Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Who opposes climate regulation? Business preferences for the European emission trading scheme

  • Published:
The Review of International Organizations Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

When do firms oppose international climate policy? Existing work often assumes that firms disapprove of climate regulation due to the immediate costs of compliance. We claim that if policy is implemented gradually, private preferences for climate policy vary as a function of its progressive stringency. That is, supportive views may rise in the initial phase of the policy, while opposing views may emerge as the policy becomes more stringent. We also argue that emissions of individual companies, as well as emissions levels in their respective sectors, influence corporate positions on these two dimensions. We test our argument with new corporate survey data on the European Union Emission Trading Scheme (EU ETS). We find that firms’ views on the performance of the EU ETS vary based on whether they concentrate on the policy’s current state or its future, more stringent development. Moreover, we find that individual firm and sectoral emissions correlate with support for the early-stage, more lenient version of the ETS, but that high-emission firms are more interested in disinvesting and relocating if the ETS becomes stricter. Our findings imply that both firm and sectoral organization can constrain environmental regulation, and that domestic compensation, especially at early stages, can have important effects on the continuity of climate policy.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. The Guardian. 2015. More Big Businesses Push For Stricter Environmental Regulations. http://www.theguardian.com/sustainable-business/2015/feb/04/business-manifesto-sustainability-guidelines-climate-policy.

  2. Carbon trading has arguably stimulated more disagreements than less flexible top-down measures, such as a carbon tax, or more discretionary measures, such as voluntary carbon standards.

  3. In the words of Meckling (2011), “to some industries, such as the oil, electricity, and energy-intensive manufacturing ones, engagement with climate policy is about managing and containing regulatory risk. Other industries including low-carbon technology producers, financial services providers, and investors can seize opportunities under a market-based climate regime” (p. 23).

  4. Note that our discussion purposefully ignores the preferences that firms may have for implementing no ETS at all. For the European ETS the possibility of abandoning altogether the carbon market is unrealistic. Nonetheless, this is not an irrelevant policy equilibrium in other contexts, and further work may want to elaborate on this potential alternative outcome.

  5. Specifically, up to three e-mail addresses for each covered emitting facility are listed. Participants receive a free copy of the resulting survey report as an incentive to complete the survey.

  6. See Eurostat data on EU structural business statistics at http://ec.europa.eu/eurostat/statistics-explained/index.php/Structural_business_statistics_overview.

  7. See Eurostat data on breakdown of economic activities in EU total employment at http://ec.europa.eu/eurostat/web/products-eurostat-news/-/DDN-20171024-1?inheritRedirect=true.

  8. Using the post-2008 surveys is also reasonable because it allows us to concentrate on firms’ positions during the first commitment period of the Kyoto Protocol and after the recent financial crisis. We need to ignore the 2007 survey because it lacks information on the companies’ countries, while the 2008 survey lacks information on sectors. We also ignore the 2014 survey responses because, although we received the data, some questions had different wordings and we do not possess several control variables.

  9. These are: Austria, Belgium, Bulgaria, Croatia, Czech Republic, Denmark, Estonia, Finland, France, Germany, Greece, Hungary, Iceland Ireland, Italy, Latvia, Lithuania, Luxembourg, Malta, Netherlands, Norway, Poland, Portugal, Romania, Slovak Republic, Slovenia, Spain, Sweden, and the United Kingdom. See Fig. A.1.

  10. Population data used in this table was gathered from the European Environmental Agency, 2016. See http://www.eea.europa.eu/data-and-maps/indicators/greenhouse-gas-emission-trends-5/assessment-1, Fig. 4, and http://www.eea.europa.eu/publications/trends-and-projections-2013, Fig. 2.1 (p. 21).

  11. See European Commission brief on the EU ETS at https://ec.europa.eu/clima/sites/clima/files/factsheet_ets_en.pdf.

  12. See Eurostat data on total GHG emissions for 1990-2015 at http://ec.europa.eu/eurostat/statistics-explained/index.php/Greenhouse_gas_emission_statistics.

  13. One may worry that the different wording of these survey items – i.e., that some require comments on statements and some require answers to questions – may affect the nature of the responses. Consequently, we may be pooling subjective and objective responses rather opinions on different temporal aspects of the EU ETS. While we cannot completely rule out this concern, we think all responses are in part subjective because they all require an interpretation of firms’ ideal policy levels and preferred regulatory uncertainty. Also, in the open comment answers (formulated as “If needed, please expand on your answers here”) we find no evidence that the questions were systematically interpreted as objective versus subjective questions. For example, to the presumably more objective question on the possibility of relocation, a 2012 respondent commented, “I think carbon leakage is a daily threat.” Similarly, to the question on the importance of CO2 price for future investments, another respondent wrote, “I suspect we will be heavily influenced in the future”. These responses appear as subjective rather than factual statements.

  14. In terms of how sensitive the manipulated variables are to the cut-points, analyses in the Online Appendix available at this journal’s website (Table A.4) show that the five variables measured on the original scales have similar patterns (i.e., are loaded on the same factors) as the dichotomized variables. Similarly, additional regression analyses (Table A.5) indicate that our findings are not sensitive to the cut-points of the binary variables, as we obtain similar results with the outcomes measured on the original scales.

  15. The WRI data can be retrieved here: http://cait.wri.org/historical/. For the year 2013, we used the equivalent indicators reported in the International Energy Agency 2015 Statistics, https://www.iea.org/publications/freepublications/publication/CO%24_2%24EmissionsFromFuelCombustionHighlights2015.pdf(p. 66).

  16. The ULC is calculated as the ratio of total labour costs to real output, and it is expressed as the ratio of total labour compensation per hour worked to output per hour workfed. See OECD 2015 data at https://stats.oecd.org/Index.aspx?DataSetCode=PDBI_I4#.

  17. We assigned ULC of oil and power to Power and Heat, Metals, and Oil and Gas; ULC of manufacture to Pulp and Paper, Cement, Lime and Glass, and Chemicals; and ULC of transportation and food to Aviation and Food Industry.

  18. Armingeon et al. (2015).

  19. Genovese et al. (2017).

  20. OECD-IEA Fossil Fuel Support Data. 2015. http://www.oecd.org/site/tadffss/.

  21. Note that stringency in this case does not necessarily reflect the price level, but rather the share of auctioned permits and the perceived likelihood that the ETS will be around for the long haul, as signaled by the European Commission’s long-term target planning.

  22. The cross-loadings measured by the uniqueness parameter (ψ) indicate for each variable the proportion of the individual variance that is associated with their factors. As the results indicate, opinions on cost-effectiveness and relocation are more uniquely associated with the two factors, respectively. This further suggests that the data are divided on two types of positions, which distinctly reflect the dual nature of opinions towards the EU ETS.

  23. One may also wonder whether hierarchical models may be more appropriate given the multilevel structure of our data. Exploratory tests suggest that the hierarchy does not capture much random variance, and neither countries nor sectors seem to have specific group-level effects on firms’ opinions. Moreover, our dataset features similar sample sizes across countries. We refer to these additional findings below.

  24. Again, the changes over time in attitudes toward the ETS in Figs. 1 and 2 support the reasoning that larger firms more positively related to the EU ETS in earlier years, while smaller firms more positively saw the EU ETS from 2012 onwards. This trend could conceivably be related to falling carbon prices; however, it can be shown that permit prices do not play a significant role in explaining attitudes toward the ETS in our data.

  25. Random-effect models that calculate the variance at the country level and at the country-sector level show that neither country nor sector intercepts capture much of the residual variance, and that the effects of the emission indicators remain qualitatively similar to the effects estimated in the main models. Furthermore, in additional regressions we transformed the composite scores into dichotomized variables where we assign 1 to positive scores (> 0), and 0 otherwise. We find that the firm- and sector-level emissions have consistent effects if we analyze these scores with probit and linear models. See Tables A.6 and A.7 in the online Appendix available at this journal’s website.

  26. See Tables A.8 and A.9 in the online Appendix available at this journal’s website.

  27. See Tables A.10 and A.11 in the online Appendix available at this journal’s website. Note that in Table A.10 the difference between high emitters and low emitters is statistically meaningful because the confidence intervals of the coefficient estimates for the firm’s GHG variables do not overlap.

  28. See Table A.12 in the online Appendix available at this journal’s website.

  29. See Table A.13 in the online Appendix available at this journal’s website.

  30. See Table A.14 in the online Appendix available at this journal’s website.

  31. See Tables A.15 and A.16 in the online Appendix available at this journal’s website.

  32. On the maturity question, by contrast, there is no difference across the groups.

  33. See Table A.17.

  34. Later, from 2014 onwards, the respondents were asked more generally to evaluate cap-and-trade as a climate policy tool in a separate part of the survey, using the question ”Please share your view on cap-and-trade as a policy instrument for emission abatement.” To avoid issues related to wording variation and to stay consistent with the years covered by our observational data, we focus only on the 2007-2013 texts.

  35. Note that the the 944 meaningful open answers are not representative of the full universe of EU firms, but that there is substantive structural variation in the firms to which these comments correspond. Furthermore, note that the volume of open comments analyzed here is similar in magnitude to the number of open answers studied in Roberts et al. (2014).

  36. See Table A.18.

References

  • Ambec, S., Coheny, M.A., Elgiez, S., Lanoie, P. (2013). The porter hypothesis at 20: can environmental regulation enhance innovation and competitiveness? Review of Environmental Economics and Policy, 7(1), 2–22.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Armingeon, K., Careja, R., Potolidis, P., Gerber, M., Weisstanner, D. (2015). Comparative political data set 1990-2013., Technical report, Bern Switzerland. Institute of Political Science, University of Berne.

  • Auld, G., Bernstein, S., Cashore, B. (2008). The new corporate social responsibility. Annual Review of Enviornment and Resources, 33, 413–435.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baldwin, R.E., & Forslid, R. (2010). Trade liberalization with heterogeneous firms. Review of Development Economics, 14(2), 161–176.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bechtel, M.M., Genovese, F., Scheve, K.F. (2018). Interests, norms, and support for the provision of global public goods: The case of climate cooperation. British Journal of Political Science, Forthcoming.

  • Bernauer, T., Böhmelt, T., Koubi, V. (2013). Is there a democracy-civil society paradox in global environmental governance. Global Environmental Politics, 13(1), 88–107.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Böhmelt, T. (2013). Civil society lobbying and countries’ climate change policies: a matching approach. Climate Policy, 13(6), 698–717.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brooks, S.M., & Kurtz, M.J. (2007). Capital, trade, and the political economies of reform. American Journal of Political Science, 51(4), 703–720.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Büthe, T., & Mattli, W. (2011). The new global rulers: the privatization of regulation in the World economy. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Cao, X., & Prakash, A. (2010). Trade competition and domestic pollution: a panel study, 1980–2003. International Organization, 64(3), 481–503.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Damania, R., Fredriksson, P.G., List, J.A. (2003). Trade liberalization, corruption, and environmental policy formation: theory and evidence. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 46(3), 490–512.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • De Massis, A., Sharma, P., Chua, J., Chrisman, J. (2012). Family business studies: an annotated bibliography. Edward Elgar Publishing.

  • Dimantchev, E., Lawson, A., Ferdinand, M., Chai, H., Nordeng, A., Fjellheim, H., Schjølset, S., Melum, F. (2013). Carbon 2013: at a tipping point.

  • Fernandez, R., & Rodrik, D. (1991). Resistance to reform: status quo bias in the presence of individual-specific uncertainty. American Economic Review, 81(5), 1146–55.

    Google Scholar 

  • Genovese, F., Kern, F., Martin, C. (2017). Policy alteration: rethinking diffusion processes when policies have alternatives. International Studies Quarterly, 61(2), 236–252.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hacker, J., & Pierson, P. (2002). Business power and social policy: employers and the formation of the american welfare state. Politics & Society, 30, 277–325.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Helpman, E., Melitz, M.J., Yeaple, S.R. (2004). Export versus fdi with heterogeneous firms. American Economic Review, 94(1), 300–316.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kim, I.S. (2017). Political cleavages within industry: Firm-level lobbying for trade liberalization. American Political Science Review, 111(1), 1–20.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kim, S.E., Urpelainen, J., Yang, J. (2016). Electric utilities and american climate policy: lobbying by expected winners and losers. Journal of Public Policy, 36 (2), 251–175.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Levy, D.L., & Kolk, A. (2002). Strategic responses to global climate change. conflicting pressures on multinationals in the oil industry. Business and Politics, 4, 275–300.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lyon, T.P., & Maxwell, J.W. (2008). Corporate social responsibility and the environment: a theoretical perspective. Review of Environmental Economics and Policy, 2(2), 240–260.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mattli, W., & Woods, N. (2009). The politics of global regulation. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Meckling, J. (2011). Carbon coalitions: business, climate politics, and the rise of emissions trading. MIT Press.

  • Meckling, J. (2015). Oppose, support, or hedge? distributional effects, regulatory pressure, and business strategy in environmental politics. Global Environmental Politics.

  • Meckling, J., Kelsey, N., Biber, E., Zysman, J. (2015). Winning coalitions for climate policy. Science, 349(1170).

  • Murphy, D.D. (2004). Dynamics of regulatory change: how globalization affects national regulatory policies, (pp. 84–117). London: University of California Press. Chapter The business dynamics of global regulatory competition.

    Google Scholar 

  • Olson, M. (1965). The logic of collective action: public goods and the theory of interest groups. Harvard University Press.

  • Ostrom, E. (2010). Polycentric systems for coping with collective action and global environmental change. Global Environmental Change, 20(4), 550–557.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Paterson, M. (2012). Who and what are carbon markets for? politics and the development of climate policy. Climate Policy, 12, 82–97.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Perkins, R., & Neumayer, E. (2012). Does the california effect’ operate across borders? Trading- and investing-up in automobile emission standards. Journal of European Public Policy, 19(2), 217–237.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pierson, P. (1993). When effect becomes cause: policy feedback and political change. World Politics, 45(4), 595–628.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Roberts, M.E., Stewart, B.M., Tingley, D. (2014). STM: R package for structural topic models. Journal of Statistical Software.

  • Roberts, M.E., Stewart, B.M., Tingley, D., Lucas, C., Leder-Luis, J., Gadarian, S.K., Albertson, B., Ran, D.G. (2014). Structural topic models for open-ended survey responses. American Journal of Political Science, 58 (4), 1064–1082.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Røine, K., Tvinnereim, E., Hasselknippe, H. (2008). Carbon 2008: post-2012 is now. Point Carbon Annual Survey Report., 11.

  • Szakonyi, D., & Urpelainen, J. (2014). Who benefits from economic reform? Firms and distributive politics. Journal of Politics, 76(3), 841–858.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tvinnereim, E. (2015). Explaining topic prevalence in answers to open-ended survey questions about climate change. Nature Climate Change, 5, 744–747.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Urpelainen, J. (2010). Regulation under economic globalization. International Studies Quarterly, 54(4), 1099–1121.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Venkatachalam, I. (2008). Behavioral economics for environmental policy. Ecological Economics, 67, 640–645.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Victor, D.G., & House, J.C. (2006). BP’s emissions trading scheme. Energy Policy, 34, 2100–2112.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Whaller, N., & Whitehead, B. (1994). It’s not easy being green. Harvard Business Review, 72(3), 46–52.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

We thank Stig Schjølset and Anders Nordeng at Thomson Reuters for data access, and Roman-Gabriel Olar and Luis Everdy Mejia for research assistance. We are also grateful to Michaël Aklin, Jacob Copas, Iza Ding, Julia Gray, Megan Mullin, Jakob Skovgaard, Paul Tobin, Simon Weschle, the editor Axel Dreher, two anonymous reviewers, and the APSA 2015, EPSA 2016, IPSA 2016 and the 2017 InoGov Durham workshop participants for very useful feedback.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Federica Genovese.

Electronic supplementary material

Below is the link to the electronic supplementary material.

(PDF 786 KB)

(ZIP 596 KB)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Genovese, F., Tvinnereim, E. Who opposes climate regulation? Business preferences for the European emission trading scheme. Rev Int Organ 14, 511–542 (2019). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11558-018-9318-3

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11558-018-9318-3

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation