Skip to main content
Log in

Capital Theory and the Process of Inter-Temporal Coordination: The Austrian Contribution to the Theory of Economic Growth

  • Published:
Atlantic Economic Journal Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Appreciation of the necessity of the inter-temporal coordination of heterogeneous capital goods is the chief contribution of Austrian economics to the theory of economic growth. Austrian theory illustrates why an institutional environment of freely formed prices predicated on private property is essential for economic growth. This leads Austrians to have a unique take on Solow growth theory, the financing gap model, national economic planning, and aggregative development measures.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. For more on how capital theory serves as the bridge between the “micro” and the “macro” in Austrian economics, see Garrison (1984), Garrison and Bellante (1988) and Horwitz (2000).

  2. Following Rothbard (2009 [1962]: 483–88; 496–500) and Hayek (2009 [1941]: 50–65), we can define “land” as consisting of all the nature-given, material factors of production as well as the previously produced factors that are physically permanent and need no maintenance or replacement. Capital goods, on the other hand, consist of the previously produced, physically impermanent resources and thus need maintenance and eventual replacement. Stated differently, they eventually wear out.

  3. This increased utility can consist of a greater quantity of the goods produced by the shorter processes already adopted or of goods that yield greater utility and are thus more highly valued but are impossible to produce using shorter processes.

  4. For a more detailed analysis of the trade-offs involved in any lengthening of the structure of production in both a Robinson Crusoe setting as well as in a modern economy, see Böhm Bawerk (1959a: 102–118), Mises (1998 [1949]: 476–499) and Rothbard (2009 [1962]: p. 47–70 and 390–409).

  5. On the time market and its relationship to the production structure, see Rothbard (2009 [1962]: 367–452) and Böhm Bawerk (1959a: book IV).

  6. The phrase “production process” here refers to the entire process culminating in a consumer good. On the market, this process is seldom undertaken by a single entrepreneur, unless the entire production process of a consumer good is completely vertically integrated. Instead, each such process is sub-divided into many sub-processes, each of which is carried out by one entrepreneur. It follows that the “two zero points” are calculated from the revenues derived from the sale of the consumer good that ultimately flows from this process and the costs incurred on all the resources utilized from start to finish in its production.

  7. For more on the categorization of goods into various orders and the concept of stages of production, see Menger (2007 [1871]: 52–77, Böhm Bawerk (1959a: 169) and Rothbard (2009 [1962]: 8–10).

  8. For a detailed exposition of how a lowering of the rate of social time preference leads to a lengthening of the production structure and therefore economic growth, see Hayek (1967 [1931]), Garrison (2001: 57–83) and Rothbard (2009 [1962]: 517–527).

  9. The classic exposition of capital heterogeneity and its implications is Lachmann (1956). For a more recent treatment of the same see Lewin (2011).

  10. In this regard, the conclusions of the Austrian theory of growth differ from those of the famous Solow model (Solow 1956).

  11. For an excellent exposition of how the Austrian theory of growth provides the necessary theoretical lens for understanding the historical growth process, see Shenoy (2007, 2010).

  12. See Berggren (2003) for a somewhat dated survey of this literature and www.freetheworld.org for a website with many of the more recent papers using the index.

References

  • Acemoglu, D., Johnson, S., & Robinson, J. (2001). The colonial origins of comparative development: an empirical investigation. American Economic Review, 91, 1369–1401.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Berggren, N. (2003). The benefits of economic freedom. The Independent Review, 8(2), 193–211.

    Google Scholar 

  • Boettke, P. (1990). The political economy of soviet socialism, 1918–1928. Norwell: Kluwer Academic Publishers.

    Google Scholar 

  • Böhm Bawerk, E. v. (1959a). Positive theory of capital. South Holland: Libertarian Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Böhm Bawerk, E. v. (1959b). Further essays on capital and interest. South Holland: Libertarian Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Easterly, W. (2001). The elusive quest for growth. Cambridge: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Garrison, R. (1984). Time and money: the universals of macroeconomic theorizing. Journal of Macroeconomics, 6(2), 197–213.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Garrison, R. (2001). Time and money: The macroeconomics of capital structure. New York: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Garrison, R., & Bellante, D. (1988). Phillips curves and Hayekian triangles: two perspectives on monetary dynamics. History of Political Economy, 20(2), 207–234.

    Google Scholar 

  • Glaeser, E., & Shleifer, A. (2002). Legal origins. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 117(4), 1193–1229.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gwartney, J., Lawson, R., & Hall, J. (2011). Economic freedom of the world annual report. Vancouver: Fraser Institute.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hayek, F. A. (1948). Individualism and economic order. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hayek, F.A. (1967 [1931]), Prices and production, New York: Augustus M. Kelly.

  • Hayek, F.A. (2009 [1941]), The pure theory of capital, Auburn: Mises Institute.

  • Higgs, R. (1992). Wartime prosperity? a reassessment of the american economy in the 1940s. Journal of Economic History, 52(1), 41–60.

    Google Scholar 

  • Horwitz, S. (2000). Microfoundations and macroeconomics: An Austrian perspective. New York: Routledge.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Lachmann, L. (1956). Capital and its structure. Kansas City: Sheed, Andrews and McMeel.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lavoie, D. (1985). National economic planning: What is left? Cambridge: Ballinger Publishing Company.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lewin, P. (2011). Capital in disequilibrium: The role of capital in a changing world. Auburn: Mises Institute.

    Google Scholar 

  • Manish, G. P. (2010). Central economic planning and India’s economic performance, 1951–65. The Independent Review, 16(2), 199–219.

    Google Scholar 

  • Manish, G.P. (2013a), “Qualitative aspects of the indian growth spurt of the 1980s,” Review of Austrian economics, published online 24 February 2013, forthcoming.

  • Manish, G. P. (2013b). Market reforms in India and the quality of economic growth. The Independent Review, 18(2), 241–262.

    Google Scholar 

  • Menger, C. (2007 [1871]), Principles of economics, Auburn: Mises Institute.

  • Mises, L.V. (1990 [1920]), Economic calculation in the socialist commonwealth, Auburn: Mises Institute.

  • Mises, L.V. (1998 [1949]), Human action: A treatise on economics, Auburn: Mises Institute.

  • North, D. (1990). Institutions, institutional change, and economic performance. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Nutter, G. W. (1962). The growth of industrial production in the soviet union. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Powell, B. (2005). State development planning: did it create an east Asian miracle? Review of Austrian Economics, 18(3/4), 305–323.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rodrik, D., & Subramanian, A. (2005). Hindu growth to productivity surge: the mystery of the Indian growth transition. IMF Staff Papers, 52(2), 193–228.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rothbard, M.N. (2009 [1962]), Man, economy and state, Auburn: Mises Institute.

  • Shenoy, S. R. (2007). Investment chains through history or an historian’s outline of development. Indian Journal of Economics and Business, 7(3), 185–215.

    Google Scholar 

  • Shenoy, S. R. (2010). Towards a theoretical framework for British and international economic history. Auburn: Mises Institute.

    Google Scholar 

  • Solow, R. M. (1956). A contribution to the theory of economic growth. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 70(1), 65–94.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Williamson, C. (2009). Informal institutions rule: institutional arrangements and economic performance. Public Choice, 139, 371–387.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to G. P. Manish.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Manish, G.P., Powell, B. Capital Theory and the Process of Inter-Temporal Coordination: The Austrian Contribution to the Theory of Economic Growth. Atl Econ J 42, 133–142 (2014). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11293-014-9404-8

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11293-014-9404-8

Keywords

JEL

Navigation