Skip to main content
Log in

Learning to save in a voluntary pension system: toward an agent-based model

  • Regular Article
  • Published:
Journal of Economic Interaction and Coordination Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Mandatory pension systems partially replace old-age income, therefore the government matches additional life-cycle savings in a voluntary pension system. Though the individual saving decisions are apparently independent, the earmarked taxes (paid to finance the matching) connect them. Previous models either neglected the endogenous tax expenditures (e.g. Choi et al., in: Wise (ed) Perspectives in the economics of aging, University of Chicago Press, Chicago, pp 81–121, 2004) or assumed very sophisticated saving strategies (e.g. Fehr et al. in FinanzArchiv Pub Finance Anal 64:171–198, 2008). We create twin models: myopic workers learn (i) from farsighted workers using public information (analytic model) and (ii) also from each other (agent-based model). These models provide more realistic results on saving behavior and the impact of matching on the income redistribution than the earlier models.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5
Fig. 6

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. In a previous version, Király and Simonovits (2016) used the expression global learning for learning by using public information.

  2. For example, in a calibrated general equilibrium model of the German economy, Fehr et al. (2008) showed that if the voluntary pillar is extended, then existing generations lose and future generations gain. In addition, the assumption of rational expectations makes the foregoing models extremely complex (for an alternative with naive expectations, see Molnár and Simonovits 1998).

  3. For the sake of simplicity, we forbid shortsighted workers to learn from farsighted workers but as suggested personally by Botond Kőszegi, its inclusion would open the door to an alternative learning mechanism not using government-made information like \(\alpha \) and especially \(\theta \).

  4. Note that even extending the rules to allow learning from farsighted workers would not significantly improve learning. Upon request, we can send an unpublished document showing this.

References

  • Auerbach AJ, Kotlikoff LJ (1987) Dynamic fiscal policy. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Baily MN, Kirkegaard JF (2009) US pension reform: lessons from other countries. Petersons Books, Washington D.C

    Google Scholar 

  • Barr N, Diamond P (2008) Reforming pensions: principles and policy choices. Oxford University Press, Oxford

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Bertotti ML, Modanese G (2016) Mathematical models describing the effects of different tax evasion behaviors. J Econ Interact Coord. https://doi.org/10.1007/s11403-016-0185-9

  • Chetty R (2015) Behavioral economics and public policy: a pragmatic approach. Am Econ Rev Papers Proc 105:1–33

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Choi J, Laibson D, Madrian B, Metrick A (2004) For better or worse: default effects and 401(k) saving behavior. In: Wise D (ed) Perspectives in the economics of aging. University of Chicago Press, Chicago, pp 81–121

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Duflo E, Saez E (2003) The role of information and social interaction in retirement decisions. Quart J Econ 111:815–842

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Duflo E, Gale W, Liebman J, Orszag P, Saez E (2007) Saving incentives for low- and moderate income families in the United States: why is saver’s credit not more effective? J Eur Econ Assoc 5:647–661

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Engen EM, Gale WG, Scholz J (1996) The illusory effects of saving incentives on saving. J Econ Perspect 10(4):111–138

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Erdős P, Rényi A (1959) Random graphs I. Publ Math 6:290–297

    Google Scholar 

  • Fehr H, Habermann C, Kindermann F (2008) Tax-favored retirement accounts: are they efficient in increasing savings and growth? FinanzArchiv Pub Finance Anal 64:171–198

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Feldstein MS (1985) The level of social security benefits. Q J Econ 100:302–320

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hinz R, Holzmann R, Tuesta D, Takayama N (eds) (2013) Matching contributions for pensions. World Bank, Washington D.C

    Google Scholar 

  • Hubbard RG, Skinner JS (1996) Assessing the effectiveness of saving incentives. J Econ Perspect 10(4):73–90

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Király B, Simonovits A (2016) Saving and taxation in voluntary pension systems: toward an agend-based model. IE-CERS-HAS Working Paper, 6

  • Lusardi A, Mitchell O (2014) The economic importance of financial literacy: theory and evidence. J Econ Lit 52:5–44

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Méder Zs, Simonovits A, Vincze J (2012) Tax morale and tax evasion: social preferences and bounded rationality. Econ Anal Policy 42:171–188

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Modigliani F, Brumberg R (1954) Utility analysis and the consumption function: an interpretation of cross-section data. In: Kurihara KK (ed) Post-Keynesian economics. Rutgers University Press, New Brunswick, pp 388–436

    Google Scholar 

  • Molnár Gy, Simonovits A (1998) Expectations, (in)stability and (in)viability in realistic overlapping cohorts models. J Econ Dyn Control 23:303–332

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • OECD (2005) Tax-favored retirement saving. OECD Economic Studies, 39, Paris

  • Pickhard M, Prinz A (2013) Behavioral dynamics of tax evasion - a survey. J Econ Psychol 39:45–60

  • Poterba JM, Venti SF, Wise DA (1996) How retirement saving program increase saving. J Econ Perspect 10(4):91–112

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Samuelson PA (1958) An exact consumption-loan model of interest with or without the social contrivance of money. J Polit Econ 66:467–482

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Simonovits A (2011) When are voluntary pensions indifferent. Econ Lett 111:153–155

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tesfatsion L (2006) Agent-based computational economics: a constructive approach to economic theory. In: Tesfatsion L, Judd KL (eds) Handbook of computational economics, vol 2. Elsevier, Amsterdam, pp 831–880

    Google Scholar 

  • Thaler RH, Benartzi Sh (2004) Save more tomorrow: using behavioral economics to increase employee saving. J Polit Econ 112:S164–S187

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Varga G, Vincze J (2017) Savers types: an evolutionary-adaptive approach. IE-CERS-HAS Working Paper 2

Download references

Acknowledgements

We thank Cars Hommes, Botond Kőszegi, Gergely Varga, Tamás Vicsek, János Vincze and the anonymous referees of this Journal for their useful comments, especially for calling our attention to the imperfect formulation of the transition from zero to positive matching in Király and Simonovits (2016) which is longer and can be found on the web. We express our gratitude for the generous grant of the Hungarian Research Foundation (OTKA) under grant number 108668.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to András Simonovits.

Electronic supplementary material

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Király, B., Simonovits, A. Learning to save in a voluntary pension system: toward an agent-based model. J Econ Interact Coord 14, 121–145 (2019). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11403-018-0218-7

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11403-018-0218-7

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation