Skip to main content
Log in

A model of a multilateral proxy war with spillovers

  • Published:
Public Choice Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Motivated by the war in Syria and the ascension of ISIS, this paper models a proxy war with three sponsors and three combatants as a dynamic game. Sponsors are leaders that provide resources for combatants to fight each other. Sponsors 1 and 2 have strong aversion to sponsor 3’s proxy, but not against each other. Three pure strategy equilibria exist in the game. When the ex post value of winning is small, all players fight in equilibrium. However, when the ex post value of winning is large, in equilibrium either sponsors 1 and 2 coordinate their actions, with one of them staying out of the contest, or sponsor 3 does not participate. The probability of winning and the sponsors’ payoffs depend on a spillover effect. We find that no unique way of characterizing the comparative statics of the spillover effect emerges and that the answer varies from one equilibrium to another. Finally, we identify conditions under which sponsors 1 and 2 would want to form an alliance.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. On terrorist spectaculars, see Arce (2010), Hoffman (2006) and Enders and Sandler (2012).

  2. On the growth of Islamic terrorism, see Enders and Sandler (2000) and Barros and Proena (2005).

  3. On ISIS, see Wood (2015).

  4. For an estimate of the economic impact of terrorism and conflicts on income per capita growth, see Gaibulloev and Sandler (2009). For the macroeconomic impacts of terrorism, see Blomberg et al. (2004) and Tavares (2004).

  5. Phares (2005) discusses the information war on Jihadism in academia and media, wherein Jihadists and their supporters actively participate, attempting to divert it, camouflage it, and move it in different directions.

  6. On conflict in dual population lands, see Levy and Faria (2007).

  7. For studies on armed groups switching sides during civil wars see Staniland (2012) and Otto (2017).

  8. A microeconomic study by Collier and Duponchel (2013) shows that during conflict, violence affects production through a form of technical regress and demand through a reduction in income. For an overview of disaggregated studies and the micro-dynamics of individual civil wars, see Cederman and Gleditsch (2009).

  9. Sorli et al.’s (2005) study of Middle East conflict finds ethnic dominance to be a significant determinant of violence. In addition, the authors find that economic development and economic growth, in addition to longer periods of peace, generally reduce the likelihood of conflict.

  10. Bevi and Corchon (2010) examine a complete information war game in which the initial distribution of resources is heterogeneous.

  11. For surveys of contest games, see Corchon (2007) and Corchon and Serena (2018).

  12. Katz et al. (1990) analyze group contests wherein groups vary in their numbers of members. They find that when the members are identical, all groups exert the same aggregate effort regardless of asymmetries in group size.

  13. It has been alleged that ISIS also has state sponsors, but to the best of our knowledge that conjecture has not been established clearly. We therefore avoid that issue.

  14. In that case, it is assumed that \(s_{1}\) and \(s_{2}\) do not provide any resources to the combatants.

  15. For details, see the Online Appendix.

  16. Following Sanchez-Pages (2007), we do not explicitly discuss the division of the alliance’s payoff among its individual constituents. However, one way to divide the aggregate payoff is to pay each constituent an amount equal to the outside option plus a fraction of the leftover surplus.

  17. We show this ratio since it is independent of V and t.

References

  • Anderton, C. H., & Carter, J. R. (2009). Principles of conflict economics. New York, NY: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Arce, D. (2010). Terrorist spectaculars: Backlash attacks and the focus of intelligence. Journal of Conflict Resolution, 54, 354–373.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Azam, J.-P. (2002). Looting and conflict between ethnoregional groups: Lessons for state formation in Africa. Journal of Conflict Resolution, 46, 131–153.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baliga, S., & Sjostrom, T. (2013). Bargaining and war: A review of some formal models. Korean Economic Review, 29, 235–266.

    Google Scholar 

  • Barros, C., & Proena, I. (2005). Mixed logit estimation of radical Islamic terrorism in Europe and North America: A comparative study. Journal of Conflict Resolution, 49, 298–314.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bevi, C., & Corchon, L. C. (2010). Peace agreements without commitment. Games and Economic Behavior, 68, 469–487.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bevi, C., & Corchon, L. C. (2013). Endogenous strength in conflicts. International Journal of Industrial Organization, 31, 297–306.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blimes, R. J. (2006). The indirect effect of ethnic heterogeneity on the likelihood of civil war onset. Journal of Conflict Resolution, 50, 536–547.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blomberg, B. S., & Hess, G. D. (2002). The temporal links between conflict and economic activity. Journal of Conflict Resolution, 46, 74–90.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blomberg, S. B., Hess, G. D., & Orphanides, A. (2004). The macroeconomic consequences of terrorism. Journal of Monetary Economics, 51, 1007–1032.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Boudreau, J. W., Rentschler, L. & Sanders, S. (2017). Stag hunt contests and alliance formation. Working Paper.

  • Brito, D., & Intriligator, M. (1985). Conflict, war and redistribution. American Political Science Review, 79, 943–957.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brown, J. (2011). Quitters never win: The (adverse) incentive effects of competing with superstars. Journal of Political Economy, 119, 982–1013.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Carey, S., Colaresi, M. P., & Mitchell, N. J. (2015). Governments, informal links to militias, and accountability. Journal of Conflict Resolution, 59, 850–876.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cederman, L.-E., & Gleditsch, K. S. (2009). Introduction to special issue on “Disaggregating Civil War”. Journal of Conflict Resolution, 53, 487–495.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Choudhury, S. M., & Sheremeta, R. M. (2011). Multiple equilibria in Tullock contests. Economics Letters, 112, 216–219.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Collier, P., & Duponchel, M. (2013). The economic legacy of civil war. Journal of Conflict Resolution, 57, 65–88.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Collier, P., & Hoeffler, A. (2002). On the incidence of civil war in Africa. Journal of Conflict Resolution, 46, 13–28.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Collier, P., & Sambanis, N. (2002). Understanding civil war. Journal of Conflict Resolution, 46, 3–12.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Corchon, L. C. (2007). The theory of contests: A survey. Review of Economic Design, 11, 69–100.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Corchon, L. C., & Serena, M. (2018). Contest theory: A survey. In L. C. Corchon & M. A. Marini (Eds.), Handbook of game theory and industrial organization (Vol. II, pp. 125–146). Northampton, MA: Edward Elgar Publishing.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Corchon, L. C., & Yildizparlak, A. (2013). Give peace a chance: The effect of ownership and asymmetric information on peace. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 92, 116–126.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dahm, M., & Porteiro, N. (2008). Biased contests. Public Choice, 136, 55–67.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • de Mesquita, B. B., Morrow, J. D., Siverson, R., & Smith, A. (1999). An institutional explanation of the democratic peace. American Political Science Review, 93, 791–808.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dixit, A. (1987). Strategic behavior in contests. American Economic Review, 77, 891–898.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dodd, V. (2016). Isis planning ’enormous and spectacular attacks’, anti-terror chief warns. https://www.theguardian.com/uk-news/2016/mar/07/isis-planning-enormous-and-spectacular-attacks-uk-counter-terrorism-chief-warns. Accessed 20 Apr 2017.

  • Enders, W., & Sandler, T. (2000). Is transnational terrorism becoming more threatening? A time-series investigation. Journal of Conflict Resolution, 44, 307–332.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Enders, W., & Sandler, T. (2012). The political economy of terrorism. New York, NY: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Faria, J. R., Silva, E., & Arce, A. (2017). Intertemporal versus spatial externalities in counterterror policy games. Dynamic Games and Applications, 7, 402–421.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fearon, J. D., & Laitin, D. D. (2003). Ethnicity, insurgency, and civil war. American Political Science Review, 97, 75–90.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fey, M., & Ramsay, K. (2007). Mutual optimism and war. American Journal of Political Science, 51, 738–754.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Filson, D., & Werner, S. (2002). A bargaining model of war and peace: Anticipating the onset, duration, and outcome of war. American Journal of Political Science, 46, 819–838.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gaibulloev, K., & Sandler, T. (2009). The impact of terrorism and conflicts on growth in Asia. Economics and Politics, 21, 359–383.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gause, F. G. (2014). ISIS and the new Middle East cold war. In Brookings Institution, Washington D.C.https://www.brookings.edu/blog/markaz/2014/08/25/isis-and-the-new-middle-east-cold-war/. Accessed 18 Jan 2017 .

  • Genicot, G., & Skaperdas, S. (2002). Investing in conflict management. Journal of Conflict Resolution, 46, 154–170.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gleditsch, K. S., & Beardsley, K. (2004). Nosy neighbors: Third-party actors in Central American conflicts. Journal of Conflict Resolution, 48, 379–402.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gleditsch, K. S., Salehyan, I., & Schultz, K. (2008). Fighting at home, fighting abroad: How civil wars lead to international disputes. Journal of Conflict Resolution, 52, 479–506.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hinnebusch, R. (2014). Syria. In E. Lust (Ed.), The middle east (pp. 764–788). Washington: CQ Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hirshleifer, J. (1989). Conflict and rent-seeking success functions: Ratio vs. difference models of relative success. Public Choice, 63, 101–112.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hoffman, B. (2006). Inside terrorism. New York, NY: Columbia University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hwang, S. (2012). Technology of military conflict, military spending, and war. Journal of Public Economics, 96, 226–236.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jackson, M., & Morelli, M. (2007). Political bias and war. American Economic Review, 97, 1353–1373.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Katz, E., Nitzan, S., & Rosenberg, J. (1990). Rent-seeking for pure public goods. Public Choice, 65, 49–60.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Klose, B., & Kovenock, D. (2015). The all-pay auction with complete information and identity-dependent externalities. Economic Theory, 59, 1–19.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Konrad, K. (2012). Dynamic contests and the discouragement effect. Revue d’Economie Politique, 122, 233–256.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Levy, A., & Faria, J. R. (2007). Ramsey in dual-population lands: Internal conflict and utility-maximizing consumption. Defence and Peace Economics, 18, 339–352.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Linster, B. G. (1993). A generalized model of rent-seeking behavior. Public Choice, 77, 421–435.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Moldovanu, B., & Sela, A. (2001). The optimal allocation of prizes in contests. American Economic Review, 91, 542–558.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mollers, M. (2012). Incentives versus competitive balance. Economics Letters, 117, 505–508.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Murdoch, J. C., & Sandler, T. (2002a). Civil wars and economic growth: A regional comparison. Defence and Peace Economics, 13, 451–464.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Murdoch, J. C., & Sandler, T. (2002b). Economic growth, civil wars, and spatial spillovers. Journal of Conflict Resolution, 46, 91–110.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Oliveira, A. R., Faria, J. R., & Silva, E. (2018). Transnational terrorism: Externalities and coalition formation. Journal of Conflict Resolution, 62, 496–528.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Otto, S. (2017). The grass is always greener? Armed group side switching in civil wars. Journal of Conflict Resolution forthcoming. https://doi.org/10.1177/0022002717693047.

    Google Scholar 

  • Phares, W. (2005). Future jihad. New York, NY: St. Martin’s Griffin.

    Google Scholar 

  • Reynal-Querol, M. (2002). Ethnicity, political systems, and civil wars. Journal of Conflict Resolution, 46, 29–54.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rogin, J. (2014). America’s allies are funding ISIS. In Daily Beast. http://www.thedailybeast.com/articles/2014/06/14/america-s-allies-are-funding-isis.html. Accessed 18 Jan 2017.

  • Russett, B., & Oneal, J. (2001). Triangulating peace: Democracy, interdependence, and international organizations. New York, NY: Norton.

    Google Scholar 

  • Salehyan, I. (2010). The delegation of war to rebel organizations. Journal of Conflict Resolution, 54(3), 493–515.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Salehyan, I., Gleditsch, K. S., & Cunningham, D. E. (2011). Explaining external support for insurgent groups. International Organization, 65, 709–744.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sambanis, N. (2001). Do ethnic and non-ethnic civil wars have the same causes? A theoretical and empirical inquiry (Part 1). Journal of Conflict Resolution, 45, 259–282.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sanchez-Pages, S. (2007). Endogenous coalition formation in contests. Review of Economic Design, 11, 139–163.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schelling, T. (1966). Arms and influence. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sela, A. (2011). Best-of-three all-pay auctions. Economics Letters, 112, 67–70.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Skaperdas, S. (1996). Contest success functions. Economic Theory, 7, 283–290.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Srli, M. E., Gleditsch, N. P., & Strand, H. (2005). Why is there so much conflict in the middle east? Journal of Conflict Resolution, 49, 141–165.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Staniland, P. (2012). Between a rock and a hard place: Insurgent fratricide, ethnic defection, and the rise of pro-state paramilitaries. Journal of Conflict Resolution, 56, 16–40.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Staniland, P. (2015). Militias, ideology and the state. Journal of Conflict Resolution, 59, 770–793.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tavares, J. (2004). The open society assesses its enemies: Shocks, disasters and terrorist attacks. Journal of Monetary Economics, 51, 1039–1070.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tir, J., & Jasinski, M. (2008). Domestic-level diversionary theory of war: Targeting ethnic minorities. Journal of Conflict Resolution, 52, 641–664.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tullock, G. (1980). Efficient rent-seeking. In J. M. Buchanan, R. D. Tollison, & G. Tullock (Eds.), Toward a theory of the rent-seeking society (pp. 97–112). College Station, TX: Texas A&M University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wood, G. (2015). What ISIS really wants? In Atlantic. http://www.theatlantic.com/ magazine/archive/2015/03/what-isis-really-wants/384980/?utm_source=SFFBants. Accessed 20 Apr 2017.

  • Zollner, B. (2009). The muslim brotherhood: Hasan Al-Hudaybi and ideology. London: Palgrave.

    Google Scholar 

  • Zorthian, J. (2015). Who’s fighting who in Syria. In Time. http://time.com/4059856/syria-civil-war-explainer/. Accessed 18 Jan 2017.

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Aniruddha Bagchi.

Electronic supplementary material

Below is the link to the electronic supplementary material.

Supplementary material 1 (pdf 75 KB)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Bagchi, A., Faria, J.R. & Mathews, T. A model of a multilateral proxy war with spillovers. Public Choice 179, 229–248 (2019). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-018-0586-5

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-018-0586-5

Keywords

Navigation