1 Introduction

Multinational enterprises (MNEs) play a vital role in helping developing countries grow by contributing to local employment and productivity improvement in normal times. However, MNEs may play a more crucial role during crisis times, especially in natural disasters. Thailand’s experience of large-scale floods in 2011 is a notable example of the destructive effects of a natural disaster on multinationals. The estimated economic damage is 46.5 billion USD across all sectors, and manufacturing alone suffered 32 billion USD of damage (Abe and Ye 2013; Haraguchi and Lall 2015). Seven industrial parks and 904 factories were inundated, more than half of which were Japanese MNEs. Thus, the business operation of many factories completely ceased for one to two months. Even non-inundated multinational plants were forced to reduce production due to the lack of parts from damaged suppliers. The disaster-hit economy hopes multinationals to show resilience so that they continue to source local intermediates and help local industry recover. The Bank of Thailand cautioned against this optimistic idea by stating that, unless the government took appropriate measures, the flood would relocate more multinationals to other Asian countries in the long run (BOT 2012). The exit of footloose multinationals would weaken their input-output linkages with local suppliers, damaging the host economy further. Indeed, using country-level data, Escaleras and Register (2011) and Doytch (2020) find that natural disasters have negative effects on aggregate foreign direct investment (FDI) inflows.Footnote 1

Only a limited attention in the literature has been paid to how MNEs respond to natural disasters and little is known about underlying mechanisms, despite its importance in the real world. This paper theoretically investigates under what conditions multinationals leave their host country once it is hit by negative supply shocks and which factor helps them stay there. To address these, our model takes into account two noticeable characteristics of multinationals: (i) input-output (or vertical) industrial linkages and (ii) footloose-ness. Vertical linkages imply that multinationals have complementarities with local industry (Markusen and Venables 1999). Sourcing by multinationals helps the local supplying industry grow, leading to a lower price of inputs and thus benefiting themselves. The footloose-ness arises because the location choice of foreign capital is based on the comparison of profits made in different countries. Multinationals are sensitive to negative shocks in their location; compared with local firms, they are likely to enter and exit a host country frequently (Görg and Strobl 2003; Bernard and Jensen 2007). We model a natural disaster as an increase in the fixed cost for local suppliers, which can be interpreted as a damage to their plants. This modeling captures an indirect damage to multinationals through their linkages with damaged local suppliers, as highlighted in the 2011 Thailand floods.

Our main findings are threefold. First, multiple equilibria, one in which multinationals enter and the other in which they do not, may exist. Second, a substantial damage to the local suppliers’ fixed cost results in a switch from one equilibrium with multinationals to the other without them. The increased fixed cost reduces the entry of local suppliers and hence raises the prices of local intermediate goods. Multinationals, even if they are not directly damaged, may find local sourcing unprofitable and leave the disaster-hit country, shrinking the local industry further.Footnote 2 This mechanism helps understand the (sometimes long-lasting) negative disaster impact on FDI found in empirical studies (Escaleras and Register 2011; Doytch 2020; Toner-Rodgers and Friedt 2020; Batala et al. 2021). Natural disasters may also raise the cost of local sourcing through the destruction of transportation infrastructure or directly damage multinational plants. In our model, the effects of these shocks are similar to those of the shock to the fixed cost for local suppliers because both reduce the profitability of multinationals staying in the host country.

Finally, conditions for multinationals showing resilience are identified. Specifically, they are more likely to stay in the disaster-hit country, if local intermediate goods are more important in multinational production or trade costs of importing foreign inputs are lower. Given that multinationals seeking low-cost inputs choose to enter the host country, a higher dependency on local suppliers and lower trade costs would lead to greater profits and thus prevent them from relocating. Contrary to the warning by the Bank of Thailand, the 2011 Thailand floods did not cause long-lasting relocation and restructuring by manufacturing MNEs, perhaps because of their strong industrial linkages with local firms and progressive trade liberalization (Milner et al. 2006; Feliciano and Doytch 2020).Footnote 3

We further examine a number of extensions of the basic model including multinationals with heterogeneous productivity, gradual recovery from disasters, the role of the host country’s market, endogenous sourcing patterns, and disaster risk. They give similar results and additional implications. Among others, we find that the least efficient multinationals are the first to leave the host country once a disaster hits. Put differently, multinationals staying in the damaged country are likely to be the most efficient ones. The heterogeneous-multinational setting avoids the extreme case where all multinationals completely exit. The result may help understand the observation that in the aftermath of the 2011 floods, larger Japanese MNEs in Thailand did not change their local procurement share as much as smaller ones (Hayakawa et al. 2015).

1.1 Relation to the Literature

We aim to contribute to the literature investigating the impact of multinationals on industrial development (Alfaro 2015 for a survey). For example, using Irish micro-level data, Görg and Strobl (2002) find that the presence of multinationals promotes the entry of local manufacturing firms.Footnote 4 Among many channels through which multinationals benefit host economies, an important one is vertical industrial linkages (e.g., Javorcik 2004; Alfaro-Ureña et al. 2022). Alfaro-Ureña et al. (2022) use firm-to-firm transaction data in Costa Rica and find that local firms increase their size and productivity after becoming a supplier to multinationals.

Although many theoretical attempts seek to understand the role of multinationals in vertically linked industries, only a limited number of studies have modeled (de)industrialization as switches between multiple equilibria (Rodríguez-Clare 1996; Markusen and Venables 1999; Carluccio and Fally 2013).Footnote 5 For example, Markusen and Venables (1999) model the upstream and downstream industries and numerically illustrate the situation where the entry of downstream MNEs fosters local upstream industry. Using a similar model, Rodríguez-Clare (1996) find that downstream MNEs benefits the host country if the intensity of their local sourcing is sufficiently high. Carluccio and Fally (2013) extend these two models further to consider a “technological incompatibility” of local intermediates with multinational production. These studies, however, analyze each equilibrium only separately and not explore which shocks trigger a shift from one equilibrium to another.

We rely on their framework and take one step further to analytically characterize the conditions under which an exogenous supply shock leads to an equilibrium switch and relate them to disaster impacts on multinationals. Specifically, we simplify the model structure of Markusen and Venables (1999) in a way such that the upstream and downstream industries are treated as one exhibiting roundabout production (Krugman and Venables 1995) and explicitly introduce trade by MNEs.Footnote 6 In doing so, we can go beyond the numerical results of Markusen and Venables (1999) and identify the conditions of MNEs showing resilience in terms of meaningful parameters such as the cost share of local intermediate goods and trade costs of foreign inputs. Our simple model allows further extensions such as heterogeneous MNEs in productivity and gradual recovery from negative shocks, none of which is examined in the three studies.

Some studies examine the impact of various types of risk on multinational behavior (Aizenman 2003; Aizenman and Marion 2004; Russ 2007; Fillat and Garetto 2015). Aizenman and Marion (2004) investigate how the volatility of demand and supply shocks affect differently market-seeking FDI and efficiency-seeking FDI. Fillat and Garetto (2015) model multinational entry as a real-option problem, where multinationals show resilience against negative shocks because of the sunk cost they have paid to enter. Unlike these studies focusing on risk under uncertainty, our model highlights actual physical damages, given the context of developing countries vulnerable to severe disasters (ADB 2013; Sivapuram and Shaw 2020). In an extended model with uncertainty, we show that the risk of disasters alone may lead multinationals to leave the host country before a disaster actually occurs (see Section 5.3.3 and Appendix 7).

Simulation studies investigating disaster impact in an economy with industrial linkages are complementary to ours (Okuyama and Chang 2004; Henriet et al. 2012; Inoue and Todo 2019; Galbusera and Giannopoulos 2018 for a survey).Footnote 7 In an economy where buyer-supplier relationship constitutes a complex network, Henriet et al. (2012) show how network features such as concentration, clustering and connectedness between subregions either dampen or magnify the effects of a natural disaster. We differ from these studies in terms of both in focus and modeling strategies. They describe regional economies by fixing the location of production, whereas we emphasize the footloose-ness of internationally mobile MNEs in developing countries. Although input-output linkages in our model are admittedly far simpler than theirs, we hope it serves as the first step toward a more comprehensive analysis on disasters and multinationals.

This paper is also related to the vast body of empirical literature assessing the disaster impact on firm performance.Footnote 8 According to recent studies using micro-level data, the destruction of physical capital due to natural disasters may be a good chance of upgrading it (Leiter et al. 2009; Vu and Noy 2018; Okazaki et al. 2019) or a bad one of decreasing productivity and the survival rates of firms (Tanaka 2015; Cainelli et al. 2018; Cole et al. 2019; Meltzer et al. 2021).Footnote 9

Only a limited number of empirical studies examine the nexus between natural disasters and multinationals. They find mixed results on whether the disaster effect is positive or negative and short- or long term (Escaleras and Register 2011; Oh and Oetzel 2011; Anuchitworawong and Thampanishvong 2015; Doytch 2020; Toner-Rodgers and Friedt 2020; Batala et al. 2021; Neise et al. 2021). Doytch (2020) examines sectoral FDI inflows in 69 countries from 1980 to 2011. Her dynamic panel regression results show negative effects in general, but also suggest that the effects vary depending on the type of disasters, industries, and regions. Using data from foreign affiliates of 71 European MNEs, Oh and Oetzel (2011) find that major natural disasters have no significant impact on the number of affiliates, whereas terrorist attacks and technological disasters have negative impacts. Closely examining disaster events in India in 2006–2019, Toner-Rodgers and Friedt (2020) report persistent intra-national shifts in multinationals’ investment patterns from disaster-affected regions to non-affected regions. Considering the discontinuous change in equilibrium due to a huge shock suggested by our theory, one may more likely find a negative effect of disasters with severe damages in sample countries less equipped with disaster prevention.

The remainder of the paper is structured as follows. The next section presents a motivating empirical example on the disaster impact on FDI. Section 3 describes the model and characterizes conditions under which different industrial configurations emerge. Section 4 examines the impact of natural disasters and characterizes the conditions under which multinationals show resilience. Section 5 provides two extensions of the basic model in detail and sketch three extensions briefly. The final section concludes the paper.

2 Disaster Impact on FDI: An Empirical Example

To motivate theoretical analysis, this section provides suggestive evidence on natural disasters and FDI. We first check whether natural disasters indeed affect FDI inflows. We then confirm that the impact of disasters on FDI into developing countries is negative and persistent when their damages are severe. We utilize country-level data on FDI in 1991–2015 from the World Bank Development Indicators (WDI) and data on natural disasters in 1976–2015 from the Emergency Disasters Database (EM-DAT) maintained by the Centre for Research on the Epidemiology of Disasters.Footnote 10 Detailed information on data sources and summary statistics are provided in Data Appendix.

We regress FDI inflows from the world to country i in year t on the total number of natural-disaster events that hit country i in \(t-1\) to \(t-\tau\) years.Footnote 11 Because the disaster impact on FDI may differ depending on its intensity, we distinguish between severe and non-severe disasters. A disaster event is defined as a severe one if it records financial damage as a share of GDP exceeding its median value for all countries that have ever suffered from disasters in 1981–2015. Hence, a non-severe event is defined as one if it is equal to or below the median. In addition, to see whether disaster impacts differ in the level of development, we interact the accumulated number of disasters with the dummy for developing countries. The regression equation is

$$\begin{aligned} \text {FDI}_{i, t} = \alpha&+ \beta \sum _{s=1}^{\tau} (\text {No. of natural disasters})_{i, t-s}\\&+ \gamma \sum _{s=1}^{\tau} (\text {No. of natural disasters})_{i, t-s} \times (\text {Developing})_{i, t} \\&+ (\text {Developing})_{i, t} + \varvec{x}'_{i,t} \varvec{\delta } + \eta _i + \theta _t +u_{i, t}, \end{aligned}$$

where \(\tau\) takes 1, 5, or 10 years; \((\text {Developing})_{i, t}\) is the dummy for developing country;Footnote 12\(\eta _t\) is the country fixed effect; \(\theta _t\) is the year fixed effect; and \(u_{i, t}\) is the error term. The column vector \(\varvec{x}_{i, t}\) includes control variables of the host country, which are considered as essential determinants of FDI  in both the theoretical and empirical literature (Markusen 2004; Antràs and Yeaple 2014; Blonigen and Piger 2014 for reviews), i.e., the log of real GDP (a measure of market size), the average tariff rate of manufacturing products (a measure of the inverse of trade openness), and the unit labor cost (a measure of labor costs). As FDI seeks greater demand and lower priced factors, we expect that GDP has a positive effect and the unit labor cost has a negative effect on FDI inflows. The openness to trade has a mixed effect and may increase or decrease FDI inflows.Footnote 13 We use one-year lag of these control variables.

Regression results are shown in Table 1.Footnote 14 In columns (1) to (3), the disaster variables count all events regardless of their intensity, while in columns (4) to (6) they count only severe ones. In the first three columns of Table 1, the coefficients on the disaster variables are all positive and significant, i.e., \(\widehat{\beta }>0\). This may reflect the facts that FDI temporarily away from the disaster-hit economy comes back as it recovers or that natural disasters provide an opportunity for foreign investors to upgrade capital equipment (see Doytch 2020; and Neise et al. 2021 for similar findings). The interaction of the disaster variable with the developing-country dummy has a negative and significant coefficient in column (1), i.e., \(\widehat{\gamma }<0\). The positive effect of prior disasters on current FDI could be smaller for developing countries than for developed countries, although their base level of FDI is higher, as indicated by the positive and significant coefficients on the developing-country dummy in all columns.

Such a heterogeneous disaster impact depending on the level of economic development is more articulated when we focus on severe events, as shown in columns (4) to (6) of Table 1. The level term of the disaster variable has an insignificant coefficient in the three columns, while its interaction with the developing-country dummy has a negative and significant coefficient in columns (5) and (6), i.e., \(\widehat{\gamma }<0\). FDI into developing countries negatively respond to severe disasters in the last 5 or 10 years, while FDI into developed countries do not. This suggests the vulnerability of developing countries to disasters possibly due to insufficient resources for disaster prevention.

In all columns of Table 1, the lagged value of \(\log (GDP)\) is consistently positive and significant, as we expected.Footnote 15 The lagged value of Tariff, a measure of the inverse of trade openness, is consistently negative and largely significant. This may suggest FDI in our sample uses their host country as a base for exporting to the other countries. The lagged value of \(\textit{Unit labor cost}\) is not significant and unexpectedly positive in some cases.

Table 1 Disaster impact on FDI

We then explore potential long-lasting effects of disasters by decomposing the number of disaster events in the prior 10 years into recent and past ones. Namely, the modified estimation equation includes three disaster variables: (i)the number of events in the prior year, (ii)that in the prior 2 to 5 years, and (iii)that in the prior 6 to 10 years. We also take into account heterogeneous disaster effects depending on the level of development and the intensity of disasters. Table 2 shows the regression results, where the disaster variables in column (1) count all events and those in column (2) count only severe events. Focusing on statistically significant coefficients in column (1), we see that FDI inflows to developing countries negatively respond to all types of disasters in the prior year (\(5.943-6.182=-0.239\)). In column (2), by contrast, they negatively respond to severe disasters in the prior 2 to 5 years (\(2.043-5.094=-3.051\)) and weakly do so to those in the prior 6 to 10 years (\(1.387-3.079=-1.692\)). These results suggest that if developing countries are hit by large scale disasters, their negative impact on FDI may continue in the medium and possibly long run.

These observations guide our theory in a way such that the negative long-term impact of disasters could be modeled as a switch between multiple equilibria of industrial configurations. Important aspects are that the equilibrium switch may be likely to occur in developing counties and to be brought especially by severe disasters. Building a model capturing these features, our aim is then to characterize the conditions under which FDI in developing countries shows resilience against substantial disasters.Footnote 16

Table 2 Disaster impact on FDI: recent vs. past disasters

3 The Model

Consider the host country and the foreign country, which comprises the rest of the world. There are two sectors: a differentiated-product sector and a homogeneous-product sector. In the differentiated sector, there are three types of firms: host domestic firms, multinationals, and foreign domestic firms. The last two are foreign-owned firms. Differentiated varieties have two roles: final goods for consumers in the two countries and intermediate goods for host domestic and multinational firms. To best fit our model in the context of developing countries, the host-country market is assumed to be small and localized and thus served by only host domestic firms, while the foreign-owned firms serve the foreign country’s market.Footnote 17 Foreign capital used as fixed costs of setting up foreign-owned firms is free to choose between the host and the foreign countries. The structure of our model, depicted in Fig. 1, is close to those of Markusen and Venables (1999); and Carluccio and Fally (2013). The crucial difference is, however, that unlike their models we combine local upstream and downstream firms into one local producer using roundabout production technology (Krugman and Venables 1995).Footnote 18 This simplification greatly helps us obtain analytical results, while maintaining a similar mechanism.

In the homogeneous sector, firms use labor to produce a homogeneous good. We assume that the good is freely traded and the unit labor requirement is unity. These imply that the good’s price is equal to both a constant world price and wage. We choose the homogeneous good as the numéraire, so that both the good price and the wage are unity. Labor is freely mobile between two sectors, which equalizes wages between the sectors.

Fig. 1
figure 1

Model structure

3.1 Tastes and Production

Consumers. The representative consumer in the host country has the following utility function:

$$\begin{aligned}&u=Q^{\alpha } (q^O)^{1-\alpha }, \nonumber \\&\text {where} \ \ Q=\left( \int q^c(\omega )^{\frac{\sigma -1}{\sigma }}d\omega \right) ^{\frac{\sigma }{\sigma -1}}, \end{aligned}$$
(1)

and where Q is the composite of the differentiated final goods and \(q^c(\omega )\) is the consumer demand for an individual variety of \(\omega\) produced by the host domestic firms. \(q^O\) is the demand for the numéraire good, \(\alpha\) is the expenditure share on final goods, and \(\sigma >1\) measures the elasticity of substitution between varieties. We solve the first-order condition (FOC) of utility maximization to obtain demand function for variety \(\omega\):

$$\begin{aligned}&q^c(\omega)=\left( \frac{p(\omega )}{P}\right) ^{-\sigma }\frac{E}{P}, \nonumber \\&\text {where}\ \ P=\left( \int p(\omega )^{ 1-\sigma }d\omega \right) ^{\frac{1 }{1-\sigma }}, \end{aligned}$$
(2)

and where p is the price of the variety and E is the aggregate expenditure on differentiated goods, which is equal to a \(\alpha\) share of income. The income of the representative consumer consists of labor income and excess profits repatriated by host domestic firms (if not zero). Noting that host domestic firms are symmetric, the price index, P, becomes

$$\begin{aligned}&P=\left( N p^{1-\sigma }\right) ^{\frac{1}{1-\sigma }} = N ^{\frac{1}{1-\sigma }} p, \end{aligned}$$
(3)

where N is the number (or mass) of host domestic firms. We will suppress the variety index of \(\omega\) in what follows.

Our focus is on the host country; hence, we do not describe in detail the market in the foreign country. The demand functions for a typical variety produced by multinational firms, \(i=m\), and foreign domestic firms, \(i=f\), are

$$\begin{aligned}&q_i = \left( \frac{p_i}{P^*} \right) ^{-\sigma } \frac{E^*}{P^*} \equiv p_i^{-\sigma } D^*, \ \ \ \ i \in \{ m, f\}, \end{aligned}$$
(4)

where \(P^*\) and \(E^*\) are respectively the price index and the total expenditure on differentiated goods in the foreign country. The market size of the foreign country is summarized by a constant \(D^* \equiv E^* (P^*)^{\sigma -1}\).

Host domestic firms. Each host domestic firm requires F amounts of labor for setup costs. Once established, they use \(\widetilde{a}\) units of a Cobb-Douglas composite input to produce one unit of output. The composite input comprises foreign intermediate goods (with a share \(1-\mu\)) and local intermediate goods produced by the differentiated sector itself (with a share \(\mu\)). The price of foreign intermediates is exogenously given by \(\tau p_u^*\), where \(p_u^* \ge 1\) is a constant free-on-board price and \(\tau \ge 1\) represents trade costs between the host country and the foreign country.Footnote 19 The minimized total cost to produce q units of a typical variety is then

$$\begin{aligned}&C(q)=P^{\mu } w^{1-\mu } \widetilde{a} q + wF = P^{\mu } \widetilde{a} q + F, \end{aligned}$$
(5)

noting that the wage is equal to one: \(w=1\). As the price elasticity of demand is given by \(\sigma\), which we will see later, the FOCs for profit maximization yield the usual constant-markup pricing:

$$\begin{aligned} p = \frac{\sigma \widetilde{a} P^{\mu } }{\sigma -1} = a P^{\mu }, \end{aligned}$$
(6)

where we choose \(\widetilde{a}\) such that \(\widetilde{a} = (\sigma -1)a/\sigma\). From Eqs. (3) and (6), we can rewrite the price index as

$$\begin{aligned} P =a^{\frac{1}{1-\mu }} N^{\frac{1}{(1-\sigma )(1-\mu )}}, \end{aligned}$$
(7)

which decreases with N because \(\sigma >1\) and \(\mu \in (0, 1)\),

Multinationals. Each multinational firm needs one unit of foreign capital to start operation and \(\widetilde{a}_m\) units of a composite input per unit of output. The composite input for multinationals is different from that for host domestic firms and is made up of foreign-produced intermediate goods (with a share \(1-\mu _m\)) and locally-produced intermediate goods (with a share \(\mu _m\)). The cost function for a typical multinational is then

$$\begin{aligned}&C_{m}(q_{m})= P^{\mu _m} (\tau p_u^*)^{1-\mu _m} \widetilde{a}_m q_m +r_{m}, \end{aligned}$$
(8)

where \(q_m\) is given by Eq. (4) and \(r_{m}\) is the rental rate of capital. The FOCs give the optimal price:

$$\begin{aligned} p_m = \frac{\sigma \widetilde{a}_m P^{\mu _m} (\tau p_u^*)^{1-\mu _m}}{\sigma -1} = a_m P^{\mu _m} (\tau p_u^*)^{1-\mu _m}, \end{aligned}$$
(9)

where \(\widetilde{a}_m\) is chosen such that \(\widetilde{a}_m = (\sigma -1)a_m/\sigma\).

Foreign domestic firms. Each foreign domestic firm needs one unit of foreign capital for setup costs and \(\widetilde{a}_m\) units of foreign intermediate goods per unit of output. They source all inputs from the foreign country’s suppliers, who we do not explicitly model, without incurring trade costs. The cost function for a typical foreign domestic firm is

$$\begin{aligned} C_f(q_f)=p_u^* \widetilde{a}_m q_f+r_f, \end{aligned}$$
(10)

where \(r_f\) is the rental rate of foreign capital for foreign firms. The optimal price for the variety is simply given by \(p_f = a_m p_u^*\).

Finally, we need to consider clearing conditions for goods and labor markets. The total output for the variety produced by each host domestic firm, q, must be equal to the sum of consumer demand and the intermediate-input demand by multinationals and host domestic firms themselves. By using Eq. (2) and applying Shepard’s lemma to Eqs. (5) and (7), we obtain

$$\begin{aligned} q&= \left( \frac{p}{P} \right) ^{-\sigma } \frac{E}{P} + N \frac{\partial C(q)}{\partial p} + N_m \frac{\partial C_m(q_m)}{\partial p} \nonumber \\&= p^{-\sigma } \left[ P^{\sigma -1}E + N \mu P^{\sigma +\mu -1} \widetilde{a} q + N_m \mu _m P^{\sigma +\mu _m -1} (\tau p_u^*)^{1-\mu _m} \widetilde{a}_m q_m \right] , \end{aligned}$$
(11)

noting that the demand elasticity is equal to the elasticity of substitution between varieties \(\sigma\).

Similarly, the labor demand in the differentiated sector can be derived by applying Shepard’s lemma to Eq. (5): \(N \cdot \partial C(q)/\partial w = N \left[ (1-\mu ) P^{\mu } \widetilde{a}q + F \right]\). The labor-market clearing requires that the sum of the labor demand in both the differentiated and the numéraire sectors must be equal to the total workforce in the host country, L. It determines the upper bound of N such that \(N \le \overline{N} \equiv L/F[\sigma (1-\mu )+\mu ]\) (see Appendix 1). In the numéraire sector, its labor demand and thus its outputs are adjusted in a way such that imports/exports of the good are balanced.

3.2 Industry Equilibrium

All three types of firms freely enter and exit from the differentiated sector. Let \(\Pi \equiv pq -C(q)\) be the excess profit of domestic firms, i.e., operating profits minus fixed costs. We assume a gradual entry-and-exit process governed by the law of motion such that \(\dot{N} = \Pi\), where the dot denotes the time derivative.Footnote 20 Entry occurs when \(\Pi >0\), while exit occurs when \(\Pi <0\). This adjustment process stops at the point where host domestic firms break even, that is, \(\Pi = 0\). Using Eqs. (5), (6), and (10), we can derive the combinations of N and \(N_m\) that satisfy \(\Pi = 0\) as

$$\begin{aligned}&\Pi = pq -C(q) = pq - P^{\mu } \widetilde{a} q - F = 0, \nonumber \\&\rightarrow N_m = \Theta N^{-\frac{\mu _m}{1-\mu }} \left( N -\alpha \overline{N} \right) , \nonumber \\&\text {where} \ \ \Theta \equiv \frac{ \sigma F {[}\sigma (1-\mu )+\mu ] \left[ a_m a^{\frac{\mu _m}{1-\mu }} (\tau p_u^*)^{1-\mu _m} \right] ^{\sigma -1} }{\mu _m D^*(\sigma -1) }, \ \ \ \ \overline{N} \equiv \frac{L}{F[\sigma (1-\mu ) +\sigma ]}, \end{aligned}$$
(12)

noting that \(\overline{N}\) represents the maximum number of host domestic firms, which depends on its workforce, L.

We draw a typical \(\Pi =0\)-locus in Fig. 2a with arrows indicating the direction of motions.Footnote 21 The locus has an upward slope under a reasonable condition that the expenditure share on varieties is not sufficiently small such that \(\alpha > 1 - (1-\mu )/\mu _m\), which we will assume throughout the paper.Footnote 22 The reason for the upward sloping locus is as follows. Suppose that the host economy is initially at the point on the \(\Pi =0\)-locus and then experiences an increase in the number of multinationals. This multinational entry generates positive profits by raising the intermediate-good demand. To maintain zero profits, a greater number of host domestic firms is necessary.

We turn to multinationals and foreign domestic firms. Let \(\Pi _i = p_i q_i - C_i(q_i)\) be the excess profit of firm \(i \in \{ m, f\}\). Then, free entry and exit lead to \(\Pi _i=0\), where the rental rate of foreign capital is exactly covered by operating profits: \(r_i = p_i q_i/\sigma\). As a result of the arbitrage behavior of foreign investors, foreign capital chooses the type of firms that generates higher rental rate/operating profits. Foreign capital becomes indifferent between becoming a multinational and a foreign domestic firm when the capital-return differential is zero:

$$\begin{aligned}&\Delta r_m \equiv r_m - r_f = p_m q_m/\sigma - p_f q_f/\sigma = 0, \nonumber \\&\rightarrow N = a^{\sigma -1} \left[ \tau ^{\frac{1-\mu _m}{\mu _m}} (p_u^*)^{-1} \right] ^{(\sigma -1)(1-\mu )} \equiv N_0, \end{aligned}$$
(13)

where we used Eqs. (4), (8) to (10) and \(p_f = a_m p_u^*\). A typical \(\Delta r_m = 0\)-locus is drawn in Fig. 2(b) with arrows indicating the direction of motion, where \(K_f\) is the total amount of foreign capital. The locus does not depend on the number of multinationals, \(N_m\), because the operating profits of both types of firms are independent of \(N_m\). What matters for the location decision of foreign capital is the price index of local intermediate goods, P, which depends only on N. The \(\Delta r_m = 0\)-locus, or equivalently the \(N=N_0\)-line is the threshold number of local suppliers above which foreign capital chooses to enter the host country.

As in the entry-and-exit of host domestic firms, we assume the gradual relocation process of foreign capital such that \(\dot{N}_m=\Delta r_m\). When \(\Delta r_m>0\) or \(N > N_0\), multinationals can produce at a lower marginal cost than foreign domestic firms, and thus all foreign capital eventually chooses to become the multinational, i.e., \(N_m=K_f\). When \(\Delta r_m<0\) or \(N<N_0\), the opposite is true and no foreign capital enters the host country, i.e., \(N_m=0\).

Fig. 2
figure 2

Equilibrium curves

Industry equilibrium, in which both the adjustments of N and \(N_m\) are completed, is determined by the relative positions of the two curves. When \(N_0 < \alpha \overline{N}\), foreign capital finds it more profitable to become the multinational than to become the foreign domestic firm even if there are few host domestic firms and hence P is high. More multinationals demand local intermediates, inducing more local suppliers to enter. Consequently, the host economy reaches point \(S_1: (N, N_m)=(\overline{N}, K_f)\), a stable equilibrium where both multinationals and host domestic firms coexist.

Meanwhile, when \(N_0 > \overline{N}\), no foreign capital prefers to become the multinational. The unique stable equilibrium is point \(S_2: (N, N_m)=(\alpha \overline{N}, 0)\), where only local firms operate in the host country. Since there are no intermediate-input demand by multinationals, the number of host domestic firms, \(\alpha \overline{N} = \alpha L/F[\sigma (1-\mu )+\sigma ]\), is constrained solely by the local expenditure on differentiated goods, \(E=\alpha L\).

When \(N_0\) is in between \(\alpha \overline{N}\) and \(\overline{N}\), both points, \(S_1\) and \(S_2\), are stable equilibria. Fig. 3 shows this situation. The foreign-capital-return differential is not large enough; hence, whether to enter the host country or to remain in the foreign country has no definite answer. Rather, the answer depends on the number of local firms currently prevailing in the host country. This complementarity between multinationals and host domestic firms creates a coordination problem. Foreign capital will enter the host country if local production is expected to expand. If there exists a prospect of multinationals increasing intermediate-input demand, more local suppliers will enter, leading the host economy to point \(S_1\). The same reasoning applies to point \(S_2\): local intermediate production is never expected to expand, if there is no prospect of multinational entry. Which of the two equilibria arises depends on the expectations of firms/investors and the initial industry configuration (Krugman 1991; Matsuyama 1991). Point U is a saddle but an unstable equilibrium, because our model does not include any jump variables to put the host economy on the saddle path.

Fig. 3
figure 3

Multiple equilibria

As \(\overline{N}\) is a function of fixed labor input F, it is convenient to characterize industry equilibrium using F. We assume that (a) the expenditure share on varieties is not too small such that \(\alpha >1-(1-\mu )/\mu _m\), in which case the \(\Pi =0\)-locus has an upward slope, and (b) it never touches the upper limit of \(N_m\), that is, a sufficiently large amount of foreign capital such that \(K_f > \Theta \overline{N}^{\frac{1-\mu -\mu _m}{1-\mu }} (1-\alpha )\) (see Eq. (12)). Then we obtain the following proposition.

Proposition 1

(Industry equilibrium). Using the fixed labor requirement for host domestic firms, F, industry equilibrium is characterized as follows:

  1. (i)

    If F is small such that \(F < F_a \equiv \alpha L/N_0[ \sigma (1-\mu )+\mu ]\), the configuration in which multinationals and host domestic firms coexist, \(S_1: (N, N_m)=(\overline{N}, K_f)\), is the only stable equilibrium.

  2. (ii)

    If F is large such that \(F > F_b \equiv L/N_0[ \sigma (1-\mu )+\mu ]\), the configuration in which all multinationals leave, \(S_2: (N, N_m)=(\alpha \overline{N}, 0)\), is the only stable equilibrium.

  3. (iii)

    If F is intermediate such that \(F_a \le F \le F_b\), both configurations are stable equilibria.

4 Natural Disasters and the Resilience of FDI

4.1 Adverse Shock to Local Firms

Let us now consider natural disasters in the host country. A disaster impact is modeled as an adverse shock to the fixed labor input for host domestic firms F, that is, an increase from F to \(F + \Delta F\) with \(\Delta F>0\). We examine (i) whether the natural disaster changes the equilibrium configuration, and if so (ii) when such a change is less likely to occur: that is, when the host economy is more likely to be resilient.

Suppose F is in between \(F_a\) and \(F_b\) and that the host economy is at point \(S_1: (N, N_m)=(\overline{N}, K_f)\). Fig. 4a depicts this situation and marks the initial point with a double circle. As shown by the thin dashed line in Fig. 4b, an increase in F raises labor used in each host domestic firm and hence reduces the maximum number of local suppliers the host country can support, i.e., a decrease from \(\overline{N}\) to \(\overline{N}'\). It means that more host domestic firms become unprofitable, moving also the \(\Pi =0\)-locus left. The \(\Delta r_m=0\)-locus does not change, however, as F does not directly enter the operating profits of multinationals and foreign domestic firms.

In Fig. 4b, the shock is so substantial that the new \(N=\overline{N}'\)-line is located to the left of the \(\Delta r_m=0\)-locus. The decline in local supplying industry raises input prices and thus makes multinationals unprofitable. If such an adverse effect reaches a certain threshold, multinationals suddenly start leaving the host country. Multinational exits in turn decreases demand for local intermediates and causes a further decline in the local industry. The dotted arrow in Fig. 4b traces the industry evolution: it goes left horizontally up to \(N_0\) and then goes lower left, heading for a new equilibrium at point \(S_2': (N, N_m)=(\alpha \overline{N}', 0)\), as indicated by a double circle in Fig. 4c.

Fig. 4
figure 4

Equilibrium switch due to a natural disaster (from panel (a) to (c))

The condition for the equilibrium switch to occur is

$$\begin{aligned}&\overline{N}' \equiv \frac{L}{(F +\Delta F)[\sigma (1-\mu ) + \mu ]} < N_0 \equiv a^{\sigma -1} \left[ \tau ^{\frac{1-\mu _m}{\mu _m}} (p_u^*)^{-1} \right] ^{(\sigma -1)(1-\mu )}, \nonumber \\&\rightarrow F +\Delta F> F_b \equiv \frac{L}{N_0[\sigma (1-\mu ) + \mu ]}, \nonumber \\&\rightarrow \Delta F > F_b - F \equiv \Delta F_{min}. \end{aligned}$$
(14)

A natural disaster causes a shift in equilibrium only if the magnitude of shock exceeds a certain threshold. In addition, as long as the location decision is myopic, the equilibrium shift is permanent.Footnote 23 This result echoes the long-lasting negative impact of severe disasters on FDI found by Toner-Rodgers and Friedt (2020) and the motivational observations we laid out in Table 2.

We can see that the threshold level of shock, \(\Delta F_{min}\), increases with the cost share of local intermediate goods in multinational production \(\mu _m\), and decreases with trade costs \(\tau\). Put differently, as \(\mu _m\) is higher or \(\tau\) is lower, the equilibrium switch is less likely to occur. Multinationals more dependent on low-price local intermediates (higher \(\mu _m\)) make greater profits, so that they are more likely to stay in the host country despite the decreased number of local suppliers.Footnote 24 Lower trade costs play a similar role by reducing the import price of foreign intermediates and thus making multinationals more profitable. Contrary to the concern of the Bank of Thailand, the 2011 flood did not cause drastic long-run changes in the location and production of manufacturing MNEs (Haraguchi and Lall 2015). This may reflect the fact that Thailand had already established strong linkages with multinationals and engaged in trade liberalization (Milner et al. 2006; Feliciano and Doytch 2020).

Assuming (a) \(\alpha >1-(1-\mu )/\mu _m\) and (b) \(K_f > \Theta \overline{N}^{\frac{1-\mu -\mu _m}{1-\mu }} (1-\alpha )\) as in Proposition 1, we can prove the following proposition (see Appendix 2 for the proof).

Proposition 2

(Natural disaster). Suppose that the fixed labor input, F, is intermediate so that multiple equilibria arise, i.e., \(F \in [F_a, F_b]\), and that the host economy is initially at point \(S_1\), where multinationals and host domestic firms coexist. If F increases to \(F+\Delta F\) due to a natural disaster, then the following holds:

  1. (i)

    If the level of shock is substantial such that \(F+\Delta F > F_b\), or equivalently \(\Delta F > \Delta F_{min}\), the equilibrium switches from \(S_1\) to \(S_2'\), where the host country loses all multinationals.

  2. (ii)

    The threshold level of shock increases with the cost share of local intermediate goods in multinational production (\(\mu _m\)) and decreases with trade costs (\(\tau\)), i.e., \(\partial (\Delta F_{min})/\partial \mu _m \ge 0\) and \(\partial (\Delta F_{min})/\partial \tau \le 0\), where equality holds at zero trade costs (\(\tau =1\)). That is, the natural disaster is less likely to trigger the equilibrium switch if multinationals are more dependent on local intermediate goods or they face lower trade costs.

4.2 Other Types of Shock

The essence of the above analysis is that the negative shock to local suppliers raises the cost of local sourcing and hence discourages foreign capital to stay in the host country. Other types of shocks that directly or indirectly raise the local-input price would give qualitatively the same result. For example, one can think of additional intra-national trade costs that local suppliers have to incur when delivering varieties to multinationals and consumers. Through the destruction of domestic transportation infrastructure, natural disasters may raise intra-national trade costs, leading to a higher local-input price. This translates into an upward shift of the \(\Pi =0\)-locus and a rightward shift of the \(\Delta r_m=0\)-locus (i.e., the \(N=N_0\)-line); however, it does not change the \(N=\overline{N}\)-line unlike the case in Section 4.1.Footnote 25 Our main results would maintain in this case. That is, if the level of shock is substantial, the equilibrium switches from the one with both local and multinational firms to the one with only local firms (Proposition 2(i)). Multinationals are more likely to stay in the disaster-hit host country if they rely more on local intermediates or they face lower trade costs (Proposition 2(ii)).

A more straightforward way to model natural disasters is direct shocks to multinationals, as documented in a number of disaster experiences in developing countries. Supposing that the fixed cost of capital for setting up a multinational increases from unity to \(F_m>1\), other things being equal, the capital return generated by multinationals decreases and foreign capital no longer finds the host country profitable. This results in a rightward shift of the \(\Delta r_m=0\)-locus.Footnote 26 Applying an analogous reasoning, we can confirm qualitatively the same results as Proposition 2.

5 Extensions

5.1 Multinationals with Heterogeneous Productivity

In the basic model, multinationals are all homogeneous in productivity. In reality, however, productivity differs among  multinationals, which may lead to heterogeneous responses to disasters. For example, Hayakawa et al. (2015) report that in the aftermath of the Thailand 2011 floods, changes in sourcing patterns of multinationals differ by their age and size, which are often associated with their productivity. We will see that introducing heterogeneous productive multinationals into the basic model would give richer implications and more realistic equilibrium configurations.

Heterogeneity comes from a stochastic draw of unit input requirements, \(\widetilde{a}_m = a_m (\sigma -1)/\sigma\), as in the literature on heterogeneous firm models (Melitz 2003; Baldwin and Okubo 2006). We assume that the cumulative density function of \(a_m \in [\underline{a}_m, \overline{a}_m]\) takes a truncated Pareto distribution. Namely, the probability of a multinational drawing productivity lower than \(a_m\) is

$$\begin{aligned}&G(a_m) = \frac{ a_m^{\rho } - \underline{a}_m^{\rho } }{ \overline{a}_m^{\rho } - \underline{a}_m^{\rho } } = \frac{ a_m^{\rho } - 1 }{ \overline{a}_m^{\rho } - 1 }, \end{aligned}$$

where \(\rho \ge 1\) is the shape parameter. We set \(\underline{a}_m\) to one without loss of generality. In addition, it is reasonable to assume that high-productive MNEs (lower \(a_m\)) enjoy lower trade costs (lower \(\tau\)) per unit shipped than low-productive firms due to scale economies in transportation (Forslid and Okubo 2015, 2016):Footnote 27

$$\begin{aligned} \tau (a_m) = a_m^{\gamma }, \end{aligned}$$

where \(\gamma >0\) governs the degree of scale economies in transportation. This specification implies that most productive firms with \(a_m=1\) have zero trade costs: \(\tau (1)=1\).

The return to foreign capital depends on its productivity and thus its relocation incentive also differs by productivity. Given the number of host domestic firms N, Fig. 5 shows a typical capital-return differential: \(\Delta r_m(a_m) \equiv r_m(a_m) - r_f(a_m)\), which captures the incentive to locate in the host country. The advantage of locating in the host country is a low cost of sourcing local intermediates, whereas its disadvantage is a high cost of sourcing foreign intermediates. For multinationals with lower \(a_m\), the advantage is more beneficial because of their larger amount of production, and the disadvantage is smaller thanks to scale economies of transportation. Hence more productive multinationals have a greater \(\Delta r_m(a_m)\) and thus a stronger incentive to locate in the host country, as shown in Fig. 5.

Fig. 5
figure 5

Location incentives of multinationals

As in the basic model, we consider a gradual relocation process. Namely, each foreign capital, initially located in the foreign country, incurs migration costs \(\chi\) to move to the host country. The migration costs are  assumed to be proportional to the flow of migrating capital, i.e., \(\chi =\dot{N}_m\) (Baldwin and Okubo 2006). Figure 5 tells that the first capital ready to pay the relocation costs will be those that have the most to gain, i.e., the most efficient foreign capital. In industry equilibrium where capital movement ceases, foreign capital with \(a_m \le a_m^R\) enters in the host country, whereas foreign capital with \(a_m > a_m^R\) remains in the foreign country, where \(a_m^R\) is the cut-off productivity at which the two locations are indifferent. The number of multinationals is thus given by

$$\begin{aligned} N_m = G(a_m^R)K_f = \frac{ (a_m^R)^{\rho } - 1 }{ \overline{a}_m^{\rho } - 1 } \cdot K_f, \end{aligned}$$

which increases \(a_m^R\).

Taking the migration of foreign capital into account, the entry and exit of local suppliers gradually take place. Fig. 6 illustrates industry equilibria in the \((N, N_m)\) plane, corresponding to Fig. 3. Unlike the basic model, the \(\Delta r_m(a_m^R)=0\)-locus is no longer a vertical line. Its upward slope comes from heterogeneous productivity: as the local supplying industry expands and the local-sourcing cost is lower, less productive foreign capital can enter. As a result, a few but very productive multinationals remain in point \(S_2\). In Appendix 3, we can check that multiple equilibria arise if the fixed labor requirement for host domestic firms, F, takes an intermediate value, just like the basic model (Proposition 1(iii)).

Fig. 6
figure 6

Industrial configurations under heterogeneous multinationals

Considering the effect of an increase in F due to a natural disaster, we can see in Fig. 7 qualitatively the same changes and the same intuition behind them as in the basic model. That is, the \(\Pi =0\)-locus moves up simply because lower profitability shrinks the area where host domestic firms can survive. The total number of local firms that the host country can accommodate decreases so that the \(N=\overline{N}\)-line moves left. As a result of these shifts, the new \(\Pi '=0\)-locus may no longer intersect at point U with the \(\Delta r_m(a_m^R)=0\)-locus, in which case the equilibrium would switch from \(S_1\) with many multinationals to \(S_2'\) with few multinationals. The unique but interesting difference from the basic model is clear from the new equilibrium \(S_2'\): the most efficient multinationals are the ones that remain in the disaster-hit country.Footnote 28

Fig. 7
figure 7

Impact of a natural disaster under heterogeneous multinationals

It can also be checked that if multinationals are more dependent on local suppliers (higher \(\mu _m\)), the disaster is less likely to trigger the equilibrium switch.Footnote 29 By imposing assumptions similar to those in Propositions 1 and 2, we can formally prove the following proposition. The proof and explicit expressions are given in Appendix 3.

Proposition 3

(Heterogeneous multinationals). Assume that multinationals are heterogeneous in a way that is specified in the text. Suppose that the fixed labor input, F, is intermediate so that multiple equilibria arise, i.e., \(F \in (\widetilde{F}_a, \widetilde{F}_b]\), and that the host economy is initially at point \(S_1\) with many multinationals. Consider an increase in F due to a natural disaster, then the following holds:

  1. (i)

    Multinationals with higher productivity are more likely to stay in the host country.

  2. (ii)

    The natural disaster is less likely to trigger the equilibrium switch from \(S_1\) to \(S_2'\), where the host country loses most of multinationals, if they are more dependent on local intermediates (higher \(\mu _m\)).

5.2 Reconstruction from Disasters

We have so far modeled a disaster as a permanent shock. Let us instead consider a temporal shock and uncover under what conditions foreign capital reenters the gradually recovering host country. The bottom line is that the host country re-attracts multinationals earlier, as (a) it recovers from the disaster more quickly, (b) they are more dependent on local intermediates or (c) they face lower trade costs. These conditions have in common with those in Propositions 2(ii) and 3(ii).

As long as the myopic relocation decision is assumed as before, no foreign capital comes back to the host country even if it fully recovers from the disaster. To allow for the possibility of reentering, we need to consider a forward-looking decision making of foreign capital: it chooses whether to become the multinational or the foreign domestic firm to maximize its lifetime return.Footnote 30

Consider the situation where the host country is hit by a natural disaster at time \(s=0\) and all multinationals leave there, corresponding to point \(S_2'\) in Fig. 4c. Suppose then that the increased fixed-labor input due to the disaster gradually gets back to the pre-shock level after some time T. Specifically, the fixed labor input at time s, denoted by F(s), is given by

$$\begin{aligned} F(s) ={\left\{ \begin{array}{ll} Fe^{\delta (T-s)} &{}\text {for} \ \ s \in [0, T) \\ F &{}\text {for} \ \ s \in [T, \infty ) \end{array}\right. }, \end{aligned}$$

where \(\delta\) is the recovery rate and we assume \(F(0) = Fe^{\delta T} > F_b \equiv L/N_0[\sigma (1-\mu ) +\mu ]\) and \(F \le F_b\). Letting \(t \ (\le T)\) be the time at which foreign capital moves from the foreign to the host country, the lifetime capital return, v(t), is given by

$$\begin{aligned} v(t)&\equiv \underbrace{\int _0^t e^{-\theta s} r_f ds}_{\text {Locate in foreign}} + \underbrace{\int _t^{T} e^{-\theta s} r_m'(s) ds +\int _T^{\infty } e^{-\theta s} r_m ds}_{\text {Locate in host}}, \end{aligned}$$

where \(\theta >0\) is the discount rate. For \(s \in [0, t)\), foreign capital remains in the foreign country and makes the flow return \(r_f\). It locates in the host country from time t onward. The flow return during recovery period \(s \in [t, T)\) is \(r_m'(s)\) and is fully recovered to the pre-shock level \(r_m (\ge r_m'(s))\) for \(s \in [T, \infty )\). The optimal timing of relocation can be derived from maximizing v(t) with respect to t.

One naturally expects that if reconstruction takes very long time (large T), foreign capital with positive discount rate \(\theta\) never relocates to the host country, i.e., \(t=\infty\). Furthermore, we see from Section 4.1 that multinationals make greater profits as the cost share of local intermediate goods in multinational production, \(\mu _m\), is higher or trade costs, \(\tau\), are lower. This should imply that a higher \(\mu _m\) or a lower \(\tau\) would make  multinationals’ reentering earlier (lower t). Assuming (a) \(\alpha >1-(1-\mu )/\mu _m\) and (b) \(K_f > \Theta \overline{N}^{\frac{1-\mu -\mu _m}{1-\mu }} (1-\alpha )\) as in Propositions 1 and 2, we can establish these arguments in Proposition 4 and formally prove them in Appendix 4.

Proposition 4

(Recovery from disaster). Consider the situation where a natural disaster hits the host country and there are no multinationals at time \(s=0\). The fixed labor input at time \(s=0\) is given by \(F(0) = Fe^T\) and gradually recovers to the pre-shock level F, according to \(F(s)=Fe^{\delta (T-s)}\), where it takes time T to fully recover and we assume \(F \le F_b < F(0)=Fe^T\). On the optimal timing \(s=t\) of multinational reentering, the following holds:

  1. (i)

    Multinationals never reenter the host country, i.e., \(t=\infty\), if the recovery time from the disaster is too long such that \(T>> \overline{T}\), where \(\overline{T}\) is a bundle of parameters distinct from T.

  2. (ii)

    Assuming a range of parameters that ensure interior solutions of optimal timing \(t \in (0, \infty )\), multinationals reenter the host country more quickly (smaller t), as the recovery time is shorter (smaller T). Assume, in addition, that trade costs are positive (\(\tau > 1\)) and the recovery time T is greater than but close to a bundle of parameters \(\widehat{T}\)distinct from T. Then, the optimal reentering timing t decreases with the cost share of local intermediate goods in multinational production (\(\mu_{m}\)) and increases with trade costs (\(\tau\)).

5.3 Other Extensions

5.3.1 Host Country’s Market

In the basic model, we assume that multinationals do not serve consumers in the host country. We can extend it in a way such that multinationals can provide final goods with both the host and the foreign markets, while foreign domestic firms still provide with the foreign market only. In the extended model, foreign capital is more likely to enter the host country rather than to remain in the foreign country. In fact, we can confirm that in any equilibria there is a positive number of multinationals. See Appendix 5 for details.

5.3.2 Endogenous Sourcing Patterns

In general, natural disasters do not only affect the location choice of multinationals but also their linkages with local suppliers. To describe the endogenous sourcing patterns, we allow foreign capital to choose either of the two types of multinationals: one type, called the H-multinational, with a high cost share of local intermediate goods \(\mu _m^H \in (0, 1)\) and the other type, called the L-multinational, with a low cost share \(\mu _m^L (<\mu _m^H)\). Because building a close relationship with local suppliers needs huge investment, it is reasonable to assume that the H-multinational incurs a greater fixed capital input than the L-multinational. Consider then a natural disaster hitting the host country where the H-multinationals operate, raising the fixed labor input for local suppliers F. If the magnitude of the shock is moderate, multinationals continue to stay in the host country, but they all switch to the L-multinational and depend less on local intermediates. The damaged local industry decreases the profitability of local sourcing and is thus unable to support the H-multinationals, which need higher fixed setup costs. See Appendix 6 for details.

5.3.3 Disaster Risk and the Timing of Leaving

Although the basic model assumes no uncertainty and myopic location decisions, empirical findings suggest that investor perceptions of risk of future disasters may also shape investment decisions in the long run (Toner-Rodgers and Friedt 2020). The disaster risk can be incorporated into the model in a way such that forward-looking multinationals choose the timing of leaving the host country while expecting future disasters. We can show that even when the damage of the (initial) shock is small, uncertainty itself may lead multinationals to move out of the host country even before the actual shock hits. The duration of stay becomes shorter as they perceive a higher frequency of disaster occurrence. See Appendix 7 for details.

6 Conclusion

This paper has developed a theoretical framework to address the resilience of multinationals against a severe shock such as natural disasters. Our focus is on two notable aspects of multinationals, footloose-ness and input-output linkages with local suppliers. These aspects give rise to multiple equilibria, one in which multinationals help local industry develop and the other in which they never enter. When a natural disaster seriously damages local suppliers and thus raises the prices of local intermediates, the equilibrium switch occurs: multinationals leave the host country and shall never return. The extreme case of the complete exit of multinationals can be avoided when allowing for heterogeneous productivity and the host country’s market. The discontinuous change in equilibrium due to severe disasters may help explain mixed evidences on the disaster impact on FDI mentioned in Introduction. When using disaster variables pooling all events with different intensities of damage, one may fail to find statistically significant coefficients on them. Mixed results may also come from sample countries with different development levels. Since the disaster preparedness of a country typically depends on its economic development level, damages are more likely to be severe in developing countries than developed ones.

Using the framework, we have identified under what conditions multinationals are more likely to stay in the disaster-hit host country. The key parameters are the share of local intermediate goods in multinational production and trade costs of foreign intermediate goods. In particular, as multinationals rely more on local suppliers and make greater profits through low sourcing costs, a decline in the local supplying industry due to natural disasters is less likely to affect their relocation decision. This insight carries over to the case where multinationals are heterogeneous and to the analysis of the timing of disaster reconstruction.

We believe that our model yields rich analytical outcomes, yet remains sufficiently simple to produce new insights into the nexus between natural disasters and multinationals. The analysis can be enriched in many ways. One way is to explicitly introduce local upstream and downstream firms and allow them to benefit from technology spillovers from multinationals. Using the extended model, one can distinguish between inter-industry (i.e., horizontal) and intra-industry (i.e., vertical) spillovers and examine their interactions with natural disasters. The degree of spillovers may decrease when greater disaster risk discourages MNEs’ commitment to local procurement. We leave this and other possible extensions to future research.