Skip to main content
Log in

Regional Housing Prices in the USA: An Empirical Investigation of Nonlinearity

  • Published:
The Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Existing literature on housing prices is predominantly in a linear framework, and an important question that has not been addressed is whether housing prices exhibit nonlinearity. We examine Smooth Transition Autoregressive (STAR) model based nonlinear properties of housing prices over the 1969–2004 period for the entire US and the four regions. Our main findings are (1) housing price for the entire US and all regions except for the Midwest show non-linearity, (2) the dynamic properties implied by the nonlinear estimation explain the typical patterns that have characterized each housing market, and (3) results of Granger causality tests look more plausible in the nonlinear framework where we find stronger evidence of Granger causality from housing price to employment and also from mortgage rates to housing price.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. McHugh et al. (2004). “A Smooth-Transition Model of the Australian Unemployment Rate.” Retrieved from the world wide web at http://www.svt.ntnu.no/iso/WP/2002/10ausu.pdf.

  2. Seslen, T. (2004). “Housing Price Dynamics and Household Mobility Decisions.” Retrieved from the world wide web at http://www.usc.edu/schools/sppd/lusk/research/pdf/wp_2005.

  3. For example, Tversky and Kahneman (1991).

  4. This steeper rise and milder fall also holds in real terms (Abraham and Hendershcott 1996; Angell and Williams 2005, please see footnote 5).

  5. Angell and Williams (2005). “Home Prices: Does Bust Always Follow Boom?” Retrieved from the world wide web at http://www.fdic.gov/bank/analytical/fyi/2005/050205fyi_table1.pdf.

  6. We use the growth rate of housing price so that r t will be stationary.

  7. Engelhardt (2001) shows that households can lever nominal capital gains to purchase larger homes, but they became constrained by nominal capital losses.

  8. See Teräsvirta and Anderson (1992), Sarantis (2001) and the references therein for a similar transformation of various macro time series.

  9. Results of the unit root tests are not reported for the sake of brevity and may be obtained from the first author.

  10. It should be noted that if \(H_{02} :\phi _{2i} = 0\,given\,\phi _{3i} = \phi _{4i} = 0\) is accepted then it implies that the hypothesis of linearity is accepted, implying that the linear AR model is appropriate.

  11. We perform Ljung Box and ARCH-LM tests to check for misspecification. These results, which can be available from the authors on request, indicate no evidence of misspecification.

  12. In the case of explosive roots, the modulus of the root is greater than 1.

  13. The outer regime in all cases includes roots with modulus values that are as low as 0.8, but are not reported in Table 7 for the sake of brevity.

  14. Housing at the Tipping Point (2006), Moody’s Economy.com.

  15. Under the null, the test statistic has an F-distribution with degrees of freedom \({{q\left( {q + 1} \right)} \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{q\left( {q + 1} \right)} {2 + 2q}}} \right. \kern-\nulldelimiterspace} {2 + 2q}}\) in the numerator and \({{{\text{T}} - n - q\left( {q + 1} \right)} \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{{\text{T}} - n - q\left( {q + 1} \right)} {2 - 2q}}} \right. \kern-\nulldelimiterspace} {2 - 2q}}\) in the denominator, where T is the number of observatiuns and n is the dimension of the gradient vector, y t-i , y t-i y t-j , and \(y_{t - i}^3 ,\).

  16. The nonlinear estimation results on regional employment are available on request from the first author.

  17. We were not able to break down the testing of the Ganger causality results into sub periods of economic booms and recessions because the method of testing for nonlinearity calls for large data sets.

  18. When the variable y Granger causes variable r, the sum of significant coefficients (the θs below) of the “causing” variable (y) shows ‘net effect of y on r’. In the following equation for the Granger causality test, the sum of θs represents the size of net effect from y to r. \(r_t = \left[ {\phi _0 + \sum\limits_{i = 1}^p {\phi _i r_{t - i} } } \right] + \left[ {\theta _0 + \sum\limits_{i = 1}^q {\theta _i y_{t - i} } } \right] + \varepsilon _t \) Details of the Granger causality estimation can be obtained from the first author on request.

  19. This does not imply that employment is not an important determinant of home prices, but only that this relationship may not be evident in the short run.

  20. The mortgage rate data is available from April 1972 onwards only.

References

  • Abraham, J. M., & Hendershott, P. H. (1993). Patterns and determinants of metropolitan house prices, 1977–1991. In: L. E. Browne & E. Rosengren (Eds.), Real estate and the credit crunch, Federal Reserve Bank of Boston Conference Series (No. 36, pp. 19–42).

  • Abraham J. M., Hendershott, P. H. (1996). Bubbles in Metropolitan housing markets. Journal of Housing Research 7(2):191–206.

    Google Scholar 

  • Baffoe-Bonnie, J. (1998). The dynamic impact of macroeconomic aggregates on housing prices and stock of houses: A national and regional analysis. Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics 17(2):179–197.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Belsky, E., & Prakken, J. (2004). Housing wealth effects: housing’s impact on wealth accumulation, wealth distribution and consumer spending. November 2004 report for the National Center for Real Estate Research.

  • Brock, W. A., & Hommes, C. H. (1998). Heterogeneous beliefs and routes to chaos in a simple asset pricing model. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 22:1235–1274.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Campbell, J. Y., & Coco, J. F. (2006). How do house prices affect consumption? Evidence from micro data. Retrieved from the National Bureau of Economic Research Website, http://papers.nber.org/papers/w11534.

  • Cecchetti, S. G., Lam, P. S., Mark, N. C. (1990). Mean reversion in equilibrium asset prices. American Economic Review 80:398–418.

    Google Scholar 

  • Coulson, E., Steven, R. (1995). Sources of fluctuations in the Boston economy. Journal of Urban Economics 38:74–93.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Eitrheim, O., Teräsvirta, T. (1996). Testing the adequacy of smooth transition autoregressive models. Journal of Econometrics 74:59–75.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Engelhardt, G. (2001). Nominal loss aversion, housing equity constraints, and household mobility: Evidence from the United States. Center for Policy Research Working Paper, (42), 1–61, (September).

  • Englund, P., Ioannides, Y. M. (1997). House price dynamics: an international empirical perspective. Journal of Housing Economics 6(2):119–136.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gallin, J. (2003). The long-run relationship between house prices and income: evidence from local housing markets. Federal Reserve Board, FEDS paper 2003–17, Retrieved from www.federalreserve.gov/Pubs/Feds/2003/200317/200317pap.pdf.

  • Genesove, D., & Mayer, C. J. (2001). Nominal loss aversion and seller behavior: Evidence from the housing market. Quarterly Journal of Economics 1233–1260 (November).

  • Granger, C. W. J., & Teräsvirta, T. (1993). Modelling nonlinear economic relationships. Oxford University Press, Oxford.

    Google Scholar 

  • Grobar, L. (1996). Comparing the New England and Southern California Regional recessions. Contemporary Economic Policy 14(3):71–84 (July).

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hamilton, J. D. (1989). A new approach to the economic analysis of nonstationary time series and the business cycle. Econometrica 57:357–384.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hsieh, D. (1991). Chaos and nonlinear dynamics: Applications to financial markets. Journal of Finance 47:1145–1189.

    Google Scholar 

  • Luukkonen, R., Saikkonen, P., & Teräsvirta, T. (1988). Testing linearity against smooth transition autoregressive models. Biometrika 75:491–499.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McGibany, J. M., & Nourzad, F. (2004). Do lower mortgage rates mean higher housing prices? Applied Economics 36(4):305–313.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Muellbauer, J., & Murphy, A. (1997). Booms and busts in the UK housing market. Economic Journal 107(1):701–727.

    Google Scholar 

  • Poterba, J. (1991). House price dynamics: The role of tax policy and demography. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 2:143–183.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sarantis, N. (2001). Nonlinearities, cyclical behaviour and predictability in stock markets: International evidence. International Journal of Forecasting 17:459–482.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Skalin, J., & Teräsvirta, T. (1999). Another look at Swedish business cycles: 1861–1988. Journal of Applied Econometrics 14:359–378.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Skalin, J., & Teräsvirta, T. (2002). Modelling asymmetries and moving equilibria in unemployment rates. Macroeconomic Dynamics 6:202—241.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Teräsvirta, T. (1994). Specification, estimation and evaluation of smooth transition autoregressive models. Journal of the American Statistical Association 89:208–218.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Teräsvirta, T., & Anderson, H. M. (1992). Characterizing nonlinearities in business cycles using smooth transition autoregressive models. Journal of Applied Econometrics 7:S119–S136.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tsay, R. (1989). Testing and modeling threshold autoregressive processes. Journal of the American Statistical Association 84:231–240.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tversky, A., & Kahneman, D. (1991). Loss aversion in riskless choice: A reference-dependent model. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 106(4):1039–1061.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Radha Bhattacharya.

Appendix

Appendix

Table 8 Definitions of Regions

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Kim, SW., Bhattacharya, R. Regional Housing Prices in the USA: An Empirical Investigation of Nonlinearity. J Real Estate Finan Econ 38, 443–460 (2009). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11146-007-9094-y

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11146-007-9094-y

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation