Skip to main content
Log in

The zecca mint: a self-enforcing monetary constitution in historic venice

  • Review Article
  • Published:
Economics of Governance Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Monetary history is largely a repeated narrative of currency debasement. Yet historic Venice (1172–1797), ruled by elite patricians, stands out as an example of relative monetary stability. This paper provides a historical case of Venice’s Zecca Mint which provided the elite patricians of Venice with a stable currency, playing a role in fostering the economic success of the Republic of Venice. This paper identifies three factors that together formed a self-enforcing monetary constitution to inhibit public currency debasement in historic Venice: (i) the assignment of public debt to patricians, (ii) the nearly uniform trade-centric focus of the patricians and (iii) the use of turn-taking in office for mintmasters.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. The term Zecca comes from the Arabic word Sikka which means “coin die”.

  2. Although warfare made debasement likely, it was less frequent in Italian city states compared to principalities. Princes debased in the absence of exceptional needs while mercantile influence on monetary policies favoured relative stability (Chilosi and Volckart 2010).

  3. See also Beaulier and Boettke 2009; Boaz 2011.

  4. For Venetian patterns of trade and trading routes, see De Lara 2007; Lane 1973: 68–73; Lopez 1976: 95, 1982: 314, 389, 393; Luzzatto 1952: 90–3.

  5. The Council of Forty approved the issue of the ducat on 31 October 1284 while its minting began in March 1285 (Stahl 2000a: 30–32).

  6. By 1400, Venetian coinage circulated from London to Yemen (Robbert 1983).

  7. According to Munro (2003: 516), “virtually everybody agreed that forced loans were a necessary obligation imposed on all citizens, in defending their state and because volition was at the very core of the usury doctrine, many theologians and jurists justified the payment and receipt of interest with some version of damnum emergens or interes.” Damnum emergens is “a compensation for damages or loss that the lender incurred after having made the loan: for example, from not having the money accessible in an emergency-a fire or storm that destroyed his barns or livestock” (Munro 2003: 511).

  8. Jones (1997: 398) states that the first Italian evidence that he has found for a forced loan was at Pisa, in 1162.

  9. The merchant class outside the Italian city states generally lacked political power and had little say in monetary policy.

  10. Major institutional reforms strengthened the system of checks and balances under Doge Sebastiano Ziani, in 1172 and 1173. For instance, the number of ducal counsellors was increased from two to six. Also, to ensure that the doge would not be able to choose his own successor, the Great Council was charged with naming a committee of 11 whose task was to elect the new doge (Coggins and Perali 1998).

  11. From the fourteenth century, aggressive debasement became increasingly common. Kohn (1999: 17) writes, “[u]sually, it was the exigencies of war that precipitated a sequence of major debasement. For example, from 1542 to 1551, England's Henry VIII ordered some ten debasements, each of 30–40%. In all, Henry's ‘Great Debasement’ reduced the silver content of the pound sterling from 6.4 troy ounces so less than one troy ounce. The seigniorage rate, 2% before the debasement, rose to 57% and, at its peak seigniorage accounted for 25% of crown revenue.” Similarly, “in 1349, Philip VI of France derived 70% of his total revenue from seigniorage” (Kohn 1999:17).

  12. Table 8.5, Minting Profits and State Finances (Stahl 2000a: 200).

  13. Venice was not a merchant-manufacturer city like most its Italian counterparts. Therefore, Venetians did not benefit from the effect of debasement on real wages. In Florence for instance, merchant-manufactures were not entirely averse to debasement of silver currency. A Florentine statute prohibited the fixing of wages in gold and therefore, the merchant oligarchy possibly supported debasement as a way of lowering real wages (Kohn 1999, 29).

  14. According to Leeson (2011: 306), “constitutions are unlikely to be effective when the individuals charged with executing them have little incentive to do so.”.

  15. While culling (systematic removal of heavier coins from circulation), clipping and counterfeiting were serious problems the Venetian mint faced, private currency debasement and the measures taken to inhibit them fall beyond the scope of this present paper.

  16. See also Glassman and Redish (1988: 8) for more on the impact of competition on seigniorage fee.

References

  • Barzun J (2000) From dawn to decadence. HarperCollins Publishers, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Beaulier S, Boettke P (2009) Hiding debt just a juggling trick. The Independent Institute. https://www.independent.org/news/article.asp?id=2660. Accessed 25 Mar 2021

  • Boaz D (2011) Deficits, debt and debasement. Cato Institute. https://www.cato.org/blog/deficits-debt-debasement. Accessed 25 Mar 2021

  • Boettke P, Leeson P (2004) Liberalism, socialism and robust political economy. J Mark Moral 7(1):99–111

    Google Scholar 

  • Boettke P, Salter A, Smith DJ (2021) Money and the rule of law: generality and predictability in monetary institutions. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Boettke P, Smith DJ (2016) Evolving views on monetary policy in the thought of Hayek, Friedman and Buchanan. The Review of Austrian Economics 29(4):351–370

    Google Scholar 

  • Bond S (2017) 11 currency and control: mint workers in the later roman empire. In: Verboven K, Laes C (eds) Work, labour and professions in the Roman world. Brill, Leiden, pp 227–245. https://doi.org/10.1163/9789004331686_012

  • Bordo MD, Schwartz AJ (1987) The importance of stable money: theory and evidence. In: Schwartz A (ed) Money in historical perspective. University of Chicago Press, Chicago, pp 255–270

    Google Scholar 

  • Bouwsma W (1968) Venice and the defense of republican liberty. University of California Press, Berkeley and Los Angeles

    Google Scholar 

  • Briones I, Rockoff H (2005) Do economists reach a conclusion on free-banking episodes? Econ J Watch 2(2):279–324

    Google Scholar 

  • Buchanan JM, Brennan HG (1981) Monopoly in money and inflation. Hobart Paper 88

  • Buchanan JM, Wagner R (1977[2000]) Democracy in deficit: the political legacy of Lord Keynes. Liberty Fund Inc, Indianapolis

  • Burns AR (2013) Money and monetary policy in early times. Routledge

    Google Scholar 

  • Calomiris C, Kahn C (1996) The efficiency of self-regulated payment systems: learning from the Suffolk System. J Money, Credit, Bank 28(4):766–797

    Google Scholar 

  • Chilosi D, Volckart O (2010) Good or bad money?: debasement, society and the state in the late Middle Ages. Department of Economic History, London School of Economics working paper no. 140/10

  • Ching FDK, Jarzombek MM, Prakash V (2011) A global history of architecture, 2nd edn. Wiley, Hoboken

    Google Scholar 

  • Cipolla CM (1963) Currency depreciation in medieval Europe. Econ Hist Rev 15(3):413–422

    Google Scholar 

  • Click RW (1998) Seigniorage in a cross-section of countries. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, pp 154–171

  • Coggins JS, Perali CF (1998) 64% majority rule in ducal Venice: voting for the doge. Public Choice 97(4):709–723

    Google Scholar 

  • Davis JH (2004) A quantity-based annual index of US industrial production, 1790–1915. Quart J Econ 119(4):1177–1215

    Google Scholar 

  • Davis JH (2006) An improved annual chronology of US business cycles since the 1790s. J Econ Hist 66(1):103–121

    Google Scholar 

  • Day WR Jr (2003) Zecca: the mint of Venice in the Middle Ages. Speculum 78(2):602–605

    Google Scholar 

  • De Lara YG (2002) Zecca: the mint of Venice in the Middle Ages. By Alan M. Stahl. Johns Hopkins University Press, Baltimore 2000, pp. 497. Book Reviews. J Econ Hist 62(4):1138–1139

  • De Lara YG (2007) Institutions, information and contracts: from debt to equity in late medieval Venice. Stanford University and University of Alicante, Mimeo

    Google Scholar 

  • De Lara YG (2008) The secret of Venetian success: a public-order, reputation-based institution. Eur Rev Econ Hist 12:247–285

    Google Scholar 

  • Dornbush R (2000) Keys to prosperity: free markets, sound money and a bit of luck. MIT Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Dotson J (2002) The Venetian money market: banks, panics and the public debt, 1200–1500. Reinhold c Mueller Speculum 77(1):223–225

    Google Scholar 

  • Dowd K (1989) The state and the monetary system. Allan P, Hemel Hempstead and St. Martin's Press, New York

  • Dowd K (1991) The evolution of central banking in England. In: Capie F, Wood GE (eds) Unregulated banking: chaos or order? Macmillan, London, pp 1821–1890

    Google Scholar 

  • Dowd K (ed) (1992) The experience of free banking. Routledge, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Dowd K (1994) Competitive banking, bankers’ clubs and bank regulation. J Money, Credit, Bank 26(2):289–308

    Google Scholar 

  • Durant TC (2011) Making executive politics mutually productive and fair. Const Polit Econ 22(2):141–172

    Google Scholar 

  • Durant TC, Weintraub M (2014) An institutional remedy for ethnic patronage politics. J Theor Polit 26(1):59–78

    Google Scholar 

  • Durant TC, Weintraub M, Houser D, Li S (2018) Trust in the executive: requiring consensus and turn-taking in the experimental lab. J Peace Res 55(5):609–624. https://doi.org/10.1177/0022343318765918

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ferraro JM (2012) Venice: history of the floating city. Cambridge University Press, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Fink ZS (1945) The classical republicans: an essay in the recovery of a pattern of thought in seventeenth-century England, 2nd edn. Resource Publications, Eugene

    Google Scholar 

  • Finlay R (1980) Politics in renaissance Venice. Rutgers University Press, New Brunswick

    Google Scholar 

  • Friedman M (1960[1992]) A program for monetary stability. Fordham University Press, New York

  • Gilbert F (1991) The Pope, his banker and Venice. Harvard University Press, Boston

    Google Scholar 

  • Glasner D (1989) Free banking and monetary reform. Cambridge University Press

    Google Scholar 

  • Glassman D, Redish A (1988) Currency depreciation in early modern England and France. Explor Econ Hist 25(1):75–97

    Google Scholar 

  • Goodhart C (1998) The two concepts of money: implications for the analysis of optimal currency areas. Eur J Polit Econ 14(3):407–432

    Google Scholar 

  • Goodhart C, Masciandaro D, Ugolini S (2021) Pandemic recession, helicopter money and central banking: Venice, 1630. CEPR discussion paper no. DP15715

  • Grendler PF (1990) The leaders of the Venetian state, 1540–1609: a prosopographical Analysis. Studi Veneziani 19:35–85

    Google Scholar 

  • Hazlitt WC (1966) The venetian republic, its rise, its growth and its fall A.D. 409–1797. AMS Press, New York

  • Hogan TL (2015) Has the fed improved US economic performance? J Macroecon 43:257–266

    Google Scholar 

  • Hogan T, Smith DJ, Aguiar-Hicks R (2018) Central banking without romance. Eur J Comp Econo 15(2):293–314

    Google Scholar 

  • Horodowich E (2009) A brief history of Venice: a new history of the city and its people. Constable & Robinson Ltd, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Howard D (1975) Jacopo Sansovino: architecture and patronage in Renaissance Venice. Yale University Press, New Haven and London

    Google Scholar 

  • Jones P (1997) The Italian city-state. Clarendon Press, Oxford

    Google Scholar 

  • Kohn MG (1999) Medieval and early modern coinage and its problems. Dartmouth College, department of economics working paper no. 99–02. https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.151828

  • Lane F (1973) Venice, a maritime republic. JHU Press

  • Lane F, Mueller R (1985) Money and banking in medieval and renaissance Venice, vol 1: Coins and moneys of account. Johns Hopkins University Press, Baltimore

  • Leeson PT (2011) Government, clubs and constitutions. J Econ Behav Organ 80(2):301–308

    Google Scholar 

  • Levy M (1981) Factors affecting monetary policy in an era of inflation. J Monet Econ 8(3):351–373

    Google Scholar 

  • Lopez RS (1971) The Commercial Revolution of the Middle Ages, 950–1350. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Lopez RS (1976) The commercial revolution of the Middle Ages, 959–1350. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Lopez RS (1982) Il commercio dell’Europa medievale: il Sud. In: Postan MM, Rich EE (eds) Storia economica Cambridge. Commercio e inustria nel Medioevo, vol 2. Einaudi, Turin

  • Luzzatto G (1952) Studi di storia economica veneziana. Cedam, Padua

  • Madden TF (2003) Enrico Dandolo and the rise of Venice. Johns Hopkins University Press, Baltimore

    Google Scholar 

  • Madden TF (2012) Venice: a new history. Viking, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Markowitz M (2015) Serenissima: medieval coinage of Venice. CoinWeek Ancient Coin Series. https://coinweek.com/worldcoins/serenissima-medieval-coinage-of-venice/. Accessed 20 Feb 2021

  • McKinnon RI (2010) Money and capital in economic development. The Brookings Institution Press

  • Miron JA, Romer CD (1990) A new monthly index of industrial production, 1884–1940. J Econ Hist 50(2):321–337

    Google Scholar 

  • Mueller RC (1997) The Venetian money market: banks, panics and the public debt, 1200–1500. Johns Hopkins University Press, Baltimore and London

    Google Scholar 

  • Munro JH (2003) The medieval origins of the financial revolution: usury, rentes and negotiability. Int Hist Rev 25(3):505–562

    Google Scholar 

  • Munro JH (2012) The technology and economics of coinage debasements in medieval and early modern Europe: with special reference to the low countries and England. Working Papers tecipa-456, University of Toronto, Department of Economics

  • Nair M (2016) Caste as self-regulatory club: evidence from a private banking system in nineteenth century India. J Inst Econ 12(03):677–698

    Google Scholar 

  • Naismith R (2018) Money and coinage in the Middle Ages. Brill, Leiden

  • Pennington M (2011) Robust political economy. Policy: A J Public Policy Ideas 27(4):8–11

  • Pezzolo L (2003) The Venetian government debt, 1350–1650. In: Boone M, Davids K, Janssens P (eds) Urban public debts, urban government and the market for annuities in Western Europe (14th-18th centuries), pp 61–74

  • Pirenne H (1937) Economic and social history of medieval Europe. Harcourt, Brace and Company, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Puga D, Trefler D (2014) International trade and institutional change: medieval Venice’s response to globalization. Q J Econ 129(2):753–821

    Google Scholar 

  • Queller DE (1986) The Venetian patriciate: reality versus myth. University of Illinois Press, Urbana and Chicago

    Google Scholar 

  • Reed RR, Ghossoub EA (2012) The effects of monetary policy at different stages of economic development. Econ Lett 117(1):138–141

    Google Scholar 

  • Reinhart C, Rogoff K (2009) This time is different: eight centuries of financial folly. Princeton University Press

    Google Scholar 

  • Rider C (2010) Law and the illicit in medieval Europe-Edited by Ruth Mazo Karras, Joel Kaye and E. Ann Matter Early Medieval Europe 18(1):125–126

    Google Scholar 

  • Robbert L (1974) Reorganization of the Venetian coinage by Doge Enrico Dandolo. Speculum 49(1):48–60

    Google Scholar 

  • Robbert L (1983) Monetary flows-Venice, 1150 to 1400. Precious Metals in the Later Medieval and Early Modern Worlds, pp 53–78

  • Ruggiero G (1980) Violence in early renaissance Venice. Rutgers University Press

  • Salter A (2014) Is there a self-enforcing monetary constitution? Const Polit Econ 25(3):280–300

    Google Scholar 

  • Selgin GA (1988) The theory of free banking: money supply under competitive note issue. Rowman & Littlefield Pub Inc

  • Selgin GA (2008) Good money: Birmingham button makers, the royal mint and the beginnings of modern coinage, 1775–1821. University of Michigan Press

    Google Scholar 

  • Selgin GA, Lastrapes WD, White LH (2012) Has the fed been a failure? J Macroecon 34(3):569–596

    Google Scholar 

  • Selgin GA, White LH (1987) The evolution of a free banking system. Econ Inq 25(3):439–457

    Google Scholar 

  • Smith A (1776) An inquiry into the nature and causes of the wealth of nations: volume one. Printed for Strahan W and Cadell T, London

  • Smith DJ (2020) Turn-taking in office. Const Polit Econ 31(2):205–226

    Google Scholar 

  • Smith DJ, Crowley GR, Leguizamon S (2020) Long live the doge? death as a term limit on Venetian chief executives. Public Choice, pp 1–27

  • Stahl AM (2000a) Zecca: the mint of Venice in the Middle Ages. JHU Press

  • Stahl AM (2000b) A prosopography of medieval Venetian mint officials. Medieval Prosopography 21:41–131

    Google Scholar 

  • Stahl AM (2007) Coins for trade and for wages: the development of coinage systems in medieval Venice. Wages and currency: global comparisons from antiquity to the twentieth century. Peter Lang, Bern, pp 193–209

  • Stahl AM (2011) Learning from the Zecca. the medieval mint of Venice as a model for pre-modern minting. The Numismatic Chronicle (1966-) 171:347–354

  • Strathern P (2013) The Venetians. Pegasus Books, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Timberlake RH (1984) The central banking role of clearinghouse associations. J Money, Credit, Bank 16(1):1–15

    Google Scholar 

  • White LH (1984) Free banking in Britain: theory, experience and debate, 1800–1845. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • White LH (2020) The dynamics of competitive coinage: evidence from private mints in the American gold rushes. GMU working paper in economics no. 19–41. https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.3499386

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Rania Adel Al-Bawwab.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Al-Bawwab, R.A. The zecca mint: a self-enforcing monetary constitution in historic venice. Econ Gov 23, 1–15 (2022). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10101-021-00260-z

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10101-021-00260-z

Keywords

JEL Codes

Navigation