Skip to main content
Log in

Reconsidering Herbert A. Simon’s Major Themes in Economics: Towards an Experimentally Grounded Capital Structure Theory Drawing from His Methodological Conjectures

  • Published:
Computational Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

A Correction to this article was published on 04 January 2021

This article has been updated

Abstract

Drawing inspiration from a renowned critique of standard economics moved by Simon (Q J Econ 69(1):99–118, 1955, Am Econ Rev 49(3):253–283, 1959), the authors of this paper develop a novel experimental design moving beyond the hypothesis-testing framework traditionally based on the use of deductive logic, while introducing a new way suitable for addressing the problem of understanding the impact of fluctuations and uncertainty in business decision-making. As claimed in the paper, this can be achieved by adopting an abductive approach to research design that incorporates an experimental methodology based on an original computerised real effort task, so that to explore firms—and other forms of business organisations—serving as experimental incubators in the market process, pursuing a range of economic enquiries more adherent to real world business applications. Among these enquiries, in this paper the authors focus on firms’ capital structure decisions in order to attempt to advance existing knowledge on the topic of experimental business research within the framework of economics.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Change history

Notes

  1. Among several critics, see Hirshleifer (1965), Hirshleifer and Riley (1979), Kaldor (1982) and Simon (1982).

  2. It is worth remembering that unlike the conventional heuristics of the earliest programme introduced by Kahneman and Tversky (1974), the heuristics in the post-Kahneman–Tversky era are focused on spelled-out and articulated algorithms (Gigerenzer and Goldstein 1996). These heuristics are supposed to make humans smart in terms of Simon’s (1982) approach to bounded rationality, rather than being merely misleading or revealing cognitive illusions and shortcomings. Therefore, Simon considered cognitive and informational constraints in a broader sense than Kahneman’s and Tversky’s subsequent analysis narrowed.

  3. Simon’s view of uncertainty regarded the future environment, the reactions of other agents, and changes in one’s own tastes and values.

  4. As explained in more detail in Sect. 3, we refer to the bailout cost as a device to deal with corporate insolvency.

  5. In particular, we refer to Knight’s concept of structural uncertainty, or “Knight-Keynes” uncertainty (Taleb 2010).

  6. We refer mainly to controlled experiments of the type lab and extra-lab, especially of the Internet type, so as to involve several countries and cultures, though this future study has already been started.

  7. Simon’s satisficing is a hybrid term (neologism) that encapsulates the combination of satisfying and sufficing (a more in-depth explanation of satisficing is provided in Velupillai 2010b).

  8. The idea of identifying design with problem-solving and pursuing it under the umbrella of bounded rationality has been lively discussed and debated across scientific disciplines for decades (e.g., see Newell et al. 1962; Schön 1983; Rowe 1987; Hatchuel 2001; Visser 2006, 2009).

  9. A design space is characterised by different types of initial knowledge and hypothesis, generally understood in terms of a set of characteristics and measures, according to which a multidimensional design space is defined involving a number of interrelated activities, and within which the ultimate solution must be sought as if design was a search (Newell and Simon 1972; Hatchuel et al. 2005).

  10. Other authors have been interested in the topic of computable economics, such as Rabin (1957) and Lewis (1986, 1991), but they are not closely related to the purpose of this study.

  11. The experimental design proposed in this paper has to be run with human subjects and, as a control group, with real-life entrepreneurs.

  12. An algorithm to relate the experimental design to randomly assigned human subjects.

  13. In this regard, we draw on experiences from (1) design science in information systems research (Simon 1996 [1969]; Hevner et al. 2004); (2) computer-supported business games and simulations (Meier et al. 1969; March and Smith 1995; Sutcliffe 2002); and (3) a specific entrepreneurial framework with its financial and microeconomic aspects (Giulini et al. 2012) closely connected to the works of Myers and Majluf (1984) and of Koeva (2009) among others.

References

  • Atkinson, G., & Whalen, C. J. (2011). Futurity: Cornerstone of post-Keynesian institutionalism. In C. J. Whalen (Ed.), Financial instability and economic security after the Great Recession. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar Publishing.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bagliano, F.-C., & Bertola, G. (2004). Models for dynamic macroeconomics. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Barros, G. (2010). Herbert A. Simon and the concept of rationality: Boundaries and procedures. Brazilian Journal of Political Economy, 30(3), 455–472.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baumol, W. J. (1968). Entrepreneurship in economic theory. American Economic Review, 58(2), 64–71.

    Google Scholar 

  • Becker, G. S. (1976). The economic approach to human behavior. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Bianchi, M., & Henrekson, M. (2005). Is neoclassical economics still entrepreneurless? Kyklos, 58(3), 353–377.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bradley, M., Jarrell, G. A., & Kim, E. H. (1984). On the existence of an optimal capital structure: Theory and evidence. Journal of Finance, 39(3), 857–878.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brüggen, A., & Strobel, M. (2007). Real effort versus chosen effort in experiments. Economics Letters, 96(2), 232–236.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Carpenter, J., Matthews, P., & Schirm, J. (2010). Tournaments and office politics: Evidence from a real effort experiment. American Economic Review, 100(1), 504–517.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chang, H.-J. (2014). Economics: The user’s guide. New York: Bloomsburry Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chen, S.-H., & Kao, Y. F. (2016). Herbert Simon and agent-based computational economics. In R. Frantz & L. Marsh (Eds.), Minds, models and milieux—Commemorating the centennial of the birth of Herbert Simon (pp. 113–144). London: Palgrave Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Clarkson, G. P. E., & Simon, H. A. (1960). Simulation of individual and group behavior. American Economic Review, 50(5), 920–932.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cross, N. (2004). Expertise in design: An overview. Design Studies, 25(5), 427–442.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dasgupta, S. (2003). Multidisciplinary creativity: The case of Herbert A. Simon. Cognitive Science, 27, 683–707.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dow, S. (2015). Addressing uncertainty in economics and the economy. Cambridge Journal of Economics, 39(1), 33–47.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Doyle, Sir A. C. (1986) [1891]. A scandal in Bohemia. In Sir A. C. Doyle (1986) Sherlock Holmes: The complete novels and stories (Vols. 1 and 2). New York: Bantam Books.

  • Falk, A., & Fehr, E. (2003). Why labour market experiments? Labour Economics, 10(4), 399–406.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fisher, I. (1933). The debt-deflation theory of great depressions. Econometrica, 1(4), 337–357.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Flannery, M. J., & Rangan, K. P. (2006). Partial adjustment toward target capital structures. Journal of Financial Economics, 79(3), 469–506.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Foss, N. J. (2003). Bounded rationality in the economics of organization: “Much cited and little used”. Journal of Economic Psychology, 24, 245–264.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gigerenzer, G., & Goldstein, D. G. (1996). Reasoning the fast and frugal way: Models of bounded rationality. Psychological Review, 103(4), 650–669.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gill, D., & Prowse, V. (2012). A structural analysis of disappointment aversion in a real effort competition. The American Economic Review, 102(1), 469–503.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Giulini, G., Bucciarelli, E., & Silvestri, M. (2012). Exploring firms’ financial decisions by human and artificial agents. In J. Filipe & A. Fred (Eds.), ICAART 2012 (Vol. 2, pp. 184–189). Setúbal: SciTePress.

    Google Scholar 

  • Griliches, H. Z. (1986). Economic data issues. In H. Z. Griliches & M. D. Intriligator (Eds.), Handbook of econometrics (Vol. 3, pp. 1466–1514). Amsterdam: Elsevier.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hanson, N. R. (1958). Patterns of discovery—An inquiry into the conceptual foundations of science. Cambridge, MA: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hanson, N. R. (1960). Is there a logic of scientific discovery? Australasian Journal of Philosophy, 38, 91–106.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Harris, M., & Raviv, A. (1991). The theory of capital structure. The Journal of Finance, 46(1), 297–355.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Harrison, G. W., & List, J. A. (2004). Field experiments. Journal of Economic Literature, 42(4), 1009–1055.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hartman, R. (1972). The effect of price and cost uncertainty on investment. Journal of Economic Theory, 5(2), 258–266.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hatchuel, A. (2001). Towards design theory and expandable rationality: The unfinished program of Herbert Simon. Journal of Management and Governance, 5(3–4), 260–273.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hatchuel, A., Le Masson, P., & Weil, B. (2005). The development of science-based products: Managing by design spaces. Creativity and Innovation Management, 14(4), 345–354.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hevner, A., March, S. T., Park, J., & Ram, S. (2004). Design science in information systems research. Management Information Systems Quarterly, 28(1), 75–105.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hirshleifer, J. (1965). Investment decision under uncertainty: Choice-theoretic approaches. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 79(4), 509–536.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hirshleifer, J., & Riley, J. G. (1979). The analytics of uncertainty and information—An expository survey. Journal of Economic Literature, 17(4), 1375–1421.

    Google Scholar 

  • Holt, C. C., Modigliani, F., Muth, J. F., & Simon, H. A. (1960). Planning production, inventories and work force. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall.

    Google Scholar 

  • Holt, C. C., Modigliani, F., & Simon, H. A. (1955). Linear decision rule for production and employment scheduling. Management Science, 2(2), 1–30.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jacobides, M. G. (2015). Rethinking the financial crisis: Structuring our historical understanding of a predictable evolutionary disaster. Business History Review, 57(5), 716–735.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kahneman, D., & Tversky, A. (1974). Judgment under uncertainty: Heuristics and biases. Science, 185(4157), 1124–1131.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kaldor, N. (1982). The scourge of monetarism. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Knight, F. (1921). Risk, uncertainty and profit. Boston: Houghton Mifflin.

    Google Scholar 

  • Koeva P. (2009). Time-to-build and convex adjustment costs. Working paper no. 1/09. Washington: International Monetary Fund.

  • Krippendorff, K. (2007). Design research: An oxymoron? In R. Michel (Ed.), Design research—Essays and selected projects (pp. 67–80). Zürich: Birkhäuser Verlag.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Kulkarni, D., & Simon, H. A. (1988). The processes of scientific discovery: The strategy of experimentation. Cognitive Science, 12(2), 139–175.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kulkarni, D., & Simon, H. A. (1990). Experimentation in machine discovery. In J. Shrager & P. Langley (Eds.), Computational models of scientific discovery and theory formation (pp. 255–273). San Mateo, CA: Morgan Kaufmann.

    Google Scholar 

  • Langley, P., Simon, H. A., Bradshaw, G. L., & Zytkow, J. M. (1987). Scientific discovery: Computational explorations of the creative processes. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Lewis, A. A. (1986). Structure and complexity: The use of recursion theory in the foundations of neoclassical mathematical economics and game theory. Manuscript/Monograph. Ithaca, NY: Department of Mathematics, Cornell University.

  • Lewis, A. A. (1991). Some aspects of effectively constructive mathematics that are relevant to the foundations of neoclassical mathematical economics and the theory of games. Unpublished Manuscript. Irvine, CA: Department of Philosophy and the School of Social Sciences, University of California at Irvine.

  • Lindblom, C. E. (1959). The science of “muddling through”. Public Administration Review, 19(2), 79–88.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lopez-Iturriaga, F., & Rodriguez-Sanz, J. A. (2008). Capital structure and institutional setting: A decompositional and international analysis. Applied Economics, 40(14), 1851–1864.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lucas, R. E., Jr. (1981). Studies in business cycle theory. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mabsout, R. (2015). Abduction and economics: The contributions of Charles Peirce and Herbert Simon. Journal of Economic Methodology, 22(4), 491–516.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • March, S. T., & Smith, G. F. (1995). Design and natural science research on information technology. Decision Support Systems, 15(4), 251–266.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Meier, R. C., Newell, W. T., & Pazer, H. L. (1969). Simulation in business and economics. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice Hall.

    Google Scholar 

  • Modigliani, F., & Miller, M. H. (1958). The cost of capital, corporate finance, and the theory of investment. The American Economic Review, 48(3), 261–297.

    Google Scholar 

  • Myers, S. C., & Majluf, N. S. (1984). Corporate financing and investment decisions when firms have information that investors do not have. Journal of Financial Economics, 13(2), 187–221.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nelson, R. R., & Winter, S. G. (1974). Neoclassical vs. evolutionary theories of economic growth: Critique and prospectus. The Economic Journal, 84(336), 886–905.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Newell, A., Shaw, J. C., & Simon, H. A. (1962). The process of creative thinking. In H. E. Gruber, G. Terrel, & M. Wertheimer (Eds.), Contemporary approaches to creative thinking (pp. 63–119). New York: Atherton Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Newell, A., & Simon, H. A. (1972). Human problem solving. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall Inc.

    Google Scholar 

  • Newell, A., & Simon, H. A. (1976). Computer science as empirical inquiry: Symbols and search. Communications of the ACM, 19(3), 113–126.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Noussair, C. N., & Tucker, S. (2013). Experimental research on asset pricing. Journal of Economic Surveys, 27(3), 554–569.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Peirce, C. S. (1931). Collected papers, Vol. 1 of 8, Principles of philosophy. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

  • Peirce, C. S. (1934). Collected papers, Vol. 5 of 8, Pragmatism and pragmaticism. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

  • Penrose, E. (1995). The theory of the growth of the firm. Foreword to the third edition, reprinted by Oxford University Press, New York.

  • Popper, K. R. (1957). The aim of science. Ratio, 1: 25–35, reprinted in Objective knowledge (1972). Oxford: Clarendon Press.

  • Putnam, H. (1992). Comments on the lectures. In C. S. Peirce & K. L. Ketner (Eds.), Reasoning and the logic of things. The Cambridge conferences lectures of 1898 (pp. 55–104). Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rabin, M. O. (1957). Effective computability of winning strategies. In M. Dresher, A. W. Tucker, & P. Wolfe (Eds.), Annals of mathematics studies, No. 39: Contributions to the theory of games (Vol. 3, pp. 147–157). Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ross, S. A. (1977). The determination of financial structure: The incentive-signalling approach. The Bell Journal of Economics, 8(1), 23–40.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rowe, P. G. (1987). Design thinking. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rubinstein, M. E. (1973). A mean–variance synthesis of corporate financial theory. Journal of Finance, 28(1), 167–181.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sarasvathy, S. D. (2003). Entrepreneurship as a science of the artificial. Journal of Economic Psychology, 24(2), 203–220.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sarasvathy, S. D. (2004). Making it happen: Beyond theories of the firm to theories of firm design. Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice, 28(6), 519–531.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sargent, T. J., & Wallace, N. (1975). “Rational” expectations, the optimal monetary instrument and the optimal money supply rule. Journal of Political Economy, 83(2), 241–254.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sargent, T. J., & Wallace, N. (1981). Rational expectations and the theory of economic policy. In R. E. Lucas Jr. & T. J. Sargent (Eds.), Rational expectations and econometric practice (pp. 199–213). Minneapolis: University of Minnesota Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schauten, M., & Spronk, J. (2010). Optimal capital structure. In C. Zopounidis & P. M. Pardalos (Eds.), Handbook of multicriteria analysis. Applied optimization (Vol. 103, pp. 405–423). Berlin: Springer.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Schön, D. A. (1983). The reflective practitioner: How professionals think in action. London: Temple-Smith.

    Google Scholar 

  • Simon, H. A. (1955). A behavioral model of rational choice. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 69(1), 99–118.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Simon, H. A. (1956). Rational choice and the structure of the environment. Psychological Review, 63(2), 129–138.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Simon, H. A. (1957) (1976) (1997) [1945]. Administrative behavior: A study of decision-making processes in administrative organizations (4th ed.). New York: Free Press.

  • Simon, H. A. (1959). Theories of decision-making in economics and behavioral science. American Economic Review, 49(3), 253–283.

    Google Scholar 

  • Simon, H. A. (1962). The architecture of complexity. Proceedings of the American Philosophical Society, 106(6), 467–482.

    Google Scholar 

  • Simon, H. A. (1965). The logic of rational decision. The British Journal for the Philosophy of Science, 16, 169–186.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Simon, H. A. (1973). Does scientific discovery have a logic? Philosophy of Science, 40(4), 471–480.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Simon, H. A. (1977), Models of discovery and other topics in the methods of science, Dordecht: D. Riedel. Previously published in Van Roostelaar and Staal (eds.) (1968). Logic, methodology and philosophy of sciences III. Amsterdam: North-Holland Publishing.

  • Simon, H. A. (1978). Information-processing theory of human problem solving. In W. K. Estes (Ed.), Handbook of learning and cognitive processes: V. Human information (pp. 271–295). Oxford: Lawrence Erlbaum.

    Google Scholar 

  • Simon, H. A. (1982). Models of bounded rationality. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Simon, H. A. (1984). On the behavioral and rational foundations of economic dynamics. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 5(1), 35–55.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Simon, H. A. (1987). Making management decisions: The role of intuition and emotion. The Academy of Management Executive, 7(1), 57–63.

    Google Scholar 

  • Simon, H. A. (1995). Artificial intelligence: An empirical science. Artificial Intelligence, 77(1), 95–127.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Simon, H. A. (1996) [1969]. The sciences of the artificial (1st ed. 1969, 3rd ed. 1996). Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.

  • Simon, H. A. (1997). Machine discovery. Foundations of Science, 2, 171–200.

    Google Scholar 

  • Simon, H. A. (2000). Bounded rationality in social science: Today and tomorrow. Mind & Society, 1(1), 25–39.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Simon, H. A., & Ando, A. (1961). Aggregation of variables in dynamic systems. Econometrica, 29(2), 111–138.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Simon, H. A., & Hayes, J. R. (1976). Understanding process: Problem isomorphs. Cognitive Psychology, 8, 165–190.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Simon, H. A., Langley, P. W., & Bradshaw, G. L. (1981). Scientific discovery as problem solving. Synthese, 47(1), 1–27.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stiglitz, J. E. (1969). A re-examination of the Modigliani–Miller theorem. American Economic Review, 59(5), 784–793.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sutcliffe, M. (2002). Simulations, games and role-play. In P. Davies (Ed.), The handbook for economic lecturers (pp. 1–26). Bristol: The Higher Education Academy Education Network.

    Google Scholar 

  • Taleb, N. N. (2010). The black swan: The impact of the highly improbable (2nd ed.). New York: Random House.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tirole, J. (2006). The theory of corporate finance. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • van Dijk, F., Sonnemans, J., & van Winden, F. (2001). Incentive systems in a real effort experiment. European Economic Review, 45(2), 187–214.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Velupillai, K. (2000). Computable economics. The Arne Ryde memorial lectures. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Velupillai, K. V. (2010a). Computable foundations for economics. London: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Velupillai, K. V. (2010b). Foundations of boundedly rational choice and satisficing decisions. Advances in Decision Sciences, 2010, 1–16.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Velupillai, K. V. (2018). Models of Simon. Abingdon: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Velupillai, K. V., & Kao, Y.-F. (2014). Computable and computational complexity theoretic bases for Herbert Simon’s cognitive behavioral economics. Cognitive Systems Research, 29–30, 40–52.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Visser, W. (2006). The cognitive artifacts of designing. Mahwah, NJ: Lawrence Erlbaum Associates.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Visser, W. (2009). Design: One, but in different forms. Design Studies, 30(3), 187–223.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Winter, S. G. (2016). The place of entrepreneurship in “the economics that might have been”. Small Business Economics, 47(1), 15–34.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Yang, G.-A., Chueh, H., & Lee, C.-H. (2014). Examining the theory of capital structure: Signal factor hypothesis. Applied Economics, 46(10), 1127–1133.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zimring, C. M., & Craig, D. L. (2001). Defining design between domains: An argument for design research à la carte. In C. Eastman, M. McCracken, & W. Newstetter (Eds.), Design knowing and learning: Cognition in design education (pp. 125–146). Amsterdam: Elsevier.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

We are very grateful to Kumaraswamy Vela Velupillai for prompting us to further explore Herbert A. Simon’s issues, even related to experimental design research. Furthermore, we are both very grateful to Stefano Zambelli and Shu-Heng Chen for many enlightening conversations and helpful comments on earlier drafts.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Edgardo Bucciarelli.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Bucciarelli, E., Mattoscio, N. Reconsidering Herbert A. Simon’s Major Themes in Economics: Towards an Experimentally Grounded Capital Structure Theory Drawing from His Methodological Conjectures. Comput Econ 57, 799–823 (2021). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10614-018-9808-7

Download citation

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10614-018-9808-7

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation