Skip to main content
Log in

Profit-splitting rules and the taxation of multinational digital platforms

  • Published:
International Tax and Public Finance Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper analyzes the strategy of a monopolistic digital platform serving users from two jurisdictions with different corporate tax rates. We consider two profit-splitting rules, Separate Accounting and Formula Apportionment based on the number of users in the two jurisdictions. We show that, even in the absence of transfer pricing, the platform shifts profit from the high-tax to the low-tax jurisdiction exploiting network externalities under Separate Accounting and manipulating the apportionment key under Formula Apportionment. In order to shift profit, the platform distorts prices and quantities. Under Separate Accounting, the direction of the distortions depends on the sign of the externalities. We use a numerical simulation to show that the ranking of fiscal revenues under the two regimes differs in the two jurisdictions: The high-tax jurisdiction prefers Separate Accounting to Formula Apportionment, whereas the low-tax jurisdiction prefers Formula Apportionment to Separate Accounting.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. See the proposal in OECD (2019)

  2. This is the case with France, which passed a law in July 2019 imposing a tax of 3% on the revenues based on intermediation and targeted advertising of 27 large digital platforms. Austria has passed a similar law in October 2019 imposing a tax of 5% on online advertising. Other countries, such as Turkey, UK, Belgium, Spain and the UK, have also declared their intention to introduce taxes on digital services (ranging from 2% in the UK to 7.5% in Turkey) in 2020. See “Why digital taxes are the new trade war flashpoint,” The Washington Post, December 10, 2019. However, to the best of our knowledge, none of the proposed taxes has actually been implemented yet.

  3. In January 2016, Google and HM Treasury reached an agreement on the tax liability of Google in the UK. See “Google agrees to pay British authorities £130 m in back taxes,” The Guardian, January 23, 2016. In 2016, Facebook decided to stop declaring all its non-US profits in Ireland and agreed to submit profit declarations in all countries in which it operates a sales office.

  4. We note that this manipulation under FA can happen even in the absence of network externalities across jurisdictions.

  5. For the high-tax jurisdiction, the effect is ambiguous as the tax base is reduced when the gap increases, and the total effect depends on the elasticity of the tax base with respect to the tax rate.

  6. The intuition underlying this result is easy to grasp: In order to shift profit assuming the number of users in the other jurisdiction fixed, when externalities are positive, the platform has an incentive to increase rather than decrease the number of users in the high-tax jurisdiction, as this increases demand in the low-tax jurisdiction. A similar reasoning shows that the number of users is reduced in the low-tax jurisdiction with positive externalities.

  7. As we show in the paper, the direct and indirect effects may have opposite signs, making the total effect of an increase in the gap between the two corporate tax rates ambiguous. However, there are some simple cases—such as symmetric markets, or markets with one-sided externalities where the total effect can easily be signed.

  8. See “Supreme Court Widens Reach of Sales Taxes for online Retailers,” The New York Times, June 21, 2018.

  9. See Bibler et al. (2018) for a study of tax compliance by AirBnB hosts in cities with and without tax collection agreements.

  10. See Weyl (2010) for a general argument, showing equivalence between price and user strategies for monopolistic platforms. This equivalence does not hold for competitive platforms where competition in prices (Bertrand) leads to different results than competition in quantities (Cournot). See Belleflamme and Toulemonde (2018) for a study of two platforms competing in prices.

  11. In online appendix, we show how prices can be derived from a micro-founded model based on heterogeneous users in the two jurisdictions.

  12. Gordon and Wilson (1986) were the first to note that FA generates distortions in the choice of the platform, albeit in a different model where firms are competitive whereas we consider a monopolistic firm.

  13. As shown in online appendix, this number is perfectly correlated with user surplus, so that the number of users is also a measure of user welfare in the two jurisdictions.

  14. In online appendix, we present the detailed computations in the linear model and numerical simulations with asymmetric jurisdictions and asymmetric externalities.

  15. In online appendix, we compute the equilibrium tax rate in a symmetric model under SA. This tax rate is equal to \(t^* = 1 - (\frac{\alpha }{\sigma -\alpha })^2\), a level which is very high when externalities are small.

  16. The finding that the low-tax country prefers FA and the high-tax country prefers SA holds true whenever externalities across jurisdictions are positive. If externalities from one jurisdiction are positive and from the other negative, as seen in online Appendix, the ranking between the two regimes may be different. It remains true, however, that the two countries always disagree on the optimal profit-splitting regime: If one gets higher tax revenues under SA, the other one gets higher tax revenues under FA.

  17. The price functions are akin to inverse demand functions, with one caveat: Due to coordination issues, a given couple of prices \((p_A,p_B)\) could lead to different demands. In that case, we select the largest demands.

References

  • Anand, B. N., & Sansing, R. (2000). The Weighting Game: Formula Apportionment as an instrument of public policy. National Tax Journal, 53(2), 183–199.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Belleflamme, P., & Toulemonde, E. (2018). Tax incidence on competing two-sided platforms. Journal of Public Economic Theory, 20(1), 9–21.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bibler, A. J., Teltser, K. F., & Tremblay, M. J. (2018). Inferring tax compliance from pass-through: Evidence from Airbnb tax enforcement agreements. Review of Economics and Statistics, forthcoming.

  • Bourreau, M., Caillaud, B., & De Nijs, R. (2018). Taxation of a digital monopoly platform. Journal of Public Economic Theory, 20(1), 40–51.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gordon, R., & Wilson, J. D. (1986). An examination of multijurisdictional corporate income taxation under formula apportionment. Econometrica, 54(6), 1357–1373.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Goolsbee, A., & Maydew, E. L. (2000). Coveting thy neighbor’s manufacturing: The Dilemma of state income apportionment. Journal of Public Economics, 75(1), 125–143.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gresik, T. A. (2010). Formula Apportionment vs. Separate Accounting: A private information perspective. European Economic Review, 54(1), 133–149.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kind, H. J., Midelfart, K. H., & Schjelderup, G. (2005). Corporate tax systems, multinational enterprises, and economic integration. Journal of International Economics, 65(2), 507–521.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kind, H. J., Koethenbuerger, M., & Schjelderup, G. (2008). Efficiency enhancing taxation in two-sided markets. Journal of Public Economics, 92(5–6), 1531–1539.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kind, H. J., Koethenbuerger, M., & Schjelderup, G. (2009). On revenue and welfare dominance of Ad Valorem Taxes in two-sided markets. Economics Letters, 104(2), 86–88.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kind, H. J., Koethenbuerger, M., & Schjelderup, G. (2010). Tax responses in platform industries. Oxford Economic Papers, 62(4), 764–783.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kind, H. J., Schjelderup, G., & Stähler, F. (2013). Newspaper differentiation and investments in journalism: The role of tax policy. Economica, 80(317), 131–148.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Koethenbuerger, M. (2020) “Taxation of Digital Platforms,” EconPol Working Paper 41, Leibniz Institute for Economic Research at the University of Munich.

  • Kotsogiannis, C., & Serfes, K. (2010). Public goods and tax competition in a two-sided market. Journal of Public Economic Theory, 12(2), 281–321.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lassmann, A., Liberini, F., Russo, A., Cuevas, A., & Cuevas, R. (2020). “Taxation and Global Spillovers in the Digital Advertising Market. Theory and Evidence from Facebook,” CesIfo working paper 8149.

  • Nielsen, S. B., Raimondos-Moller, P., & Schjelderup, G. (2003). Formula Apportionment and transfer pricing under Oligopolistic Competition. Journal of Public Economic Theory, 5(2), 419–437.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nielsen, S. B., Raimondos-Moller, P., & Schjelderup, G. (2010). Company taxation and tax spillovers: Separate Accounting versus Formula Apportionment. European Economic Review, 54(1), 121–132.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • OECD (2019) Programme of Work to Develop a Consensus Solution to the Tax Challenges Arising from the Digitalisation of the Economy, OECD/G20 Inclusive Framework on BEPS, available at http://www.oecd.org/tax/beps/

  • Suarez Serrato, J. C., & Zidar, O. (2018). The structure of state corporate taxation and its impact on state tax revenues and economic activity. Journal of Public Economics, 167, 158–176.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Weyl, E. G. (2010). A price theory of multi-sided platforms. American Economic Review, 100(4), 1642–72.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Francis Bloch.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Appendices

Appendix

Proof of Proposition 1

In the absence of externalities, under SA the platform chooses \(x_A\) and \(x_B\) to maximize the profits separately in the two jurisdictions,

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial V_A}{\partial x_A} = \frac{\partial V_B}{\partial x_B} = 0, \end{aligned}$$
(13)

resulting in the optimal number of users \(x_A^*\) and \(x_B^*\).

Under FA, the platform chooses \(x_A\) and \(x_B\) to satisfy the first-order conditions:

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial V}{\partial x_A}\left[ 1 - t_A \frac{x_A}{x_A + x_B} - t_B \frac{x_B}{x_A + x_B}\right]= & {} \frac{V (t_A-t_B) x_B}{(x_A+x_B)^2}, \end{aligned}$$
(14)
$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial V}{\partial x_B} \left[ 1 - t_A \frac{x_A}{x_A + x_B} - t_B \frac{x_B}{x_A + x_B}\right]= & {} \frac{V (t_B-t_A) x_A}{(x_A+x_B)^2}. \end{aligned}$$
(15)

If \(t_A >t_B\), \(\frac{\partial V}{\partial x_A} >0\). As the profit is concave in \(x_A\), this implies that \(x_A< x_A^*\). Similarly, as \(\frac{\partial V}{\partial x_B} <0\), \(x_B>x_B^*\). \(\square\)

Proof of Proposition 2

Let \(t'_A > t_A\). Let \(z = (x_A,y_A,x_B,y_B)\) denote an optimal choice of the platform when the tax rate in A is \(t_A\) and \(z'=(x'_A,y'_A,x'_B,y'_B)\) an optimal choice when the rate is \(t'_A\). Optimality implies

$$\begin{aligned} (1-t_A) V_A(z) + (1-t_B) V_B(z)\ge & {} (1-t_A) V_A(z') + (1-t_B) V_B(z'), \end{aligned}$$
(16)
$$\begin{aligned} (1-t'_A) V_A(z') + (1-t_B) V_B(z')\ge & {} (1-t'_A) V_A(z) + (1-t_B) V_B (z), \end{aligned}$$
(17)

which can be written as

$$\begin{aligned} (1- t_A) (V_A(z) - V_A(z') )\ge (1-t_B)( V_B(z') -V_B(z)) \ge (1- t'_A) (V_A(z) - V_A(z') ) . \end{aligned}$$

Since \(t'_A\ge t_A\), the two extreme inequalities imply \(V_A (z) \ge V_A(z')\), which in turn implies \(V_B(z') -V_B(z)\ge 0\). When the profit is strictly concave, the optimal choices are unique and the above inequalities are strict.

Consider now the change in the pre-tax profit \(\Delta = V_A(z')+ V_B(z') - ( V_A(z)+ V_B(z))\). Writing the post-tax profit \((1-t_A) V_A(z) + (1-t_B) V_B(z)\) as \((1-t_B) V(z) + (t_A-t_B) V_A(z)\), we derive from (16) and (17) again,

$$\begin{aligned} - (t'_A-t_B) (V_A(z) - V_A(z') ) \le (1-t_B) \Delta \le - (t_A-t_B) (V_A(z) - V_A(z') ). \end{aligned}$$

Since \(V_A(z) - V_A(z') \ge 0\), \(\Delta \le 0\) if \(t_A \ge t_B\): Starting with a tax in A at least equal to the level in B, increasing \(t_A\) further has a negative effect on the pre-tax profit. The opposite holds, i.e., \(\Delta \ge 0\), when \(t'_A \le t_B\): In that case, \(t_A < t_B\) hence the increase in the tax level diminishes the gap between the tax levels of the countries. \(\square\)

Proof of Proposition 3

It is convenient to operate a change in variables. Let us define the share of users of type x in A as \(\lambda = \frac{x_A}{x_A + x_B}\), the share of users of type y in A as \(\mu = \frac{y_A}{y_A+y_B}\), the total number of users of type x as \(T= x_A+x_B\) and the total number of users of type y as \(Z = y_A + y_B\). We rewrite the profit as

$$\begin{aligned} \Pi ( \lambda , T )= [1 - t_B - ( t_A - t_B ) (\omega \lambda + (1-\omega ) \mu )] V(\lambda T , \mu Z, (1-\lambda ) T, (1-\mu ) Z). \end{aligned}$$

Let \(t'_A > t_A\). Let \((\lambda , \mu , T, Z)\) denote an optimal choice of the platform when the tax rate in A is \(t_A\) and \((\lambda ' , \mu ', T', Z')\) when the rate is \(t'_A\), and \(v= V(\lambda T , \mu Z, (1-\lambda ) T, (1-\mu ) Z)\) and \(v'= V(\lambda ' T' , \mu ' Z', (1-\lambda ') T', (1-\mu ') Z')\). Optimality implies that

$$\begin{aligned} (1 - t_B - ( t_A - t_B ) (\omega \lambda + (1-\omega ) \mu )) v\ge & {} \\ (1 - t_B - ( t_A - t_B )(\omega \lambda ' + (1-\omega ) \mu ')) v'&\\ (1 - t_B - ( t'_A - t_B )(\omega \lambda ' + (1-\omega ) \mu ') ) v'\ge & {} \\ (1 - t_B - ( t'_A - t_B ) (\omega \lambda + (1-\omega ) \mu )) v,&\end{aligned}$$

which results in:

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{ 1 - t_B - ( t'_A - t_B ) (\omega \lambda ' + (1-\omega ) \mu ') }{ [1 - t_B - ( t'_A - t_B ) (\omega \lambda + (1-\omega ) \mu )] } \ge \frac{ v}{v'} \ge \frac{ 1 - t_B - ( t_A - t_B )(\omega \lambda ' + (1-\omega ) \mu ')}{ 1 - t_B - ( t_A - t_B ) (\omega \lambda + (1-\omega ) \mu ) } \end{aligned}$$

or

$$\begin{aligned}&1+ \frac{ ( t'_A - t_B ) (\omega (\lambda -\lambda ') + (1-\omega ) (\mu -\mu ')) }{ 1 - t_B - ( t'_A - t_B ) (\omega \lambda + (1-\omega ) \mu ) } \nonumber \\&\quad \ge \frac{ v}{v'} \ge 1+ \frac{ ( t_A - t_B ) (\omega (\lambda -\lambda ') + (1-\omega ) (\mu -\mu '))}{ 1 - t_B - ( t_A - t_B ) (\omega \lambda + (1-\omega ) \mu ) }. \end{aligned}$$
(18)

Consider the terms on the left and the right of the above equation. Since \(t'_A >t_A\), the denominator in the left equation is larger than that on the right. Hence, we must have \(( t'_A - t_B )(\omega (\lambda -\lambda ') + (1-\omega ) (\mu -\mu ')) \ge ( t_A - t_B ) (\omega (\lambda -\lambda ') + (1-\omega ) (\mu -\mu '))\), which in turn implies \((\omega (\lambda -\lambda ') + (1-\omega ) (\mu -\mu '))>0\) since \(t'_A> t_A \ge t_B\): The share of users in A goes down. This implies \(\frac{ V(\lambda T , \mu Z, (1-\lambda ) T, (1-\mu ) Z)}{V(\lambda ' T' , \mu ' Z', (1-\lambda ') T', (1-\mu ') Z') } \ge 1\), so that the pre-tax profit V decreases.

To prove that the tax base in jurisdiction B increases, we need to show (with the change of variables) that \((1- (\omega \lambda + (1-\omega ) \mu )) V(\lambda T , \mu Z, (1-\lambda ) T, (1-\mu ) Z) \le (1- (\omega \lambda ' + (1-\omega ) \mu '))V(\lambda ' T' , \mu ' Z', (1-\lambda ') T', (1-\mu ') Z')\). Using (18), it suffices to show

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{ 1- (\omega \lambda ' + (1-\omega ) \mu ')}{1 - (\omega \lambda + (1-\omega ) \mu )} \ge 1+ \frac{ ( t'_A - t_B ) (\omega (\lambda -\lambda ') + (1-\omega ) (\mu -\mu ')) }{ 1 - t_B - ( t'_A - t_B ) (\omega \lambda + (1-\omega ) \mu ) }, \end{aligned}$$

which is equivalent to

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{(\omega (\lambda -\lambda ') + (1-\omega ) (\mu -\mu ')) }{1 -(\omega \lambda + (1-\omega ) \mu )} \ge \frac{ ( t'_A - t_B ) ((\omega (\lambda -\lambda ') + (1-\omega ) (\mu -\mu ')) }{ 1 - t_B - ( t'_A - t_B )(\omega \lambda + (1-\omega ) \mu ) }, \end{aligned}$$

or, since \((\omega (\lambda -\lambda ') + (1-\omega ) (\mu -\mu ') \ge 0\), to

$$\begin{aligned}{}[1 - t_B - ( t'_A - t_B ) (\omega \lambda + (1-\omega ) \mu )] \ge ( t'_A - t_B ) ( 1 -(\omega \lambda + (1-\omega ) \mu )) \end{aligned}$$

and finally to \(1\ge t'_A\), which is of course always satisfied. \(\square\)

Proof of Proposition 4

As noted in the text, if the profit is concave in \((x_A,x_B)\), the first-order conditions (4) and (5) hold at an interior solution. By the implicit function theorem, \(X_A\) and \(X_B\) are differentiable in \(t_A\) and the derivatives satisfy:

$$\begin{aligned} {\frac{\partial ^2 \Pi }{\partial x_A \partial t_A}} + {\frac{\partial ^2 \Pi }{\partial x_A \partial x_A}} X'_A(t_A) + {\frac{\partial ^2 \Pi }{\partial x_A \partial x_B}} X'_B(t_A) =0, \end{aligned}$$
(19)
$$\begin{aligned} {\frac{\partial ^2 \Pi }{\partial x_B \partial t_A}} + {\frac{\partial ^2 \Pi }{\partial x_A \partial x_B}} X'_A(t_A) + {\frac{\partial ^2 \Pi }{\partial x_B \partial x_B}} X'_B(t_A) =0. \end{aligned}$$
(20)

Solving the system of linear equations, we obtain:

$$\begin{aligned} X'_A(t_A)= & {} \frac{ \frac{\partial ^2 \Pi }{\partial x_A \partial x_B} \frac{\partial ^2 \Pi }{\partial x_B \partial t_A} - \frac{\partial ^2 \Pi }{\partial x_B \partial x_B} \frac{\partial ^2 \Pi }{\partial x_A \partial t_A} }{ \frac{\partial ^2 \Pi }{\partial x_A \partial x_A} \frac{\partial ^2 \Pi }{\partial x_B \partial x_B} - \frac{\partial ^2 \Pi }{\partial x_A \partial x_B} ^2 } \\ X'_B(t_A)= & {} \frac{ \frac{\partial ^2 \Pi }{\partial x_A \partial x_B} \frac{\partial ^2 \Pi }{\partial x_A \partial t_A} - \frac{\partial ^2 \Pi }{\partial x_A \partial x_A} \frac{\partial ^2 \Pi }{\partial x_B \partial t_A} }{ \frac{\partial ^2 \Pi }{\partial x_A \partial x_A} \frac{\partial ^2 \Pi }{\partial x_B \partial x_B} - \frac{\partial ^2 \Pi }{\partial x_A \partial x_B} ^2. } \end{aligned}$$

Factoring out the numerator and denominator by \(\frac{\partial ^2 \Pi }{\partial x_A \partial x_A} \frac{\partial ^2 \Pi }{\partial x_B \partial x_B}\), we obtain expressions (8) and (9). Now, under SA,

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial ^2 \Pi }{\partial x_A \partial t_A} = - \frac{\partial V_A}{\partial x_A} \text{ and } \frac{\partial ^2 \Pi }{\partial x_B \partial t_A} = - \frac{\partial V_A}{\partial x_B}. \end{aligned}$$

Using the first-order condition on profit maximization with respect to \(x_A\) (4), we have

$$\begin{aligned} - \frac{\partial V_A}{\partial x_A} = \frac{1-t_B}{1-t_A} \frac{\partial V_B}{\partial x_A} = \frac{1-t_B}{1-t_A} x_B \frac{\partial P_B}{\partial x_A}, \end{aligned}$$

which gives the expression for \(\delta _A\). Finally,

$$\begin{aligned} - \frac{\partial V_A}{\partial x_B} = - x_B \frac{\partial P_B}{\partial x_A}, \end{aligned}$$

which gives the expression for \(\delta _B\). \(\square\)

Proof of Proposition 5

Consider one of the situations where direct and indirect effects have opposite signs. Suppose that markets are complements and externalities are positive, \(\delta _A >0, \delta _B<0\) and \(s_A, s_B >0\). All other situations are handled in a similar way. Suppose without loss of generality that the indirect effect dominates the direct effect for \(X_A\) so that

$$\begin{aligned} \delta _A + s_A \delta _B < 0, \end{aligned}$$

yielding

$$\begin{aligned} \delta _B < - \frac{\delta _A}{s_A}. \end{aligned}$$

Consider the effect of a change in \(t_A\) on \(X_B\):

$$\begin{aligned} \delta _B + s_B \delta _A< - \frac{\delta _A}{s_A} + s_B \delta _A = \frac{\delta _A}{s_A} (-1 + s_A s_B) < 0, \end{aligned}$$

where the last inequality is obtained because \(\delta _A > 0\) and \(s_A s_B < 1\) by strict concavity of the profit. This implies that the direct effect dominates the indirect effect for \(X_B\). \(\square\)

Proof of Proposition 6

The direct effects are still given by the same expression (8) as under SA but computed at an optimal solution under FA. Necessarily, the second derivatives \(\frac{\partial ^2 \Pi }{\partial x_A \partial x_A}\) and \(\frac{\partial ^2 \Pi }{\partial x_B \partial x_B}\) are negative (even if the profit is not globally concave) so it suffices to compute the sign of \(\frac{\partial ^2 \Pi }{\partial x_A \partial t_A}\) and \(\frac{\partial ^2 \Pi }{\partial x_B \partial t_A}\).

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial ^2 \Pi }{\partial x_A \partial t_A}= & {} - \frac{\partial V \frac{x_A}{x_A + x_B}}{\partial x_A} \\= & {} - \frac{V x_B}{(x_A + x_B)^2} - \frac{x_A}{x_A + x_B} \frac{\partial V}{\partial x_A}. \end{aligned}$$

By the first-order conditions of profit maximization

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial \Pi }{\partial x_A}= & {} \frac{\partial V}{\partial x_A} \left[ 1 - t_A \frac{x_A}{x_A + x_B} - t_B \frac{x_B}{x_A+x_B}\right] - \frac{V x_B (t_A - t_B)}{(x_A + x_B)^2}, \\= & {} 0 \end{aligned}$$

so that

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial V}{\partial x_A} = \frac{1}{ [1 - t_A \frac{x_A}{x_A + x_B} - t_B \frac{x_B}{x_A+x_B}]} \frac{V x_B (t_A - t_B)}{(x_A + x_B)^2} \ge 0, \end{aligned}$$

showing that \(\frac{\partial ^2 \Pi }{\partial x_A \partial t_A} < 0\). Similarly, we compute

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial ^2 \Pi }{\partial x_B \partial t_A}= & {} \frac{V x_A}{(x_A + x_B)^2} - \frac{x_A}{x_A + x_B} \frac{\partial V}{\partial x_B}, \\= & {} \frac{V x_A}{(x_A + x_B)^2} + \frac{1}{ [1 - t_A \frac{x_A}{x_A + x_B} - t_B \frac{x_B}{x_A+x_B}]} \frac{V x_A (t_A - t_B)}{(x_A + x_B)^2} \\> & {} 0, \end{aligned}$$

showing that \(\frac{\partial ^2 \Pi }{\partial x_B \partial t_A} > 0.\) \(\square\)

Online appendix

1.1 Micro-foundation of the prices

In this appendix, we describe a model of consumer behavior which gives rise to the inverse demand functions considered in the text. Every jurisdiction is populated by a continuum of heterogeneous users characterized by their willingness to pay for using the platform. In addition, users experience externalities from the presence of other users on the platform. Formally, letting U and W denote the utilities of users of the two types on the platform,

$$\begin{aligned} U_A= & {}\, \theta _A + u_A(x_A,y_A, x_B,y_B) - p_A, \\ W_A= &\, {} \eta _A + w_A(x_A,y_A, x_B,y_B) - q_A, \\ U_B= &\,{} \theta _B + u_B(x_A,y_A, x_B,y_B) - p_B, \\ W_B= &\, {} \eta _B + w_B(x_A,y_A, x_B,y_B) - q_B, \end{aligned}$$

where \(\theta _A\) and \(\theta _B\) are distributed according to continuous distributions with full support \(F_A\) and \(F_B\) on \([{\underline{\theta }}, {\overline{\theta }}]\) and \(\eta _A\) and \(\eta _B\) are distributed according to continuous distributions with full support \(G_A\) and \(G_B\) on \([{\underline{\eta }}, {\overline{\eta }}]\).

We now derive the demand associated to the fees \((p_A, q_A, p_B, q_B)\). Let \(x_A,y_A, x_B, y_B\) be the common expectation of every user over the number of users in the two jurisdictions. We compute the value of the user of type 1 in jurisdiction A who is indifferent between buying access to the platform or not. This value is given by

$$\begin{aligned} \widehat{\theta _A} = p_A - u_A(x_A,y_A, x_B,y_B), \end{aligned}$$

provided that \(p_A - u_A(x_A,y_A,x_B,y_B)\) belongs to the support of \(F_A\); otherwise, \(\widehat{\theta _A}\) will be equal to one of the extreme values \({\underline{\theta }}\) (if the market is covered) or \({\overline{\theta }}\) (if no user accesses the platform). We can similarly compute the value of all other indifferent users. The two jurisdictions may have different sizes. We normalize the measure of users in jurisdiction B to 1, and let s denote the measure of users in jurisdiction A. Assuming that expectations are rational, the demand thus satisfies

$$\begin{aligned} x_A = s(1-F_A(p_A-u_A(x_A,y_A,x_B,y_B)). \end{aligned}$$

Similarly,

$$\begin{aligned} y_A= & {}\, s(1-G_A(q_A - w_A(x_A,y_A,x_B,y_B)), \\ x_B= &\, {} 1-F_B(p_B-u_B(x_A,y_A,x_B,y_B)), \\ y_B= & \,{} 1-G_B(q_B-w_B(x_A,y_A,x_B,y_B)). \end{aligned}$$

From the computations above, the prices are given byFootnote 17

$$\begin{aligned} P_A (x_A,y_A,x_B,y_B)= &\, {} u_A(x_A,y_A,x_B,y_B) + F^{-1}_A (1-\frac{x_A}{s}), \end{aligned}$$
(21)
$$\begin{aligned} Q_A(x_A,y_A,x_B,y_B)= &\, {} w_A(x_A,y_A,x_B,y_B) + G^{-1}_A (1-\frac{y_A}{s}), \end{aligned}$$
(22)
$$\begin{aligned} P_B (x_A,y_A,x_B,y_B)= &\, {} u_B(x_A,y_A,x_B,y_B) + F^{-1}_B (1-x_B), \end{aligned}$$
(23)
$$\begin{aligned} Q_B(x_A,y_A,x_B,y_B)= &\, {} w_B(x_A,y_A,x_B,y_B) + G^{-1}_B (1-y_B). \end{aligned}$$
(24)

The sign of the derivatives \(\partial P_A / \partial y_A\), \(\partial P_A / \partial x_B\), \(\partial P_A / \partial y_B\) depends on the sign of the externalities, \(\partial u_A / \partial y_A\), \(\partial u_A / \partial x_B\), \(\partial u_A/\partial y_B\). For \(P_A\) to be decreasing in \(x_A\), as required in the paper we need the externalities \(\partial u_A/\partial x_A\) to be small relative to the direct effect measured by \(\frac{\partial F^{-1}_A (1-\frac{x_A}{s})}{\partial x_A}\). The same computations hold for the inverse demands \(Q_A,P_B\) and \(Q_B\).

Next, we compute the surplus of users and show that they only depend on the number of users of the same type in the same jurisdiction. Consider the surplus of users of type 1 in jurisdiction A. Taking into account their participation decision, the surplus of users of type 1 in jurisdiction A can be written as

$$\begin{aligned} US_A= & {} \int _{p_A- u(x_A,y_A,x_B,y_B)}^{{\underline{\theta }}} [ \theta _A + u_A(x_A,y_A,x_B,y_B) - p_A ] f_A(\theta _A) \mathrm{{d}} \theta _A, \end{aligned}$$

which, using (21), writes

$$\begin{aligned} US_A= & {} \int _{F^{-1}_A (1-\frac{x_A}{s})}^{{\underline{\theta }}} [ \theta _A - F^{-1}_A (1-\frac{x_A}{s})] f_A(\theta _A) \mathrm{{d}} \theta _A. \end{aligned}$$

The surplus of users of type 1 in jurisdiction A can thus be written as a function of \(x_A\). Furthermore, it is easy to check that this function is non-decreasing: Since \(F^{-1}_A (1-\frac{x_A}{s})\) is non-increasing in \(x_A\) both the domain of integration and the integrand are non-decreasing in \(x_A\). Hence, as intuition suggests, an increase in the number of users \(x_A\) results in an increase in the user surplus of type 1 users in jurisdiction A. The same reasoning holds for the surplus of all other type of users, showing that measures of number of users and of user surplus are perfectly correlated.

1.2 The linear model

In this appendix, we consider the linear model with two types of users. Let

$$\begin{aligned} P_A(x_A,x_B)= &\, {} 1- {\sigma _A}x_A +\beta x_B, \end{aligned}$$
(25)
$$\begin{aligned} P_B(x_A,x_B)= &\, {} 1-{\sigma _B}x_B +\alpha x_A. \end{aligned}$$
(26)

We first consider the optimal choice of the platform under Separate Accounting. The platform’s profit is given by

$$\begin{aligned} \Pi = (1-t_A)x_A(1-\sigma _A x_A + \beta x_B) + (1-t_B) x_B(1-\sigma _B x_B + \alpha x_A). \end{aligned}$$

The first-order conditions are given by:

$$\begin{aligned} (1-t_A)(1-2 \sigma _A x_A + \beta x_B) + (1-t_B) \alpha x_B= &\, {} 0, \\ (1-t_A) \beta x_A + (1-t_B) (1-2 \sigma _B x_B + \alpha x_A)= & \,{} 0. \end{aligned}$$

Solving the system of linear equations, we obtain the interior solutions:

$$\begin{aligned} X_A= & {} \frac{ 2 \sigma _B (1-t_A)(1-t_B) + (1-t_B) [ \beta (1-t_A) + \alpha (1-t_B)]}{ 4 \sigma _A \sigma _B (1-t_A)(1-t_B) - [\beta (1-t_A) + \alpha (1-t_B)]^2}, \end{aligned}$$
(27)
$$\begin{aligned} X_B= & {} \frac{2 \sigma _A (1-t_A)(1-t_B) + (1-t_A) [ \beta (1-t_A) + \alpha (1-t_B)]}{ 4 \sigma _A \sigma _B (1-t_A)(1-t_B) - [\beta (1-t_A) + \alpha (1-t_B)]^2}. \end{aligned}$$
(28)

The second-order conditions are satisfied if \(4 \sigma _A \sigma _B (1-t_A)(1-t_B) > [\beta (1-t_A) + \alpha (1-t_B)]^2\). We need to put additional restrictions (that we do not explicitly spell out) to guarantee that the prices \(P_A\) and \(P_B\) are positive.

Even in the linear model, the comparative statics effect of changes in \(t_A\) on \(X_A\) and \(X_B\) cannot be signed easily. The decomposition into direct and indirect effects gives

$$\begin{aligned} \delta _A= & {} \frac{1-t_B}{1-t_A} \frac{ \alpha x_B }{2(1-t_A) sigma_A}, \, \delta _B= - \frac{ \beta x_A }{ 2(1-t_B) \sigma _B} \\ s_A= & {} \frac{ (1-t_A) \beta + (1-t_B) \alpha }{2(1-t_A) \sigma _A} , \, \, s_B= \frac{ (1-t_A) \beta + (1-t_B) \alpha }{2(1-t_B) \sigma _B}. \end{aligned}$$

Notice that \(s_A\) and \(s_B\) are both positive—the linear model captures a market with complements. The direct effects \(\delta _A\) and \(\delta _B\) depend on the optimal solutions \(x_A\) and \(x_B\), making a comparison of the magnitude of the direct and indirect effects uneasy. Our next result provides a sufficient condition under which prices \(P_A\) and \(P_B\) are monotonic in the corporate tax rate \(t_A\).

Proposition 7

Suppose that \(\sigma _A \sigma _B \ge \max \{ \alpha (\frac{1-t_B}{1-t_A}\alpha +\beta ), \beta (\alpha + \frac{1-t_A}{1-t_B}\beta ) \}\), then at an interior solution, the equilibrium price \(P_A\) is decreasing in \(t_A\) , while the equilibrium price \(P_B\) is increasing in \(t_A\).

Proof of Proposition 7

Note that

$$\begin{aligned} P'_A(t_A)= & {}\, - \sigma _A X'_A(t_A) + \beta X'_B(t_A), \\ P'_B(t_A)= &\, {} \alpha X'_A(t_A) - \sigma _B X'_B(t_A). \end{aligned}$$

We use the decomposition of \(X'_A(t_A)\) and \(X'_B(t_A)\) to write

$$\begin{aligned} P'_A(t_A)= & {} \frac{1}{1-s_A s_B} [ - \sigma _A + \beta s_B] \delta _A + [- \sigma _A s_A + \beta ] \delta _B], \\ P'_B(t_A)= & {} \frac{1}{1-s_A s_B} [ \alpha - \sigma _B s_B ] \delta _A + [\alpha s_A - \sigma _B] \delta _B. \end{aligned}$$

Using the formulas for \(\delta _A, \delta _B, \sigma _A\) and \(\sigma _B\), the sign of \(P'_A(t_A)\) is the same as the sign of

$$\begin{aligned} R'_A= & {} (- 2 \sigma _A \sigma _B (1-t_B) + \beta [(1-t_A) \beta + (1-t_B) \alpha ]) \frac{1-t_B}{1-t_A} \alpha x_B \\&+ ( 2 \beta (1-t_A) \sigma _A - \sigma _A [(1-t_A) \beta + (1-t_B) \alpha ]) (- \beta x_A). \end{aligned}$$

Now, because the price \(P_B\) is positive

$$\begin{aligned} \sigma _B \frac{1-t_B}{1-t_A} x_B - \beta x_A > 0. \end{aligned}$$

Hence,

$$\begin{aligned} - \sigma _A \sigma _B (1-t_B) \frac{1-t_B}{1-t_A} \alpha x_B + \sigma _A (1-t_B) \alpha \beta x_A < 0, \end{aligned}$$

so that

$$\begin{aligned} R'_A< & {} (- \sigma _A \sigma _B (1-t_B) + \beta [(1-t_A) \beta + (1-t_B) \alpha ]) \frac{1-t_B}{1-t_A} \alpha x_B \\- & {} \beta \sigma _A (1-t_A) \beta x_A, \\< & {} (- \sigma _A \sigma _B (1-t_B) + \beta [(1-t_A) \beta + (1-t_B) \alpha ]) \frac{1-t_B}{1-t_A} \alpha x_B. \end{aligned}$$

and using the condition \(\sigma _A \sigma _B \ge \beta (\alpha + \frac{1-t_A}{1-t_B}\beta )\), \(R'_A < 0\).

Similarly, we see that \(P'_B(t_A)\) has the same sign as

$$\begin{aligned} R'_B= & {} (2 \alpha (1-t_B) \sigma _B - \sigma _B [(1-t_A) \beta + (1-t_B) \alpha ]) \frac{1-t_B}{1-t_A} \alpha x_B \\&+ (-2 (1-t_A) \sigma _A \sigma _B + \alpha [(1-t_A) \beta + (1-t_B) \alpha ])(- \beta x_A). \end{aligned}$$

Because the price \(P_A\) is positive,

$$\begin{aligned} \sigma _A x_A > \alpha \frac{1-t_A}{1-t_B} x_B, \end{aligned}$$

so that

$$\begin{aligned} (1-t_A) \sigma _A \sigma _B \beta x_A > (1-t_A) \sigma _B \beta \alpha \frac{1-t_A}{1-t_B} x_B \end{aligned}$$

and

$$\begin{aligned} R'_B> & {} \alpha (1-t_B) \sigma _B \frac{1-t_B}{1-t_A} \alpha x_B \\&+\, ((1-t_A) \sigma _A \sigma _B - \alpha [[(1-t_A) \beta + (1-t_B) \alpha ]) \beta x_A, \\> &\, {} ((1-t_A) \sigma _A \sigma _B - \alpha [[(1-t_A) \beta + (1-t_B) \alpha ]) \beta x_A. \end{aligned}$$

Using the condition \(\sigma _A \sigma _B \ge \alpha (\alpha + \frac{1-t_B}{1-t_A} \beta )\), the result follows. \(\square\)

Proposition 7 shows that, as in the analysis of Kind et al. (2005, 2008, 2010, 2013), an increase in the corporate tax rate \(t_A\) leads to a reduction in the price \(P_A\) and an increase in the price \(P_B\) in the linear model. Next, we analyze tax competition when platforms are symmetric (Figs. 6, 7, 8, 9, 10, 11).

Proposition 8

Suppose that platforms are symmetric, \(\sigma _A = \sigma _B = \sigma\), \(\alpha = \beta\). In a model of tax competition, where both countries choose their corporate tax rate to maximize tax revenues, there exists a unique symmetric equilibrium where

$$\begin{aligned} t^* = 1 - \left( \frac{\alpha }{\sigma -\alpha }\right) ^2. \end{aligned}$$

Proof of Proposition 8

Consider the marginal effect of an increase in \(t_A\) on \(R_A\) at a point where \(t_B=t_A =t\). We compute

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial R_A}{\partial t_A} = V_A(t) + (1- 2 \sigma x + \alpha x)X'_A(t_A)+ \alpha x X'_B(t_A). \end{aligned}$$

Now, at \(t_A=t_B=t\), \(X'_A(t_A) = -X'_B(t_A)\). In addition, \(V_A = x(1-\sigma x + \alpha x)\) and \(1 - 2 \sigma x + 2 \alpha x = 0\). Hence,

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial R_A}{\partial t_A} = x(1-\sigma x + \alpha x) - 2 \alpha x X'_A(t_A). \end{aligned}$$

Next, using the decomposition formula,

$$\begin{aligned} X'_A(t_A) = \frac{\delta }{1-s} = \frac{\frac{\alpha x}{2(1-t)\sigma }}{1 - \frac{\alpha }{\sigma }} = \frac{\alpha x}{2(\sigma - \alpha )(1-t)}. \end{aligned}$$

Replacing,

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial R_A}{\partial t_A} = x^2 (\sigma - \alpha ) - x^2 \frac{\alpha ^2}{(\sigma -\alpha )(1-t)}. \end{aligned}$$

Hence, at a symmetric equilibrium where \(\frac{\partial R_A}{\partial t_A} = 0\),

$$\begin{aligned} t ^*= 1 - ( \frac{\alpha }{\sigma -\alpha })^2. \end{aligned}$$

\(\square\)

We next consider the optimal choice of the platform under Formula Apportionment. As in the Proof of Proposition 3, let \({\lambda }= \frac{x_A}{x_A + x_B}\) and \(T = x_A + x_B\). After this change of variable, the profit of the platform becomes:

$$\begin{aligned} \Pi= & \,{} (1- {\lambda }t_A - (1- {\lambda })t_B) [ {\lambda }T (1- \sigma _A {\lambda }T + \beta (1- {\lambda }T) \\&+ (1-{\lambda }) T (1- \sigma _B (1- {\lambda }) T+ \alpha {\lambda }T)] \\= &\, {} (1- {\lambda }t_A - (1- {\lambda })t_B) T [1 + {\lambda }(1-{\lambda }) (\alpha + \beta ) T - \sigma _A {\lambda }^2 T - \sigma _B (1-{\lambda })^2 T]. \end{aligned}$$

Notice in particular that the optimal choices of the platform under FA only depend on the sum of externalities \(\alpha + \beta\). The first-order conditions with respect to \({\lambda }\) and T give rise to a system of quadratic equations:

$$\begin{aligned} 0= & \,{} (t_B - t_A) [1 + {\lambda }(1-{\lambda }) (\alpha + \beta ) T - \sigma _A {\lambda }^2 T - \sigma _B (1-{\lambda })^2 T] \\&+ T[(\alpha + \beta )(1- 2 {\lambda }) - 2 {\lambda }\sigma _A - 2 (1-{\lambda }) \sigma _B] (1- {\lambda }t_A - (1- {\lambda })t_B), \\ 0= &\, {} 1 + 2(\alpha + \beta ) {\lambda }(1-{\lambda }) T - 2 \sigma _A{\lambda }^2 T - 2 \sigma _B (1-{\lambda })^2 T. \end{aligned}$$

Assuming that the parameters are chosen so that the second-order conditions are satisfied, this system of equation gives rise to an interior solution in \(({\lambda },T)\) which allows us to compute the optimal number of users \(X_A\) and \(X_B\). Unfortunately, under Formula Apportionment, even in the linear model, the decomposition of the effect of a change in \(t_A\) on the number of users into direct and indirect effects does not give rise to simple formulas that can easily be signed or interpreted.

1.3 Numerical simulations

1.3.1 Asymmetric countries

We suppose that jurisdiction A is three times larger than jurisdiction B, which results in \(\sigma _A = \frac{1}{3} -0.1\), whereas \(\sigma _B = 0.9\).

Fig. 6
figure 6

Asymmetric countries: tax base, tax revenues and profits

Fig. 7
figure 7

Asymmetric countries: users and prices

1.3.2 Asymmetric externalities I: positive from A to B, negative from B to A

We suppose that jurisdictions have the same size, with \(\sigma _A = \sigma _B =0.9\) but externalities are asymmetric. There are positive externalities from A to B, reflected in \(\alpha = 0.3\), but negative externalities from B to A reflected in \(\beta = -0.1\). These numbers capture the situation of a search engine where advertisers are located in the low-tax jurisdiction and users in the high-tax jurisdiction.

Fig. 8
figure 8

Asymmetric externalities I: tax base, tax revenues and profits

Fig. 9
figure 9

Asymmetric externalities I: users and prices

1.3.3 Asymmetric externalities II: negative from A to B, positive from B to A

We suppose that jurisdictions have the same size, with \(\sigma _A = \sigma _B =0.9\) but externalities are asymmetric. There are negative externalities from A to B, reflected in \(\alpha = -0.1\), and positive externalities from B to A reflected in \(\beta =0.3\).

Fig. 10
figure 10

Asymmetric externalities II: tax base, tax revenues and profits

Fig. 11
figure 11

Asymmetric externalities II: users and prices

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Bloch, F., Demange, G. Profit-splitting rules and the taxation of multinational digital platforms. Int Tax Public Finance 28, 855–889 (2021). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10797-020-09643-0

Download citation

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10797-020-09643-0

Keywords

JEL Classification Numbers

Navigation