Skip to main content
Log in

The city and the region as contrasts in spatial organization

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
The Annals of Regional Science Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Within a number of disciplines, the terms “city” and “region” are frequently referred to in combination, raising the obvious question as to the relationship between two. The central focus of the paper involves an attempt to identify the more significant differences between the city and the region in terms of their respective modes of spatial organization. This is undertaken from three broad perspectives. The first compares the individual city and the individual region as independent entities, while the second perspective considers the city in relation to the region in which it is located. A third perspective is concerned with a system of cities in comparison with a system of regions. The latter part of the discussion examines alternative definitions of the city, and the extent to which these may be regarded as satisfactory.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. For nations with populations of less than around 50 m (particularly if these are also territorially extensive) a minimum built-city population below the 200,000 level would be more realistic, while a value greater than 200,000 might be more appropriate for nations with populations in excess of 50 m. On particular occasions it has been found desirable to allow the minimum population of the built city to vary according to the overall population density within different geographical sections of a nation (Bogue 1950, p. 16).

  2. In contrast to the nodal region, a region based on a river basin is frequently not organized around a particular city or node, while the polycentric urban region has no single city occupying a position of clear dominance.

  3. In other respects, cities can be said to be in competition, since firms in different cities compete for markets, skilled labor, capital, entrepreneurial talent, etc. Within the individual city, competition for land among the various users is obviously present.

  4. There were, of course, exceptions to this spacing of cities, and mention has already been made of the twin-city phenomenon. In other instances, the expansion of a group of neighboring independent cities (and smaller urban centers) eventually coalesced to form of a single urban concentration such as Boston in the USA and Birmingham in the UK.

  5. As used in this subsection (and as commonly employed in the literature), the term “density function” refers exclusively to marginal density, i.e., the density at distance x from the center of the city or the region. By contrast, average density is the population density within the area extending from a central location to a perimeter at distance x. The relationship between the two types of function (marginal and average) is discussed by Holden and Parr (2013).

  6. It might be supposed that the existence of an urban center in the hinterland at a particular distance from the core city of the region would cause a secondary peak in distance–density plot. This tends not to be the case, however. Each point on a distance–density plot (from which the best-fitting function is derived) refers to the mean density throughout the relevant concentric ring. This has the effect of smoothing the form of plot, usually leading to a suppression of a local peak. In the Bogue (1950) study, the vast majority of the regional distance–density plots did not display secondary peaks.

  7. The argument here does not refer to those agglomeration economies (usually of urbanization type) which are enjoyed by firms in non-core cities of the region. These are appropriately termed “local agglomeration economies.”

  8. If the focus is on all urban centers, which would include those well below the minimum level for the built city of 200,000 (\(p_{h}\) in Fig. 2a), net entry of centers into the system over a given interval would be negligible or nonexistent. As a consequence and assuming the law of proportionate effect to be in operation, the steady-state distribution would tend to the cumulative lognormal, as in the case of regions.

  9. In Fig. 3a (and also Fig. 3b), the right section of the x axis refers to the population–area relation, while the left section refers to the density–area relation (considered shortly).

  10. An upper limit below 100 % is necessary, in order to exclude the relatively few workers that are employed in the built city but who reside at particularly long distances from it. Without such a limit, the workforce city would become unrealistically large.

  11. In a compact nation with a high population density, the various functional urban areas might form a space-filling set, as in the study of the Netherlands by Klaassen et al. (1981). Outcomes such as this may also be due to the selection of a relatively low minimum-population level for cities on which the functional urban areas are based.

  12. The problem is exacerbated if the added units are of a relatively large areal extent, as tends to be the case for certain MSAs in the western states of the USA, where the “added” counties are especially large. This difficulty does not arise in the case of the various forms of the extended city considered in Sect. 7.1, where the areal extent of the added units is deliberately small.

References

  • Aitchison J, Brown JC (1957) The lognormal distribution. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Alonso W (1964) Location and land use. Harvard University Press, Cambridge

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Barrow CJ (1998) River basin development planning and management: a critical review. World Dev 26:171–186

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Beavon KSO (1977) Central place theory: a reinterpretation. Longman, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Berry BJL, Goheen P, Goldstein H (1968) Metropolitan area definition: a re-evaluation of concept and statistical practice. Working Paper No. 28. US Department of Commerce, Bureau of the Census, Washington DC

  • Berry BJL, Horton FE (1970) Geographic perspectives on urban systems. Prentice-Hall, Englewood Cliffs

    Google Scholar 

  • Bogue DJ (1950) The structure of the metropolitan community: a study of dominance and subdominance. Horace H. Rackham School of Graduate Studies, University of Michigan, Ann Arbor

    Google Scholar 

  • Boudeville J (1966) Problems of regional economic planning. Edinburgh University Press, Edinburgh

    Google Scholar 

  • Cheshire PC, Hay DG (1989) Urban problems in Western Europe: an economic analysis. Unwin Hyman, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Christaller W (1933/1966) Die zentralen Orte in Süddeutschland. Gustav Fischer, Jena, Germany. Translated by C W Baskin as Central places in Southern Germany. Prentice-Hall, Englewood Cliffs

  • Clark C (1951) Urban population densities. J Roy Stat Soc Ser A 114:490–496

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Davoudi S (2003) Polycentricity in European Spatial Planning: from an analytical tool to a normative agenda. Eur Plan Stud 11:979–999

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dickinson RE (1947) City, region and regionalism. Routledge and Kegan Paul, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Duncan OD, Scott WR, Lieberson S, Duncan BD, Winsborough HH (1960) Metropolis and region. Johns Hopkins Press, Baltimore

    Google Scholar 

  • Evans AW (1973) The economics of residential location. Macmillan, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Fox KA, Kumar TK (1965) The functional economic area: delineation and implications for economic analysis and policy. Pap Reg Sci Assoc 15:57–85

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gibrat R (1931) Les inégalités économiques. Libraire du Receuil Sirey, Paris

    Google Scholar 

  • Haggett P (1965) Locational analysis in human geography. Edward Arnold, London

  • Hall P (1991) Moving information: a tale of four technologies. In: Brotchie J, Batty M, Hall P, Newton P (eds) Cities of the 21st century. Longman, Melbourne, pp 1–21

    Google Scholar 

  • Hall P, Hay DG (1980) Growth centres in the European urban system. Heinemann, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Hall P, Pain K (2006) The polycentric metropolis: learning from mega-city regions in Europe. Earthscan, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Harris CD, Ullman EL (1945) The nature of cities. Ann Am Acad Polit Sci 242:7–17

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hewings GJD, Parr JB (2007) Spatial interdependence in a metropolitan setting. Spat Econ Anal 2:8–22

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Holden D, Parr JB (2013) A note on the average density function in urban analysis. Urban Stud 50:3027–3035

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Klaassen LH, Boudrez JA, Vollmulle J (1981) Transport and urbanization. Gower, Aldershot

    Google Scholar 

  • Kloosterman RC, Musterd S (2001) the polycentric urban region: towards a research agenda. Urban Stud 38:623–669

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Levy L (2009) Gibrat’s law for (all) cities: comment. Am Econ Rev 99:1672–1675

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lösch A (1944/1954) Die räumliche Ordnung der Wirtschaft (2nd edn). Gustav Fischer, Jena, Germany. The economics of location (trans: Woglom WH, Stolper WF). Yale University Press, New Haven

  • Lotka AJ (1925) Elements of physical biology. Williams and Watkins, Baltimore

    Google Scholar 

  • Meijers EJ, Romein A, Hoppenbrouwer EC (eds) (2003) Planning polycentric regions in Northwest Europe. Delft University Press, Delft

    Google Scholar 

  • Meyer J (1963) Regional economics: a survey. Am Econ Rev 53:19–54

    Google Scholar 

  • Nairn AGM, O’Neill GJ (1988) Population density functions: a differential equation approach. J Reg Sci 28:89–102

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Newling BE (1969) The spatial variation of population densities. Geogr Rev 59:242–252

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Organization for Economic Co-operation and Development (2012) Redefining urban: a new way to measure metropolitan areas. OECD Publishing, Paris

  • Parr JB (2005) Perspectives on the city-region. Reg Stud 39:555–566

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Parr JB (2007) Spatial definitions of the city: four perspectives. Urban Stud 44:381–392

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Parr JB (2012) Spatial-structure differences between urban and regional systems. Ann Reg Sci 49:293–303

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Parr JB, Holden D (2015) The regional density function and the definition of regional boundaries. In: Nijkamp P, Rose A, Kourtit K (eds) Regional science matters: studies dedicated to Walter Isard. Springer, Heidelberg, pp 71–86

    Google Scholar 

  • Portnov B (2012) Does the choice of geographic units matter for the validation of Gibrat’s Law? Région et Développement 36:79–106

    Google Scholar 

  • Rosenthal SS, Strange WC (2003) Evidence on the nature and sources of agglomeration economies. In: Henderson JV, Thisse J-F (eds) Handbook of regional and urban economics: cities and geography. Elsevier, Amsterdam, pp 2119–2179

    Google Scholar 

  • Scott AJ (ed) (2001) Global city regions: trends, theory, policy. O.U.P, Oxford

    Google Scholar 

  • Skinner G (1964) Marketing and social structure in rural China. J Asian Stud 24:3–43

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stephan GE (1972) International tests of the size-density hypothesis. Am Sociol Rev 37:365–368

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stephan GE (1977) Territorial subdivision: the least-time constraint behind the formation of subnational boundaries. Science 196:523–524

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stewart J, Warntz W (1958) Physics of population distribution. J Reg Sci 1:99–123

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Steindl J (1965) Random processes and the growth of firms. Hafner, New York City

    Google Scholar 

  • Storper M (1995) The resurgence of regional economies, ten years later: the region as a nexus of untraded interdependencies. Eur Urban Reg Stud 2:191–221

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Storper M (2010) Agglomeration, trade, and spatial development: bringing dynamics back in. J Reg Sci 50:313–342

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tinbergen J (1961) The spatial dispersion of production: a hypothesis. Schweiz Z Volkswirtschaft Stat 97:412–419

    Google Scholar 

  • van den Berg L, Drewett R, Klaassen LH, Rossi A, Vijverberg CHT (1982) Urban Europe: a study in growth and decline, vol 1. Pergamon Press, Oxford

    Google Scholar 

  • Vining D, Louw S (1978) A cautionary note on the use of the allometric function to estimate urban populations. Prof Geogr 30:365–370

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Vining D, Yang C-H, Yeh ST (1979) Political subdivision and population density. Science 205:219

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Vining R (1955) A description of certain spatial aspects of an urban system. Econ Dev Cult Change 3:147–195

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Weiss HK (1961) The distribution of urban population and an application to a servicing problem. Oper Res 9:860–874

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

The author is grateful to D. Holden and anonymous referees for suggesting a number of modifications and revisions. Thanks are also due to D. Adams, D. Houston, R. Paddison, N. Sprigings, and K. Swales, who provided valuable comments on earlier versions of the paper.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to John B. Parr.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Parr, J.B. The city and the region as contrasts in spatial organization. Ann Reg Sci 54, 797–817 (2015). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00168-015-0686-9

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00168-015-0686-9

JEL Classification

Navigation