Skip to main content
Log in

Explaining the volatility smile: non-parametric versus parametric option models

  • Original Research
  • Published:
Review of Quantitative Finance and Accounting Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

We employ a “non-parametric” pricing approach of European options to explain the volatility smile. In contrast to “parametric” models that assume that the underlying state variable(s) follows a stochastic process that adheres to a strict functional form, “non-parametric” models directly fit the end distribution of the underlying state variable(s) with statistical distributions that are not represented by parametric functions. We derive an approximation formula which prices S&P 500 index options in closed form which corresponds to the lower bound recently proposed by Lin et al. (Rev Quant Financ Account 38(1):109–129, 2012). Our model yields option prices that are more consistent with the data than the option prices that are generated by several widely used models. Although a quantitative comparison with other non-parametric models is more difficult, there are indications that our model is also more consistent with the data than these models.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. The extensions to the Black–Scholes model are too numerous to be reviewed here. We only highlight the most relevant studies in this paper. Empirical research is briefly described in Sect. 4.

  2. Unlike models such as Rubinstein (1994), Ait-Sahalia and Lo (1998), and Jackwerth and Rubinstein (1996), these models do not perfectly calibrate to the market option prices.

  3. We follow previous “non-parametric” studies that, in contrast to traditional option pricing models, do not assume continuous trading.

  4. Similar to our horserace, Mozumder et al. (2013) provide a comparative analysis of option pricing under non-normality.

  5. A price histogram on the expiration date can be derived given the current price and a return histogram for the period between the current date and the expiration date. Thus, we use the histogram of returns till the expiration date and the histogram of prices on the expiration date interchangeably.

  6. See, for example, Bakshi et al. (1997), page 2022.

  7. See Das and Sundaram (1999) for details.

  8. Let the physical measure be denoted as \(\varvec{\mathbb{P}}\). The usual separation theorem gives rise to the well-known, risk-neutral pricing result:

    \(\begin{aligned} S_{t} & = E_{t} [M_{t,T} S_{T} ] \\ & = E_{t} [M_{t,T} ]\hat{E}_{t}^{(T)} [S_{T} ] \\ & = P_{t,T} \hat{E}_{t}^{(T)} [S_{T} ] \\ \end{aligned}\)

    If the risk free interest rate is stochastic, then \(\hat{E}_{t}^{(T)} [ \cdot ]\) is the conditional expectation under the \(T\)—forward measure \(\varvec{\hat{\mathbb{P}}}^{(T)}\). When the risk free rate is non-stochastic, then the forward measure reduces to the risk neutral measure \(\varvec{\hat{\mathbb{P}}}\) and will not depend upon maturity time, i.e. \(\hat{E}_{t}^{(T)} [ \cdot ] \to \hat{E}_{t}^{{}} [ \cdot ]\). Without loss of generality and for the ease of exposition, we shall assume non-stochastic interest rates and proceed with the risk neutral measure \(\varvec{\hat{\mathbb{P}}}\) for the rest of the paper.

  9. Later in the calibration, we alter the variance of this histogram so that the option price computed by Eq. 3 matches with the market price.

  10. The correlation between the volatility and the stock price is assumed 0 and the jump intensity is assumed to be 0.001.

  11. See, for example, Hull (2008).

  12. The first to document biases are Black and Scholes (1972) who find option prices for high (low) variance stocks to be lower (higher) than predicted by the model.

  13. Examples that do not take the American premium into consideration include MacBeth and Merville (1979), Emanuel and MacBeth (1982), Rubinstein (1985), Geske et al. (1983), and Scott (1987). Whaley (1982) and Geske and Rolls (1984) discuss possible biases if such premiums are not included. Examples that take into consideration of the American premium include Whaley (1986), who adopt the Geske-Roll-Whaley model, for American style S&P 500 futures options and Bodurtha and Courtadon (1987), who adopt the approximation algorithm by Mason (1979) and Parkinson (1977), for currency options.

  14. Note that the Black–Scholes sneer found by Rubinstein (1994) is based upon data from 1 day.

  15. For additional evidence, see Bates (1991, 1996) and Dumas et al. (1998). In addition, the smile is not restricted to options on stock indices. See, for example, Jarrow et al. (2007).

  16. In their Table 1, Das and Sundaram demonstrate that, using jump diffusion models, extra kurtosis for the three-month holding period is less than 8 % of the extra kurtosis for the 1-week holding period. In their Table 3, Das and Sundaram demonstrate that, using stochastic volatility models, extra kurtosis for the 3-month holding period is more than 70 % of the extra kurtosis for the 1-week holding period. In contrast, the corresponding number during our sample period between January 3, 1950 and December 31, 2009 is 28 %. Detailed calculations are available upon request.

  17. To further examine whether a market overpricing of in- and out-of-the-money option contracts generates the non-flat pattern of implied volatilities, we calculate the payoffs generated by selling naked option contracts and examine the relationship between the payoffs and the implied volatilities.

  18. We also calculate the average of the absolute values of the percentage errors (relative to market prices) that are associated with the predicted prices. The results indicate an even stronger dominance of our model.

  19. Note that the implied volatility is replaced by the expected volatility in the Heston and Bakshi–Cao–Chen models.

  20. Since \(C_{T,T,K}\) is part of the dependent variable, we cannot include \(E[C_{T,T,K} ]\) on the right hand side.

  21. Alternatively, we could have included a dummy variable for each day on which contract prices are recorded. This would also help control for changes in the expected future volatility relative to the recently realized volatility. However, it would necessitate adding over 900 dummy variables. We assume that, controlling for the realized return of the index between the trading date and the expiration date, the profits should not be related to the identity of the trading date.

  22. Looking at the Fig. 1, we do observe our out of the money implied volatilities are higher than the Black–Scholes’.

References

  • Ait-Sahalia Y, Lo AW (1998) Nonparametric estimation of state-price densities implicit in financial asset prices. J Financ 53(2):499–547

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bakshi GS, Cao C, Chen Z (1997) Empirical performance of alternative option pricing models. J Financ 52:2003–2049

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bates D (1991) The crash of 87’: Was it expected? The evidence from options markets. J Financ 46:1009–1044

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bates D (1996) Jumps and stochastic volatility: exchange rate processes implicit in deutsche mark options. Rev Financ Stud 9:69–107

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bates DS (2003) Empirical option pricing: a retrospection. J Econom 116:387–404

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Black F (1975) Fact and fantasy in the use of options. Financ Anal J 31(36–41):61–72

    Google Scholar 

  • Black F, Scholes M (1972) The valuation of option contracts and a test of market efficiency. J Financ 27:399–417

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Black F, Scholes M (1973) The pricing of options and corporate liabilities. J Polit Econ 81:637–659

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bodurtha J, Courtadon G (1987) Tests of the American option pricing model in the foreign currency option market. J Financ Quant Anal 22:153–167

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brennan Michael (1979) The pricing of contingent claims in discrete time. J Financ 24(1):53–68

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Broadie M, Detemple JB (2004) Option pricing: valuation models and applications. Manage Sci 50:1145–1177

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Carr P, Wu L (2004) Time-changed levy processes and option pricing. J Financ Econ 71(1):113–141

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chidambaran NK, Jevons Lee CH, Trigueros J (1999) An adaptive evolutionary approach to option pricing via genetic programming. In: Abu-Mostafa YS, LeBaron B, Lo AW, Weigend AS (eds) Computational finance—proceedings of the sixth international conference. MIT Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Cochrane JH, Saa-Requejo Jesus (2000) Beyond arbitrage: good-deal asset price bounds in incomplete markets. J Polit Econ 108:79–119

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Costabile M, Leccadito A, Massabó I, Russo E (2014) A Reduced Lattice Model for Option Pricing under Regime-Switching. Rev Quant Financ Account 42:667–690

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Das SR, Sundaram RK (1999) Of smiles and smirks: a term structure perspective. J Financ Quant Anal 34:211–239

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Duan JC (1996) Cracking the smile. Risk 9:55–59

    Google Scholar 

  • Dumas B, Fleming J, Whaley R (1998) Implied volatility smiles: empirical tests. J Financ 53:2059–2106

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Eberlein E, Keller U, Prause K (1998) New insights into smile, mispricing, and value at risk: the hyperbolic model. J Bus 71:371–405

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Emanuel D, MacBeth JD (1982) Further results on constant elasticity of variance call option models. J Financ Quant Anal 17:533–554

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Eraker B, Johannes M, Polson N (2003) The impact of jumps in volatility and returns. J Financ 53:1269–1300

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Geng J, Navon IM, Chen X (2014) Non-parametric calibration of the local volatility surface for European options using a second-order Tikhonov regularization. Quant Financ 14:73–85

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Geske R, Rolls R (1984) On valuing American call options with the Black–Scholes European formula. J Financ 39:443–455

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Geske R, Roll R, Shastri K (1983) Over-the-counter option market dividend protection and “biases” in the Black–Scholes model: a note. J Financ 38:1271–1277

    Google Scholar 

  • Heston SL (1993) A close-form solution for options with stochastic volatility with applications to bond and currency options. Rev Financ Stud 6:327–343

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Huang JZ, Wu L (2004) Specification analysis of option pricing models based on time-changed levy processes. J Financ 59(3):1405–1439

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hull J (2008) Options, futures, and other derivatives, 7th edn. Prentice Hall, Upper Saddle River

    Google Scholar 

  • Hutchinson J, Lo A, Poggio T (1994) A Nonparametric approach to pricing and hedging securities via learning networks. J Financ 49(3):851–889

  • Ingersoll J (1989) Theory of financial decision making. Rowman & Littlefield, Totowa

    Google Scholar 

  • Jackwerth JC, Rubinstein M (1996) Recovering probability distributions from option prices. J Financ 51:1611–1631

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jarrow R, Li H, Zhao F (2007) Interest rate caps “smile” too! But can the LIBOR market models capture the smile? J Financ 62(1):345–382

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lin HC, Chen RR, Palmon O (2012) Non-parametric method for European option bounds. Rev Quant Financ Acc 38(1):109–129

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Longstaff F (1995) Option pricing and the martingale restrict. Rev Financ Stud 8:1091–1124

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • MacBeth JD, Merville LJ (1979) An empirical examination of the Black–Scholes call option pricing model. J Financ 34:1173–1186

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mason SP (1979) Essays in continuous time finance. Ph.D. Dissertation, M.I.T

  • Mozumder S, Sorwar G, Dowd K (2013) Option pricing under non-normality: a comparative analysis. Rev Quant Financ Acc 40:273–292

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Parkinson M (1977) Option pricing: the American put. J Bus 50:21–36

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Peña I, Rubio G, Serna G (1999) Why do we smile? On the determinants of the implied volatility function. J Bank Financ 23:1151–1179

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rubinstein M (1985) Nonparametric tests of alternative option pricing models using all reported trades and quotes on the 30 most active CBOE option classes from August 23, 1976 through August 31, 1978. J Financ 40:455–480

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rubinstein M (1994) Implied binomial trees. J Financ 49:771–818

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Scott L (1987) Option pricing when the variance changes randomly: theory, estimation, and an application. J Financ Quant Anal 22(4):419–438

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Scott L (1997) Pricing stock options in a jump diffusion model with stochastic volatility and interest rates: applications of Fourier inversion methods. Math Financ 7(4):413–424

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shafer G, Vovk V (2001) Probability and finance: It’s only a game!. Wiley, New York

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Shimko D (1993) Bounds of probability. Risk 6:33–37

    Google Scholar 

  • Stutzer M (1996) A simple non-parametric approach to derivative security valuation. J Financ 51(5):1633–1652

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Whaley RE (1982) Valuation of American call options on dividend-paying stocks: empirical tests. J Financ Econ 10:29–58

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Whaley RE (1986) Valuation of American futures options: theory and empirical tests. J Financ 41:127–150

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

We thank Charles Cao for letting us use his data set. We also thank Gurdip Bakshi, John Cochrane, Ramon Rabinovitch, Avi Wohl, and participants at a seminar at Rutgers University and at the Twelfth Annual Conference on Financial Economics and Accounting for comments. We also thank the Whitcomb center for financial support.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Hsuan-Chu Lin.

Appendix

Appendix

1.1 Variances under jump diffusion and random volatility

In this appendix, we derive \(V^{\text{Hes}}\) and \(V^{\text{BCC}}\) used in regression. Note that \(V^{\text{Hes}}\) and \(V^{\text{BCC}}\) replace the notion of implied volatility in the Black–Scholes model. In both models, the volatility follows a mean-reverting square-root process as follows:

$$\left\{ {\begin{array}{*{20}l} {dS = \mu Sdt + \sqrt V SdW_{1} } \hfill \\ {dV = a(b - V)dt + g\sqrt V dW_{2} } \hfill \\ \end{array} } \right.$$
(14)

where \(\mu\), \(a\), \(b\), and \(g\) are constants and \(W_{1}\) and \(W_{2}\) are Brownian motions under the physical measure and \(dW_{1} dW_{2} = \rho dt\) while in the empirical study \(\rho = 0\). It is known that the expected volatility under 14 is:

$$E_{t} [V_{u} ] = b\left( {1 - e^{ - a(u - t)} } \right) + e^{ - a(u - t)} V_{t}$$
(15)

and hence the expected total volatility in the Heston model is:

$$\begin{aligned} V^{Hes} & = \int_{t}^{T} {E_{t} [V_{u} ]} \\ & = b(T - t) + (V_{t} - b)\frac{{1 - e^{ - a(T - t)} }}{a} \\ \end{aligned}$$
(16)

In a jump-diffusion case with a jump size \(Y\) and an intensity parameter \(\lambda\), we have the following distribution:

$${ \ln }\,S_{T} = \left\{ {\begin{array}{*{20}l} {e^{ - \lambda (T - t)} } \hfill & {{ \ln }\,S_{t} + \mu (T - t) - \frac{1}{2}\int_{t}^{T} {V_{u} du + \sqrt {V_{T} } dW_{u} } } \hfill & {\text{no jump}} \hfill \\ {1 - e^{ - \lambda (T - t)} } \hfill & {{ \ln }\,S_{t} + \ln Y + \mu (T - t) - \frac{1}{2}\int_{t}^{T} {V_{u} du + \sqrt {V_{T} } dW_{u} } } \hfill & {\text{jump}} \hfill \\ \end{array} } \right.$$
(17)

where \(V\) and \(Y\) are random. The mean

$$E_{t} [{ \ln }\,S_{T} ] = { \ln }\,S_{t} + \mu (T - t) - \frac{1}{2}\int_{t}^{T} {E_{t} [V_{u} ]du + (1 - e^{ - \lambda (T - t)} )E[{ \ln }\,Y]}$$
(18)

and variance

$$V^{\text{BCC}} \approx \int_{t}^{T} {E_{t} [V_{u} ]du} + \left( {1 - e^{ - \lambda (T - t)} } \right)\left( {\mu_{Y}^{2} + \sigma_{Y}^{2} } \right)$$
(19)

1.2 Proof of Theorem

By Eq. 1, the option price must follow \(C_{t} = E_{t} [M_{t,T} C_{T} ]\), and hence:

$$\begin{gathered} C_{t} = E_{t} [M_{t,T} C_{T} ] \\ = E_{t} [M_{t,T} ]E_{t} [C_{T} ] + \text{cov} [M_{t,T} ,C_{T} ] \\ = P_{t,T} E_{t} [C_{T} ] + \text{cov} [M_{t,T} ,C_{T} ] \\ \end{gathered}$$
(20)

Further expand the covariance term:

$$\begin{aligned} \text{cov} [M_{t,T} ,C_{T} ] & = \rho_{MC} \sigma_{M} \sigma_{C} = (\text{sgn} [\rho_{SC} ]\rho_{MS} + \varepsilon_{1} )\sigma_{M} \sigma_{C} \\ & = \text{sgn} [\rho_{SC} ]\rho_{MS} \sigma_{M} \sigma_{C} + \varepsilon_{1} \sigma_{M} \sigma_{C} \\ & = \text{sgn} [\rho_{SC} ]\rho_{MS} \sigma_{M} \sigma_{S} \frac{{\sigma_{C} }}{{\sigma_{S} }} + \varepsilon_{1} \sigma_{M} \sigma_{C} \\ & = \text{sgn} [\rho_{SC} ]\text{cov} [M_{t,T} ,S_{T} ]\frac{{\sigma_{C} }}{{\sigma_{S} }} + \varepsilon_{1} \sigma_{M} \sigma_{C} \\ & = \beta \text{cov} [M_{t,T} ,S_{T} ] + \varepsilon_{1} \sigma_{M} \sigma_{C} + \varepsilon_{2} \\ \end{aligned}$$
(21)

where \(\sigma_{C} = \sqrt {\text{var} [C_{T} ]}\), \(\sigma_{S}\,=\, \sqrt {\text{var} [S_{T} ]}\) and

$$\varepsilon_{1} = \rho_{MC} - \text{sgn} [\rho_{SC}^{{}} ]\rho_{MS}$$
$$\varepsilon_{2} = \left\{ {\text{sgn} [\rho_{SC} ]\frac{{\sigma_{C} }}{{\sigma_{S} }} - \beta } \right\}\text{cov} [M_{t,T} ,S_{T} ]$$

Given perfection correlation, \(\beta = \tfrac{{\text{cov} [S_{T} ,C_{T} ]}}{{\text{var} [S_{T} ]}} = \text{sgn} [\rho_{SC}^{{}} ]\tfrac{{\sigma_{C} }}{{\sigma_{S} }}\). 21 becomes:

$$\text{cov} [M_{t,T} ,C_{T} ] = \beta \text{cov} [M_{t,T} ,S_{T} ] + \varepsilon_{1} \sigma_{M} \sigma_{C}$$
(22)

Also, under perfect correlation, \(\rho_{MC} = \text{sgn} [\rho_{SC} ]\rho_{MS}\) and consequently \(\varepsilon_{1} = 0\). We can then further simplify 22 to:

$$\begin{gathered} \text{cov} [M_{t,T} ,C_{T} ] = \beta \text{cov} [M_{t,T} ,S_{T} ] \\ = \beta \{ E_{t} [M_{t,T} S_{T} ] - E_{t} [M_{t,T} ]E_{t} [S_{T} ]\} \\ = \beta \{ S_{t} - P_{t,T} E_{t} [S_{T} ]\} \\ \end{gathered}$$
(23)

Substituting this result back into 20 and verifying that \(\varepsilon_{1} \sigma_{M} \sigma_{C} + \varepsilon_{2} = \varepsilon\) complete the proof.

1.3 Results of approximation error

To gauge the magnitude of the errors, we create a standard binomial model where there are \(n\) states and each state is \(S_{j} = u^{j} d^{n - j}\) with probability \(\hat{p}_{j} = \left( {_{j}^{n} } \right)\hat{p}^{j} (1 - \hat{p})^{n - j}\) in which \(u = e^{{\sigma \sqrt {\varDelta t} }}\), \(d = \tfrac{1}{u}\), and the risk neutral probability \(\hat{p} = \tfrac{\exp (r\varDelta t) - d}{u - d}\). Then the call value can be computed as \(C = e^{ - jr\varDelta t} \sum\nolimits_{j = 0}^{n} {} \hbox{max} \{ S_{j} - K,0\} \hat{p}_{j}\). Define the real probability as \(p = \tfrac{\exp (\mu \varDelta t) - d}{u - d}\) where \(\mu > r\). Following the state pricing theory and define state price as \(\pi_{j} = \hat{p}_{j} e^{ - nr\varDelta t}\). Hence, kernel is: \(M_{j} = \pi_{j} /p_{j}\). This way, \(E[M] = \sum\nolimits_{j = 0}^{n} {} M_{j} = e^{ - nr\varDelta t}\). Now, we can simulate the option price and the errors with \(n = 400\). The following is the table for the errors. We examine errors for the combinations of various moneyness levels (25 % in the money to 17 % out of the money), interest rates (3–9 %), and volatilities (0.2–0.6). Percentage errors are computed as \(\tfrac{{\varepsilon_{1} + \varepsilon_{2} }}{C}\).

\(r = 3\;\%\)

    

\(\sigma = 0.2\)

    
 

1.2500

1.1765

1.1111

1.0526

1.0000

0.9524

0.9091

0.8696

0.8333

Option price

18.7678

15.0116

11.7246

8.9380

6.6738

4.8632

3.4847

2.4474

1.6883

\(\rho_{SC}\)

0.9959

0.9909

0.9823

0.9689

0.9499

0.9242

0.8925

0.8543

0.8103

%error

0.0026

0.0053

0.0104

0.0194

0.0347

0.0610

0.1041

0.1753

0.2916

     

\(\sigma = 0.4\)

    

Option price

24.0460

21.1811

18.6027

16.2725

14.2259

12.4022

10.7875

9.3660

8.1208

\(\rho_{SC}\)

0.9822

0.9753

0.9669

0.9569

0.9457

0.9330

0.9188

0.9034

0.8868

%error

0.0047

0.0066

0.0090

0.0122

0.0162

0.0212

0.0275

0.0352

0.0447

     

\(\sigma = 0.6\)

    

Option price

30.1393

27.7423

25.5301

23.4889

21.6352

19.9316

18.3608

16.9060

15.5754

\(\rho_{SC}\)

0.9795

0.9745

0.9688

0.9626

0.9559

0.9488

0.9411

0.9329

0.9242

%error

0.0044

0.0055

0.0068

0.0083

0.0100

0.0119

0.0141

0.0165

0.0193

\(r = 6\;\%\)

    

\(\sigma = 0.2\)

    
 

1.2500

1.1765

1.1111

1.0526

1.0000

0.9524

0.9091

0.8696

0.8333

Option price

20.6885

16.844

13.4109

10.4353

7.95713

5.92756

4.34122

3.11746

2.19909

\(\rho_{SC}\)

0.99585

0.9909

0.98232

0.96887

0.94986

0.92418

0.89247

0.85429

0.8103

%error

0.00193

0.00404

0.00794

0.01484

0.02658

0.04643

0.07867

0.13117

0.21581

     

\(\sigma = 0.4\)

    

Option price

25.5

22.5839

19.9419

17.5397

15.4146

13.5094

11.8121

10.3088

8.98399

\(\rho_{SC}\)

0.98223

0.97529

0.96691

0.95691

0.9457

0.93299

0.91885

0.90339

0.88677

%error

0.00408

0.00575

0.00792

0.01072

0.01421

0.0186

0.02405

0.03077

0.03898

     

\(\sigma = 0.6\)

    

Option price

31.3427

28.9226

26.6822

24.6088

22.7194

20.978

19.3682

17.8734

16.5025

\(\rho_{SC}\)

0.97951

0.97447

0.96883

0.96258

0.95592

0.94877

0.9411

0.93287

0.92424

%error

0.00411

0.00513

0.00632

0.00769

0.00924

0.011

0.013

0.01528

0.01782

\(r = 9\;\%\)

    

\(\sigma = 0.2\)

    
 

1.2500

1.1765

1.1111

1.0526

1.0000

0.9524

0.9091

0.8696

0.8333

Option price

22.6283

18.7284

15.1812

12.0431

9.36818

7.12722

5.33085

3.91127

2.81952

\(\rho_{SC}\)

0.99585

0.9909

0.98232

0.96887

0.94986

0.92418

0.89247

0.85429

0.8103

%error

0.0014

0.00298

0.00591

0.01112

0.01994

0.03476

0.05861

0.09701

0.15815

     

\(\sigma = 0.4\)

    

Option price

26.9729

24.0141

21.316

18.8485

16.6499

14.6672

12.8903

11.307

9.90323

\(\rho_{SC}\)

0.98223

0.97529

0.96691

0.95691

0.9457

0.93299

0.91885

0.90339

0.88677

%error

0.00355

0.00501

0.00691

0.00937

0.01241

0.01623

0.02097

0.0268

0.0339

     

\(\sigma = 0.6\)

    

Option price

32.5547

30.1151

27.8499

25.7472

23.8247

22.0479

20.4009

18.868

17.4581

\(\rho_{SC}\)

0.97951

0.97447

0.96883

0.96258

0.95592

0.94877

0.9411

0.93287

0.92424

%error

0.0038

0.00474

0.00583

0.0071

0.00853

0.01016

0.012

0.01409

0.01643

Percentage wise, we see that the errors are large when the option is more out of the money (therefore low correlation), lower volatility, and lower interest rates. Hence in the above table, the largest error is observed on the most upper right (29 %) and the smallest error is on the most lower left (0.38 %). In dollar amount, the differences across various moneyness levels are not substantial. When the errors are large, the approximation formula gives substantially lower values than the correct price, resulting in higher implied volatility, causing the volatility smile to be more pronounced. In other words, the bias in the model will inflate the implied volatility generated by our model for out of the money calls. Hence, with the bias, our model is more conservative in resolving the smile puzzle.Footnote 22

1.4 Pricing formulas of the Black–Scholes, Heston, and Bakshi–Cao–Chen models

Following the notation of 14, the Black and Scholes (1973) call option formula on the SPX is:

$$C_{t,T,K}^{\text{BS}} = S_{t} N(d_{1} ) - e^{ - r(T - t)} KN(d_{2} ),$$
(24)

where

$$\begin{aligned} d_{1} & = \frac{{{ \ln }(S_{t} /K) + (r + \tfrac{{\sigma^{2} }}{2})(T - t)}}{{\sigma \sqrt {(T - t)} }} \\ d_{2} & = d_{1} - \sigma \sqrt {(T - t)} \\ \end{aligned}$$

We solve for the implied volatility of the Black–Scholes model, denoted as \(\sigma^{*}\), by substituting the market price of the call option into the pricing equation.

The Heston (1993) model allows the volatility in the Black and Scholes (1973) model to be random over time. Heston shows that such a model has a closed form solution in the Fourier space:

$$C_{t,T,K}^{\text{Hes}} = S_{t} \varPi_{1} - e^{ - r(T - t)} K\varPi_{2}$$
(25)

where

$$\varPi_{j} = \frac{1}{2} + \frac{1}{\pi }\int\limits_{0}^{\infty } {\text{Re} \left[ {\frac{{e^{ - iu\;\ln K} \phi_{j} }}{iu}} \right]du} \quad j = 1,2$$
(26)

\(i = \sqrt { - 1}\) and \(\phi_{j}\), \(j = 1,2\) is the characteristic function defined as:

$$\phi_{j} = e^{{B_{j} + D_{j} V + iux}}$$
(27)

where

$$\left\{ {\begin{array}{*{20}l} {B_{j} = riu(T - t) + \frac{ab}{{g^{2} }}\left\{ {(x_{j} - \rho giu + d_{j} )(T - t) - 2\;{ \ln }\left[ {\frac{{1 - y_{j} e^{{d_{j} (T - t)}} }}{{1 - y_{j} }}} \right]} \right\}} \hfill \\ {D_{j} = \frac{{x_{j} - \rho giu + d_{j} }}{{g^{2} }}\left[ {\frac{{1 - e^{{d_{j} (T - t)}} }}{{1 - y_{j} e^{{d_{j} (T - t)}} }}} \right]} \hfill \\ \end{array} } \right.$$
(28)

and

$$\left\{ {\begin{array}{*{20}l} {y_{j} = \frac{{x_{j} - \rho giu + d_{j} }}{{x_{j} - \rho giu - d_{j} }}} \hfill \\ {d_{j} = \sqrt {(\rho giu - x_{j} )^{2} - (ab)^{2} (2iu\xi_{j} - u^{2} )} } \hfill \\ \end{array} } \right.$$
(29)

\(x_{1} = a - \rho g\), \(x_{2} = a\), \(\xi_{1} = {\raise.5ex\hbox{$\scriptstyle 1$}\kern-.1em/ \kern-.15em\lower.25ex\hbox{$\scriptstyle 2$} }\) and \(\xi_{2} = - {\raise.5ex\hbox{$\scriptstyle 1$}\kern-.1em/ \kern-.15em\lower.25ex\hbox{$\scriptstyle 2$} }\). Here we assume that the volatility risk carries no risk premium. Bakshi et al. (1997) as well as other similar models add to the model jumps that are independent of volatility and stock price processes. Hence, for each characteristic function, \(j = 1,2\) in A16, we multiply correspondingly the following characteristic function from the jumps:

$$\phi_{J1} (u) = \exp \left( {\begin{array}{*{20}l} { - iu\lambda e^{{ - \mu_{Y} + {\raise0.5ex\hbox{$\scriptstyle 1$} \kern-0.1em/\kern-0.15em \lower0.25ex\hbox{$\scriptstyle 2$}}\sigma_{Y}^{2} }} (T - t)\left( {e^{{\mu_{J} - {\raise0.5ex\hbox{$\scriptstyle 1$} \kern-0.1em/\kern-0.15em \lower0.25ex\hbox{$\scriptstyle 2$}}\sigma_{Y}^{2} }} - 1} \right)} \hfill \\ { + \lambda (T - t)\left( {e^{{iu\mu_{Y} - {\raise0.5ex\hbox{$\scriptstyle 1$} \kern-0.1em/\kern-0.15em \lower0.25ex\hbox{$\scriptstyle 2$}}\sigma_{Y}^{2} u^{2} }} - 1} \right)} \hfill \\ \end{array} } \right)$$
(30)

and

$$\phi_{J2} (u) = \exp \left( {\begin{array}{*{20}l} { - iu\lambda e^{{ - \mu_{Y} + {\raise0.5ex\hbox{$\scriptstyle 1$} \kern-0.1em/\kern-0.15em \lower0.25ex\hbox{$\scriptstyle 2$}}\sigma_{Y}^{2} }} (T - t)\left( {e^{{\mu_{Y} - {\raise0.5ex\hbox{$\scriptstyle 1$} \kern-0.1em/\kern-0.15em \lower0.25ex\hbox{$\scriptstyle 2$}}\sigma_{Y}^{2} }} - 1} \right)} \hfill \\ { + \lambda (T - t)e^{{ - \mu_{Y} + {\raise0.5ex\hbox{$\scriptstyle 1$} \kern-0.1em/\kern-0.15em \lower0.25ex\hbox{$\scriptstyle 2$}}\sigma_{Y}^{2} }} \left( {e^{{iu(\mu_{Y} - \sigma_{Y}^{2} ) - {\raise0.5ex\hbox{$\scriptstyle 1$} \kern-0.1em/\kern-0.15em \lower0.25ex\hbox{$\scriptstyle 2$}}\sigma_{Y}^{2} u^{2} }} - 1} \right)} \hfill \\ \end{array} } \right)$$
(31)

where \(\lambda\), \(\mu_{Y}\), and \(\sigma_{Y}\) are the jump intensity, jump mean size and jump size standard deviation respectively. The full Bakshi et al. (1997) model also has random interest rates. However, since the impact of random interest rates on option prices is minimal for short maturity option contracts, we choose not to use it in our comparison. This reduces the complexity of the model and the number of parameters that should be estimated.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Lin, HC., Chen, RR. & Palmon, O. Explaining the volatility smile: non-parametric versus parametric option models. Rev Quant Finan Acc 46, 907–935 (2016). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11156-014-0491-z

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11156-014-0491-z

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation