard classification of occupations. Leuven University Press, Leuven

    Google Scholar 

  • Webb S, Webb B (1927) English poor law history. Part I: the old poor law. Longmans, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Williamson JG (1982) The structure of pay in Britain, 1710–1911. Res Econ Hist 7:1–54

    Google Scholar 

  • Wrigley EA, Davies R, Oeppen J, Schofield R (1997) English population history from family reconstitution. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Xie Y, Killewald A (2013) Intergenerational occupational mobility in Great Britain and the United States since 1850: comment. Am Econ Rev 103(5):2003–2020

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

We would like to thank Gregory Clark, Nicholas Crafts, Carl-Johan Dalgaard, Marc Klemp, Andreea-Alexandra Maerean, Karl Gunnar Persson, Ulrich Pfister, Eric Schneider, Jacob Weisdorf as well as participants at seminars and conferences for their help and suggestions. Thanks also to the Cambridge Group for allowing us to use the family reconstitution data.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Paul Sharp.

Appendix

Appendix

See Figs. 4 and 5 and Tables 7, 8, 9, 10, 11 and 12.

Fig. 4
figure 4

Source: Marshall (1834)

Relief spending per recipient by county, 1803.

Fig. 5
figure 5

Source: Marshall (1834)

Number of poor relief recipients by county, 1803.

Table 7 Frequencies of observations by occupational group and location
Table 8 Examples of occupations in the four groups
Table 9 Mobility tables, intergenerational occupational mobility in Northern England, 100-year periods
Table 10 Mobility tables, intergenerational occupational mobility in Southern England, 100-year periods
Table 11 Components of d(North,I), d(South,I) and d(South,North), pre-1650
Table 12 Components of d(North,I), d(South,I) and d(South,North), 1650–1749

We have coded all the occupations in the dataset according to the HISCO classification scheme. HISCO, the historical version of the ISCO scheme, gives a code to each occupation based on the duties and tasks performed in the occupation. These are then grouped together into different “social classes” according to the degree of supervision exercised and whether the occupation was manual or non-manual. This scheme is called HISCLASS and gives a total of 12 “social classes”, with class 12 being the lowest and class 1 the highest. For more details on HISCO and HISCLASS, see also van Leeuwen et al. (2002) and van Leeuwen and Maas (2011).

Whenever the specific occupation/HISCO code in our data is not available in one of Williamson’s wage groups we assign an average of one or several, similar wage groups to the occupation according to the HISCLASS it is in. We do this according to the following scheme: Table 13.

Table 13 Link from HISCLASS to Williamson wage groups

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Boberg-Fazlić, N., Sharp, P. North and south: long-run social mobility in England and attitudes toward welfare. Cliometrica 12, 251–276 (2018). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11698-017-0160-2

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11698-017-0160-2

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation