Skip to main content
Log in

Home bias in portfolio choices: social learning among partially informed agents

  • Original Research
  • Published:
Review of Quantitative Finance and Accounting Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Using an ‘incomplete information’ model, we explore the role of social learning in the global portfolio choices of stock market investors. When partially informed followers attempt to estimate true domestic (home) mean returns, they likely acquire private domestic signals from partially informed leaders. However, the calibration results indicate the existence of home bias when partially informed agents have poor quality information. Partially informed agents are prone to a learning bias; they overreact to new domestic information due to overconfidence in their domestic private signals, but they demonstrate a conservative response to new information in foreign markets. Links between the private signals of partially informed agents may lead to correlated foreign investment strategies among such agents through social learning. We suggest the acquisition of private signals, along with the dissemination of information, affect international portfolio decision rules and are determinants of the phenomenon of home bias.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. For recent estimates across countries, see Table 1 in Gau et al. (2010).

  2. For detailed surveys of home bias literature, see Lewis (1999) and Cooper et al. (2013).

  3. This tendency is confirmed by growing evidence on home bias, as demonstrated by Karlsson and Norden (2007) and Lutje and Menkhoff (2007).

  4. For social learning models, see Cao et al. (2011) and Kaustia and Knupfer (2012); reviews of social learning in the field of finance are provided by Hirshleifer and Teoh (2003).

  5. A detailed survey of the incomplete information model is provided by Feldman (2007).

  6. The same methodology for solving for equilibria with incomplete information can be employed to solve for the case with complete information, because it is possible to restate the incomplete information non-Markovian problem as an σ-algebraic equivalent of the complete information Markovian problem (Feldman 2007).

  7. Merton (1980) demonstrates that in reality, expected returns are notoriously more difficult to estimate than variances; Chopra and Ziemba (1993) suggest that accurate means forecasting is critical to mean–variance frameworks.

  8. Regardless of the value taken by \(\xi\) and ϕ, the optimal portfolio weight of all agents is still restricted to within the range of 0 ≤ θ B  ≤ 1.

  9. Brandt et al. (2004) suggest that conservatism could be interpreted as a person’s overconfidence in his or her ability to learn.

  10. Social learning can also arise as a result of a change in the behavior of the followers in our study, resulting in their acting against the crowd (Eyster and Rabin 2011; Park and Sabourian 2011); that is, some followers have contrarian behavior in the model, viewing the good news possessed by their leaders as a signal of bad news, such that they expect a reversal in current trends. Therefore, their estimation of the mean domestic returns may be more accurate than their better-informed leaders, because their domestic private signal relates negatively to that of their counterparts (ρ L,F  = − 0.99). Their contrarian behavior also enlarges their information sets and enhances their prior beliefs. Under the same scenario, they may have less hedging demand for their global portfolio choices than their leaders, such that they lean toward the benchmark weights suggested by mean–variance optimization.

References

  • Ahearne A, Griever W, Warnock F (2004) Information costs and home bias: an analysis of US holdings of foreign equities. J Int Econ 62:313–336

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Avery C, Zemsky P (1998) Multidimensional uncertainty and herd behavior in financial markets. Am Econ Rev 88:724–748

    Google Scholar 

  • Back K (2004) Incomplete and asymmetric information in asset pricing theory. In: Frittelli M, Runggaldier W (eds) Stochastic methods in finance. Springer, Berlin, pp 1–25

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Baele L, Pungulescu C, Ter Horst J (2007) Model uncertainty, financial market integration and the home bias puzzle. J Int Money Finance 26:606–630

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Banerjee A (1992) A simple model of herd behavior. Q J Econ 107:797–817

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barber B, Odean T (2000) Trading is hazardous to your wealth: the common stock investment performance of individual investors. J Finance 55:773–806

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Berrada T (2009) Bounded rationality and asset pricing with intermediate consumption. Rev Finance 13:693–725

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bihkchandani S, Hirshleifer D, Welch I (1992) A theory of fads, fashion, custom and cultural change as informational cascades. J Polit Econ 100:992–1026

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brandt M, Zeng Q, Zhang L (2004) Equilibrium stock return dynamics under alternative rules of learning about hidden states. J Econ Dyn Control 28:1925–1954

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brennan MJ (1998) The role of learning in dynamic portfolio decisions. Eur Finance Rev 1:295–306

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brennan M, Cao H (1997) International portfolio investment flows. J Finance 52:1858–1880

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brown J, Ivkovic Z, Smith P, Weisbenner S (2008) Neighbors matter: causal community effects and stock market participation. J Finance 63:1509–1531

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cao H, Han B, Hirshleifer D (2011) Taking the road less traveled by: does conversation eradicate pernicious cascades? J Econ Theory 146:1418–1436

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chiou P, Lee C-F (2013) Do investors still benefit from culturally home-biased diversification? An empirical study of China, Hong Kong, and Taiwan. Rev Quant Finance Acc 40:341–381

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chopra V, Ziemba W (1993) The effect of errors in means, variances, and covariances on optimal portfolio choice. J Portf Manag 19:6–11

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Colla P, Mele A (2010) Information linkages and correlated trading. Rev Finance Stud 23:203–246

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cooper I, Sercu P, Vanpee R (2013) The equity home bias puzzle: a survey. Found Trends Finance 7:289–416

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Coval J, Moskowitz T (2001) The geography of investment: informed trading and asset prices. J Polit Econ 109:811–841

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cronqvist H (2006) Advertising and portfolio choice. Working Paper

  • DeMarzo P, Kaniel R, Kremer I (2004) Diversification as a public good: community effects in portfolio choice. J Finance 59:1677–1716

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Detemple J (1986) Asset pricing in a production economy with incomplete information. J Finance 41:383–391

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dothan MU, Feldman D (1986) Equilibrium interest rates and multiperiod bonds in a partially observable economy. J Finance 41:369–382

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Eyster E, Rabin M (2011) Rational observational learning. Working Paper

  • Feldman D (2003) The term structure of interest rates: bounded or falling? Eur Finance Rev (Rev Finance) 7:103–113

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Feldman D (2007) Incomplete information equilibria: separation theorems and other myths. Ann Oper Res 151:119–149

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Foad H (2011) Immigration and equity home bias. J Int Money Finance 30:982–998

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • French K, Poterba J (1991) Investor diversification and international equity markets. Am Econ Rev 81:222–226

    Google Scholar 

  • Frijns B, Lai Q, Tourani-Rad A (2014) Institutional trading and stock returns: evidence from China. Rev Pac Basin Finance Mark Pol 17:1–26

    Google Scholar 

  • Gau Y-F, Hua M, Wu W-L (2010) International asset allocation for incompletely-informed investors. J Finance Mark 13:422–447

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gehrig T (1993) An information-based explanation of the domestic bias in international equity. Scand J Econ 95:97–109

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gelos R, Wei S (2005) Transparency and international portfolio holdings. J Finance 60:2987–3020

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Graham J (1999) Herding among investment newsletters: theory and evidence. J Finance 54:237–268

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grinblatt M, Keloharju M (2001) How distance, language, and culture influence stockholdings and trades. J Finance 56:1053–1073

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hirshleifer D, Luo GY (2001) On the survival of overconfident traders in a competitive securities market. J Finance Mark 4:73–84

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hirshleifer D, Teoh SH (2003) Herd behavior and cascading in capital markets: a review and synthesis. Eur Finance Manag 9:25–66

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hong H, Kubik J, Stein J (2004) Social interaction and stock-market participation. J Finance 59:137–163

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hong H, Kubik J, Stein J (2005) Thy neighbor’s portfolio: word-of-mouth effects in the holdings and trades of money managers. J Finance 60:2801–2824

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Huberman G (2001) Familiarity breeds investment. Rev Finance Stud 14:659–680

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ivković Z, Weisbenner S (2005) Local does as local is: information content of the geography of individual investors’ common stock investments. J Finance 60:267–306

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ivković Z, Weisbenner S (2007) Information diffusion effects in individual investors’ common stock purchases: covet thy neighbors’ investment choices. Rev Finance Stud 20:1327–1357

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Juneja J (2015) An evaluation of alternative methods used in the estimation of Gaussian term structure models. Rev Quant Finance Acc 44:1–24

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kang J, Stulz R (1997) Why is there a home bias? An analysis of foreign portfolio equity ownership in Japan. J Finance Econ 46:3–28

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Karlsson A, Norden L (2007) Home sweet home: home bias and international diversification among individual investors. J Bank Finance 31:317–333

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kaustia M, Knupfer S (2012) Peer performance and stock market entry. J Finance Econ 104:321–338

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kilka M, Weber M (2000) Home bias in international stock return expectations. J Behav Finance 1:176–192

    Google Scholar 

  • Korniotis G, Kumar A (2013) Do portfolio distortions reflect superior information or psychological biases? J Finance Quant Anal 48:1–48

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kuvvet E (2013) Threats to foreign equity investments in international capital markets: nationalism and militarism. Rev Pac Basin Finance Mark Pol 16:1–16

    Google Scholar 

  • Lang M, Lins K, Miller D (2003) ADRs, analysts, and accuracy: does cross listing in the United States improve a firm’s information environment and increase market value? J Acc Res 41:317–345

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lewis K (1999) Trying to explain home bias in equity and consumption. J Econ Lit 37:571–608

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Li K (2004) Confidence in the familiar: an international perspective. J Finance Quant Anal 39:47–68

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Liptser RS, Shiryaev AN (2001) Statistics of random process I and II. Springer, Berlin

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Lundtofte F (2006) The effect of information quality on optimal portfolio choice. Finance Rev 41:157–185

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lundtofte F (2013) The quality of public information and the term structure of interest rates. Rev Quant Finance Acc 40:715–740

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lutje T, Menkhoff L (2007) What drives home bias? Evidence from fund managers’ views. Int J Finance Econ 12:21–35

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Merton R (1980) On estimating the expected return on the market: an explanatory investigation. J Finance Econ 8:323–361

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mishra AV (2011) Australia’s equity home bias and real exchange rate volatility. Rev Quant Finance Acc 37:223–244

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mishra AV, Conteh UB (2014) Australia’s bond home bias. Rev Pac Basin Finance Mark Pol 17:1–30

    Google Scholar 

  • Ng L, Wu F (2010) Peer effects in the trading decisions of individual investors. Finance Manag 39:807–831

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nosic A, Weber M, Glaser M (2011) Opening the black box: from an individual bias to portfolio performance. Working Paper

  • Ozsoylev H (2007) Asset pricing implications of social networks. Working Paper

  • Park A, Sabourian H (2011) Herding and contrarian behavior in financial markets. Econometrica 79:973–1026

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Parwada J, Yang J (2009) Information diffusion among international fund managers: multicountry evidence. Finance Manag 38:817–835

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Portes R, Rey H (2005) The determinants of cross-border equity flows. J Int Econ 65:269–296

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Riedel F (2000) Decreasing yield curves in a model with an unknown constant growth rate. Eur Finance Rev (Rev Finance) 4:51–67

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stone D, Miller S (2013) Learning, leading and herding. Math Soc Sci 65:222–231

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Strong N, Xu X (2003) Understanding the equity home bias: evidence from survey data. Rev Econ Stat 85:307–312

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Van Nieuwerburgh S, Veldkamp L (2009) Information immobility and the home bias puzzle. J Finance 64:1187–1215

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Welch I (1992) Sequential sales, learning, and cascades. J Financ 47:695–732

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zhu N (2002) The local bias of individual investors. Yale ICF Working Paper No. 02–30

Download references

Acknowledgments

The authors would like to thank C. F. Lee (the editor), an anonymous referee, and the participants at The 2012 NTU International Conference on Finance, the 20th Conference on Securities and Financial Markets, the 2013 Annual Conference of Taiwan Finance Association, the 8th NCTU International Finance Conference, and the 22nd Annual Conference on Pacific Basin Finance, Economics, Accounting, and Management (PBFEAM) for many useful comments and suggestions on earlier drafts of this paper. Any remaining errors are our own. Wen-Lin Wu acknowledges the research grant of the Ministry of Science and Technology of Taiwan (NSC102-2410-H-035-011).

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Wen-Lin Wu.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Wu, WL., Gau, YF. Home bias in portfolio choices: social learning among partially informed agents. Rev Quant Finan Acc 48, 527–556 (2017). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11156-016-0560-6

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11156-016-0560-6

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation