Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Third-party intervention in secessions

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
Economics of Governance Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper presents and solves a model of ethnically motivated warfare which treats annexations as the explicit outcomes of secessions. An ethnic group within one country may want to engage in a secession in order to join its ethnic peers in the annexing country. The annexing country decides whether or not to support the separatist ethnic group in the conflict. I use this model to discuss how equilibrium behavior depends on economies of scale in the public good provision, ethnic heterogeneity, and sanctions. Among others, I find that sanctions can have the seemingly paradoxical effect of increasing conflict intensity

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. (Yektas et al. 2019) provide a model which nests the specific payoff structures of wars of conquest and independence. However, they focus on the inherent asymmetric payoff structure of these conflicts and not on their implications for the size of countries.

  2. See, among others, (Akerlof 1997) and (Akerlof and Kranton 2000, 2002, 2005) on identity.

  3. A further motivation could be the prevention of the spread of conflict to its neighboring countries. See (Salehyan and Gleditsch 2006) and (Gleditsch 2007) for an analysis on the risk of transnational spread of civil war.

  4. See (Bolton et al. 1996) for an overview on this literature.

  5. I abstract from collective action problems. Among others, (Caselli and Coleman 2013; Esteban and Ray 2008), and (Esteban and Ray 2011) argue that ethnicity solves collective action problems. Ethnicity enforces group membership and helps to exclude non-members. Furthermore, within-group inequality promotes the appearance of ethnic group conflicts. Rich members of the ethnic group provide financial aid, while poor members of the same ethnic group provide conflict labor. These arguments justify the abstraction of collective action problems in ethnic groups.

  6. See (Blattman and Miguel 2010) for a survey of the literature on civil conflict.

  7. See (Gershenson 2002) for a theoretical model on sanctions in conflicts.

  8. There is a large literature which looks at collective action problems. See for example (Olson and Zeckhauser 1966) and (Berkok 2006).

  9. This model assumes that ethnic groups are not mobile. See (Olofsgård 2003) for an analysis with mobile ethnic groups. This paper further abstracts from the possibility of transfers. The central government can not suggest transfers in order to avoid a conflict. See (Haimanko et al. 2005) on this topic.

  10. See (Hirshleifer 1989, 1991) and (Skaperdas 1996) for an analysis of contest success functions, and (Konrad 2009) and (Nitzan 1994) on contests in general. See also (Clark and Riis 1998) for an extension of the axiomatic analysis to unfair contests and (Corchón and Dahm 2010) for an investigation of the foundations for contest success functions.

  11. See (Epstein and Hefeker 2003) for this particular type of contest success function. See also (Garfinkel 2004a, b), and (Skaperdas 1998) for an analysis of alliances and group formation in conflicts, and (Bozbay and Vesperoni 2018) for an axiomatic foundation of network conflicts.

  12. The model in this paper does not allow for peaceful agreement in order to avoid conflict.

  13. These sanctions are imposed by an exogenous fourth party. This fourth party is not explicitly modeled in this approach for reasons of tractability. One may think of the fourth player as supranational organizations or alliances which are able to impose effective sanctions on a country.

  14. This utility is independent on the provision of conflict support.

  15. It holds that \(\frac{\partial ^{2} V_{L}}{\partial ^{2} b_{L}}=-\frac{2b_{M}(\lambda _{M}+b_{R})}{[(\lambda _{M}+b_{R})b_{M}+b_{L}]^{3}}S_{M}t\).

  16. It holds that \(\frac{\partial ^{2} V_{M}}{\partial ^{2} b_{M}}=-\frac{2b_{L}(\lambda _{M}+b_{R})^{2}}{[(\lambda _{M}+b_{R})b_{M}+b_{L}]^ {3}}[(S_{M}+S_{R})t-(1+S_{M})\alpha t]\).

  17. It holds that \(\frac{\partial ^{2} V_{R}}{\partial ^{2} b_{R}}=-\frac{2b_{M}^{2}b_{L}(\lambda _{M}+b_{R})}{[(\lambda _{M}+b_{R})b_{M} +b_{L}]^{3}}S_{M}t\).

  18. This assumption is consistent with the previously made assumptions \((S_{R}+S_{M})t-\alpha t(1+S_{M})> 0\) and \(S_{M}t-(1+S_{M})\alpha t<0\).

  19. The results for the remaining exogenous factors and for the case \(\lambda _{M}\ge \lambda ^{\kappa }\) can be provided upon request.

References

  • Akerlof GA (1997) Social distance and social decisions. Econometrica 65(5):1005–1027

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Akerlof GA, Kranton RE (2000) Economics and identity. Quart J Econ 115(3):715–753

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Akerlof GA, Kranton RE (2002) Identity and schooling: some lessons for the economics of education. J Econ Lit 40(4):1167–1201

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Akerlof GA, Kranton RE (2005) Identity and the economics of organizations. J Econ Perspect 19(1):9–32

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Alesina A, Perotti R, Spolaore E (1995) Together or separately? Issues on the costs and benefits of political and fiscal unions. Euro Econ Rev 39(3–4):751–758

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Alesina A, Spolaore E (1997) On the number and size of nations. Quart J Econ 112(4):1027–1056

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Amegashie JA (2014) Asymmetric information and third-party intervention in civil wars. Def Peace Econ 25(4):381–400

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Amegashie JA, Kutsoati E (2007) (Non)intervention in intra-state conflicts. Euro J Polit Econ 23(3):754–767

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Berkok UG (2006) Third country demand for peacekeeping. Def Peace Econ 17(5):473–485

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blattman C, Miguel E (2010) Civil war. J Econ Lit 48(1):3–57

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bolton P, Roland G (1997) The breakup of nations: a political economy analysis. Quart J Econ 112(4):1057–1090

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bolton P, Roland G, Spolaore E (1996) Economic theories of the break-up and integration of nations. Euro Econ Rev 40(3–5):697–705

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bozbay I, Vesperoni A (2018) A contest success function for networks. J Econ Behav Organ 150(C):404–422

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Carment D, Rowlands D (1998) Three’s company: evaluating third party intervention in intrastate conflict. J Confl Resolut 42(5):572–599

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Caselli F, Coleman WJ (2013) On the theory of ethnic conflict. J Euro Econ Assoc 11(s1):161–192

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chang Y-M, Potter J, Sanders S (2007) War and peace: third party intervention in conflict. Euro J Polit Econ 23(4):954–974

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chang YM, Sanders S (2009) Raising the cost of rebellion: the role of third-party intervention in intrastate conflict. Def Peace Econ 20(3):149–169

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Clark DJ, Riis C (1998) Contest success functions: an extension. Econ Theory 11(1):201–204

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Corchón L, Dahm M (2010) Foundations for contest success functions. Econ Theory 43(1):81–98

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Epstein GS, Hefeker C (2003) Lobbying contests with alternative instruments. Econ Gov 4(1):81–89

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Esteban J, Ray D (2008) On the salience of ethnic conflict. Am Econ Rev 98(5):2185–2202

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Esteban J, Ray D (2011) A model of ethnic conflict. J Euro Econ Assoc 9(3):496–521

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Garfinkel MR (2004) On the stability of group formation: managing the conflict within. Confl Manag Peace Sci 21(1):43–68

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Garfinkel MR (2004) Stable alliance formation in distributional conflict. Euro J Polit Econ 20(4):829–852

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gershenson D (2002) Sanctions and civil conflict. Economica 69(274):185–206

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gleditsch KS (2007) Transnational dimensions of civil war. J Peace Res 44(3):293–309

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Goyal S, Staal K (2004) The political economy of regionalism. Euro Econ Rev 48(3):563–593

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Haimanko O, Le Breton M, Weber S (2005) Transfers in a polarized country: bridging the gap between efficiency and stability. J Public Econ 89(7):1277–1303

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hentschel F (2019) Unraveling secessions. J Conf Resolut 63(6):1517–1541

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hirshleifer J (1989) Conflict and rent-seeking success functions: ratio vs. difference models of relative success. Public Choice 63(2):101–112

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hirshleifer J (1991) The technology of conflict as an economic activity. Am Econ Rev 81(2):130–134

    Google Scholar 

  • Konrad KA (2009) Strategy and dynamics in contests. Oxford University Press, Oxford

    Google Scholar 

  • Nitzan S (1994) Modelling rent-seeking contests. Euro J Polit Econ 10(1):41–60

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Olofsgård A (2003) Incentives for secession in the presence of mobile ethnic groups. J Public Econ 87(9–10):2105–2128

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Olson M, Zeckhauser R (1966) An economic theory of alliances. Rev Econ Stat 48(3):266–279

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Regan PM (1998) Choosing to intervene: outside interventions in internal conflicts. J Polit 60(3):754–779

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Regan PM (2002) Third-party interventions and the duration of intrastate conflicts. J Conf Resolut 46(1):55–73

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Regan PM, Aydin A (2006) Diplomacy and other forms of intervention in civil wars. J Conf Resolut 50(5):736–756

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Salehyan I, Gleditsch KS (2006) Refugees and the spread of civil war. Int Organ 60(2):335–366

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sambanis N, Skaperdas S, Wohlforth W (2020) External intervention, identity, and civil war. Comp Polit Stud 53(14):2155–2182

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Siqueira K (2003) Conflict and third-party intervention. Def Peace Econ 14(6):389–400

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Skaperdas S (1996) Contest success functions. Econ Theory 7(2):283–290

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Skaperdas S (1998) On the formation of alliances in conflict and contests. Public Choice 96(1–2):25–42

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Spolaore E (2008) Civil conflict and secessions. Econ Gov 9(1):45–63

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wittman D (2000) The wealth and size of nations. J Conf Resolut 44(6):868–884

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Yektas H, Hoffmann M, Hentschel F, Hodler R (2019) Wars of conquest and independence. J Inst Theor Econ 175(4):617–640

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

I would like to thank an anonymous referee, the editor of this journal, Luis Corchón, Tina Hentschel, Roland Hodler, and Martin Kolmar for helpful comments and discussions

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Friedhelm Hentschel.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Appendix

Appendix

Lemma 3

Player L’s best response is \(b_{L}(b_{M},b_{R})=\sqrt{(\lambda _{M}+b_{R})b_{M}\Pi _{R}}-(\lambda _{M}+b_{R})b_{M}\) if \(\Pi _{R}>(\lambda _{M}+b_{R})b_{M}\) holds, and \(b_{L}(b_{M},b_{R})=0\) otherwise. Player M’s best response is \(b_{M}(b_{L},b_{R})=\sqrt{\frac{b_{L}}{(\lambda _{M}+b_{R})}S_{M}\Pi _{M}}-\frac{b_{L}}{(\lambda _{M}+b_{R})}\) if \(S_{M}\Pi _{M}>\frac{b_{L}}{(\lambda _{M}+b_{R})}\) holds, and \(b_{M}(b_{L},b_{R})=0\) otherwise. Player R’s best response is \(b_{R}(b_{L},b_{M})=\sqrt{\frac{S_{R}}{1+\Psi }\frac{b_{L}}{b_{M}}\Pi _{R}}-\lambda _{M}-\frac{b_{L}}{b_{M}}\) if \(\frac{S_{R}}{1+\Psi }\frac{b_{L}}{b_{M}}\Pi _{R}>(\lambda _{M}+\frac{b_{L}}{b_{M}})^{2}\) holds, and \(b_{R}(b_{L},b_{M})=0\) otherwise.

Figure 4 plots the best response functions for all three players; and shows that the best response functions’ shifts to changes can be ambiguous with respect to each other.

Fig. 4
figure 4

Players’ best response functions for \(\lambda _{M}=1/2, S_{M}=1, t=1/2, S_{R}=3, \alpha =1/2, \Psi =1/10\). Left: Player M’s and L’s best response functions holding player R’s choice variable fixed with \(b_{R}=0.1\) and \(b_{R}=0.2\). Right: Player M’s and R’s best response functions holding player L’s choice variable fixed with \(b_{L}=0.1\) and \(b_{L}=0.2\)

Player L raises \(b_{L}(b_{M},b_{R})\) with diminishing marginal rate if his potential loss increases. Furthermore, player L raises \(b_{L}(b_{M},b_{R})\) with increasing \(b_{M},b_{R}\), and \(\lambda _{M}\) if his gain from preventing a secession is sufficiently high, i.e., if \(4 b_{M}<\Pi _{R}/(b_{R}+\lambda _{M})\) is satisfied. Otherwise, it is too costly for player L to fight a secession and he reduces his conflict bid.

Player M raises \(b_{M}(b_{L},b_{R})\) with diminishing marginal rate if his potential gain increases. He also raises \(b_{M}(b_{L},b_{R})\) with increasing \(b_{L}\) if his gain from a secession is sufficiently high, i.e., if \(S_{M}\Pi _{M}>4b_{L}/(\lambda _{M}+b_{R})\) is satisfied. Otherwise, it is too costly for player M to fight a secession and he reduces his conflict bid. Furthermore, player M raises \(b_{M}(b_{L},b_{R})\) with increasing \(b_{R}\) and \(\lambda _{M}\) if his gain from winning the conflict is sufficiently low, i.e., if \(S_{M}\Pi _{M}<4b_{L}/(\lambda _{M}+b_{R})\) is satisfied. Player M’s conflict bid is large if his gain from conflict is large. In this case, player R’s support allows player M to reduce his bid without imposing a loss on himself.

Player R raises \(b_{R}(b_{L},b_{M})\) with diminishing marginal rate if his potential gain increases. Sanctions always reduce player R’s willingness to provide support. He also raises \(b_{R}(b_{L},b_{M})\) with increasing \(b_{L}\) if his gain from a secession is sufficiently high, i.e., if \(S_{R}\Pi _{R}/(1+\Psi )>4b_{L}/b_{M}\) is satisfied. Otherwise, it is too costly for player R to provide support and he reduces his conflict bid. Furthermore, player R raises \(b_{R}(b_{L},b_{M})\) with increasing \(b_{M}\) if his gain from a successful secession is sufficiently low, i.e., if \(S_{R}\Pi _{R}/(1+\Psi )<4b_{L}/b_{M}\) is satisfied.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Hentschel, F. Third-party intervention in secessions. Econ Gov 23, 65–82 (2022). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10101-022-00270-5

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10101-022-00270-5

Keywords

JEL Classification:

Navigation