The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics

2018 Edition
| Editors: Macmillan Publishers Ltd

Lindahl, Erik Robert (1891–1960)

  • Otto Steiger
Reference work entry
DOI: https://doi.org/10.1057/978-1-349-95189-5_828

Abstract

Erik Lindahl’s writings between 1919 and 1959 covered four major areas. In public finance his pioneering contribution is today known as the ‘Wicksell–Lindahl paradigm of just taxation’. In dynamic analysis he was first to develop the methods of intertemporal equilibrium and temporary equilibrium. In macroeconomics Lindahl anticipated many of the insights of Keynes’s General Theory, and in his discussion of the concepts of income and capital he laid the foundations of the theory of national accounting. His contributions in the four fields have been acknowledged internationally step by step only since the 1950s – in the third area since the 1970s.

Keywords

Accelerationist hypothesis Aggregate demand and supply Benefit rule Budget balance Capital theory Central banking Davidson, D. Debreu, G. Domar, E. D. European Central Bank European Monetary Union Eurosystem Ex ante and ex post Expectations Financial equilibrium Friedman, M. Frisch, R. A. K. General equilibrium Hansen, B. Hayek, F. A. Hicks, J. R. Imperfect foresight Income International Economic Association Intertemporal equilibrium Kaldor, N. Keynes, J. M. Leijonhufvud, A. Lindahl, E. R. Lundberg, E. F. Monetary equilibrium Monetarist(s) Myrdal, G. Musgrave, R. A. National accounting Normal rate of interest Neumann, J. von Ohlin, B. G. Peacock, A. T. Phelps, E. S. Paradox of saving Perfect foresight Public debts Public expenditure Public finance Public works Quantity theory of money Riksbank Samuelson, P.A. Sequence analysis Stockholm School Stock and flow Swedish Unemployment Committee Taxation Temporary equilibrium Time Total capital Unemployment equilibrium Wicksell–Lindahl paradigm of just taxation Wicksell, J. G. K. 

JEL Classifications

B31 
This is a preview of subscription content, log in to check access.

Bibliography

  1. Åkerman, J.G. 1923–4. Realkapital und Kapitalzins. 2 vols. Stockholm: Centraltryckeriet.Google Scholar
  2. Andvig, J.C. 1991. Ragnar Frisch and the Stockholm School. In Jonung (1991).Google Scholar
  3. Bohm, P. 1987. Lindahl on public finance. In The New Palgrave. A dictionary of economics. Vol. 3, ed. J. Eatwell, M. Milgate and P. Newman. London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
  4. Boianovsky, M., and H.-M. Trautwein. 2006. Price expectations, capital accumulation and employment. Lindahl’s macroeconomics from the 1920s to the 1950s. Cambridge Journal of Economics 30: 881–900.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  5. Carlson, B. 1982. Bagge, Lindahl och nationalinkomsten. Om ‘National Income of Sweden 1861–1930’ [Bagge, Lindahl and the national income. On ‘National Income of Sweden 1861–1930’]. Meddelande från Ekonomiskhistoriska institutionen, Lunds Universitet, No. 27.Google Scholar
  6. Chiodi, G., and K. Velupillai. 1983. A note on Lindahl’s theory of distribution. Kyklos 36: 103–111.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  7. Debreu, G. 1959. Theory of value. An axiomatic analysis of economic equilibrium. New York: Wiley.Google Scholar
  8. Domar, E.D. 1944. The ‘burden of the debt’ and the national income. American Economic Review 34: 798–827.Google Scholar
  9. Fisher, I. 1906. The nature of capital and income. New York: Macmillan. 2nd ed., 1912.Google Scholar
  10. Fregert, K. 1993. Erik Lindahl’s norm for monetary policy. In Swedish economic thought. Explorations and advances, ed. L. Jonung. London: Routledge.Google Scholar
  11. Friedman, M. 1968. The role of monetary policy. American Economic Review 58: 1–17.Google Scholar
  12. Frisch, R. 1933. Propagation problems and impulse problems in economic dynamics. In Economic essays in honour of Gustav Cassel. October 20th, 1933. London: Allen & Unwin.Google Scholar
  13. Grossekettler, H. 2006. Wicksell, Knut: Finanztheoretische Untersuchungen (1896). In Lexikon der ökonomischen Werke. 650 wegweisende Schriften von der Antike bis ins 20. Jahrhundert, ed. D. Herz and V. Weinberger. Düsseldorf: Verlag Wirtschaft und Finanzen.Google Scholar
  14. Hahn, F.H. 1980. Unemployment from a theoretical viewpoint. Economica NS 47: 285–298.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  15. Hammarskjöld, D. 1933a. Utkast till en algebraisk metod för dynamisk prisanalys [Outline of an algebraic method for the dynamic analysis of prices]. Ekonomisk Tidskrift 34 (5–6) (1932, printed 1933): 157–176.Google Scholar
  16. Hammarskjöld, D. 1933b. Konjunkturspridningen. En teoretisk och historisk undersökning [The propagation of business cycles. A theoretical and historical investigation]. Stockholm: Statens offentliga utredningar 1933: 29.Google Scholar
  17. Hammarskjöld, D. 1935. Åtgärder mot arbetslöshet. Arbetslöshetsutredningens betänkande, del II [Measures against unemployment. Report of the Swedish Unemployment Committee, Part II]. Stockholm: Statens offentliga utredningar 1935: 6.Google Scholar
  18. Hammarskjöld, D. 1944. Den svenska diskussionen om penningpolitikens mål. In Studier i ekonomi och historia tillägnade Eli F. Heckscher [Studies in economics and history in honour of Eli F. Heckscher]. Uppsala: Almqvist & Wiksell. Trans. as ‘The Swedish discussion on the aims of monetary policy’. International Economic Papers 5 (1955), 145–154.Google Scholar
  19. Hansen, B. 1955. Finanspolitikens ekonomiska teori. Stockholm: Statens offentliga utredningar, 1955: 25. Quoted from and trans. as The economic theory of fiscal policy. London: Allen & Unwin, 1958.Google Scholar
  20. Hansen, B. 1970. A survey of general equilibrium systems. New York: McGraw-Hill.Google Scholar
  21. Hansen, B. 1979. Review of Erik Lundberg (ed.): Inflation theory and anti-inflation policy (1977). Scandinavian Journal of Economics 81: 119–125.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  22. Hansen, B. 1981. Unemployment, Keynes, and the Stockholm School. History of Political Economy 13: 256–277.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  23. Hansson, B. 1982. The Stockholm School and the development of dynamic method. London: Croom Helm.Google Scholar
  24. Hansson, B. 1987. Stockholm School. In The New Palgrave. A dictionary of economics, ed. J. Eatwell, M. Milgate, and P. Newman, vol. 4. London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
  25. Hansson, B. 1991. The Stockholm School and the development of dynamic method. In The history of Swedish economic thought, ed. B. Sandelin. London: Routledge.Google Scholar
  26. Hayek, F.A. 1928. Das intertemporale Gleichgewichtssystem der Preise und die Bewegungen des ‘Geldwertes’. Weltwirtschaftliches Archiv 28, 33–76. Trans. as ‘Intertemporal price equilibrium and movements in the value of money’, in F.A. von Hayek, Money, capital and fluctuations. Early essays, ed. R. Cloughry. London: Routledge & Kegan Paul, 1984.Google Scholar
  27. Heinsohn, G. and O. Steiger 2003. The European Central Bank and the Eurosystem. An analysis of the missing central monetary institution in the European Monetary Union. ZEI Working Paper No. B03–09. Center for European Integration Studies (ZEI), Universität Bonn. Repr. in The Euro, the eurosystem, and the European economic and monetary union, ed. D. Ehrig and O. Steiger. Hamburg: LIT-Verlag, 2007.Google Scholar
  28. Hicks, J.R. 1939. Value and capital. An inquiry into some fundamental principles of economic theory. Oxford: Clarendon Press. 2nd ed, 1946.Google Scholar
  29. Hicks, J.R. 1973. Recollections and documents. Economica NS 40: 2–11.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  30. Hicks, Sir J. 1985. Methods of dynamic economics. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
  31. Hicks, Sir J. 1991. The Swedish influence on value and capital. In Jonung (1991).Google Scholar
  32. Johansson, A. 1934. Löneutvecklingen och arbetslösheten [The development of wages and unemployment]. Stockholm: Statens offentliga utredningar 1934: 2.Google Scholar
  33. Jonung, L., ed. 1991. The Stockholm School of economics revisited. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
  34. Kaldor, N. 1955. An expenditure tax. London: Allen & Unwin. Quoted from the reprint of 54–78, ‘The concept of income in economic theory’, in Readings in the concept and measurement of income, ed. R.H. Parker and G.C. Harcourt. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1969.Google Scholar
  35. Keynes, J.M. 1934. Letter to Erik Lindahl. Bloomsbury, 8 December. Quoted from the reproduction in Steiger (1971).Google Scholar
  36. Keynes, J.M. 1936. The general theory of employment, interest and money. London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
  37. Landgren, K.-G. 1960. Den ‘nya ekonomien’ i Sverige. J.M. Keynes, B. Ohlin och utvecklingen 1927–39 [The ‘new economics’ in Sweden. J.M. Keynes, B. Ohlin and the development 1927–39]. Stockholm and Uppsala: Almqvist & Wiksell.Google Scholar
  38. Leijonhufvud, A. 1991. Roundtable discussion. In Jonung (1991).Google Scholar
  39. Lindahl, G., and O. Wallmén. 1960. Erik Lindahl. Bibliograf! 1919–1960 [Erik Lindahl. Bibliography 1919–1960]. Ekonomisk Tidskrift 62: 59–74.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  40. Lundberg, E. 1930. Om begreppet ekonomisk jämvikt [On the notion of economic equilibrium]. Ekonomisk Tidskrift 32: 133–160.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  41. Lundberg, E. 1937. Studies in the theory of economic expansion. Stockholm: Norstedt & Söner.Google Scholar
  42. Lundberg, E. 1982. Lindahl, Erik. In Svenskt biografiskt lexikon [The Swedish Dictionary of Bibliography] 23. Stockholm: Norstedts Tryckeri.Google Scholar
  43. Milgate, M. 1982. Capital and employment. A study of Keynes’s economics. London: Academic Press.Google Scholar
  44. Musgrave, R.A. 1959. The theory of public finance. New York: McGraw-Hill.Google Scholar
  45. Musgrave, R.A. and A.T. Peacock. eds. 1958. Classics in the theory of public finance. London: Macmillan. 2nd ed, 1967.Google Scholar
  46. Myrdal, G. 1927. Prisbildningsproblemet och föränderligheten [The problem of price formation and changeability]. Uppsala and Stockholm: Almqvist & Wiksell.Google Scholar
  47. Myrdal, G. 1932. Om penningteoretisk jämvikt. En studie över den ‘normala räntan’ i Wicksells penninglära [On monetary equilibrium. A study on the ‘normal rate of interest’ in Wicksell’s monetary doctrine]. Ekonomisk Tidskrift 33 (1931, printed 1932), 191–302. Revised version trans. as Myrdal (1933).Google Scholar
  48. Myrdal, G. 1933. Der Gleichgewichtsbegriff als Instrument der geldtheoretischen Analyse. In Beiträge zur Geldtheorie, ed. F.A. Hayek. Vienna: J. Springer. 1st rev. version of Myrdal (1932); 2nd rev. version trans. as Myrdal (1939).Google Scholar
  49. Myrdal, G. 1934. Finanspolitikens ekonomiska verkningar [The economic effects of fiscal policy]. Stockholm: Statens offentliga utredingar 1934: 1.Google Scholar
  50. Myrdal, G. 1939. Monetary equilibrium. London: Hodge. Revised version of Myrdal (1933).Google Scholar
  51. Myrman, J. 1991. The monetary economics of the Stockholm School. In Jonung (1991).Google Scholar
  52. Ohlin, B. 1933. Till frågan om penningteoriens uppläggning [On the question of the method and structure in monetary theory]. Ekonomisk Tidskrift 35, 45–81. Quoted from and translated as ‘On the formulation of monetary theory’, History of Political Economy 10 (1978), 353–388.Google Scholar
  53. Ohlin, B. 1934. Penningpolitik, offentliga arbeten, subventioner och tullar som medel mot arbetslöshet. Bidrag till expansionens teori [Monetary policy, public works, subsidies and tariffs as remedies for unemployment. A contribution to the theory of expansion]. Stockholm: Statens offentliga utredningar 1934: 12.Google Scholar
  54. Ohlin, B. 1937. Some notes on the Stockholm theory of savings and investment. I–II. Economic Journal 47: 53–69, 221–240.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  55. Patinkin, D. 1982. Anticipations of the general theory? And other essays on Keynes. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
  56. Petersson, J. 1987. Erik Lindahl och Stockholsskolans dynamiska metod [Erik Lindahl and the dynamic method of the Stockholm School]. Lund: Universitetsförlaget Dialogus.Google Scholar
  57. Phelps, E.S. 1967. Phillips curves, expectations of inflation and optimal unemployment over time. Economica NS 34: 254–281.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  58. Roberts, J. 1987. Lindahl equilibrium. In The New Palgrave. A dictionary of economics, ed. J. Eatwell, M. Milgate, and P. Newman, vol. 3. London/ New York: Macmillan/Stockton Press.Google Scholar
  59. Samuelson, P.A. 1954. The pure theory of public expenditures. Review of Economics and Statistics 36: 387–389.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  60. Siven, C.-H. 1985. The end of the Stockholm School. Scandinavian Journal of Economics 87: 577–593.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  61. Siven, C.-H. 1991. Expectation and plan. The microeconomics of the Stockholm School. In Jonung (1991).Google Scholar
  62. Siven, C.-H. 2002. Analytical foundations of Erik Lindahl’s monetary analysis, 1924–1930. History of Political Economy 34: 111–153.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  63. Siven, C.-H. 2006a. Stockholmsskolan och Keynes [The Stockholm School and Keynes]. Okonomisk Forum 60 (6): 10–17.Google Scholar
  64. Siven, C.-H. 2006b. Monetary equilibrium. History of Political Economy 38: 665–709.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  65. Spethmann, D. and O. Steiger 2005. The four Achilles’ heels of the Eurosystem. Missing central monetary institution, different real rates of interest, nonmarketable securities, and missing lender of last resort. International Journal of Political Economy 34(2), (2004, printed Summer 2005) 46–68.Google Scholar
  66. Steiger, O. 1971. Studien zur Entstehung der Neuen Wirtschaftslehre in Schweden. Eine Anti-Kritik. Berlin: Duncker & Humblot.Google Scholar
  67. Steiger, O. 1978. Prelude to the theory of a monetary economy. Origins and significance of Ohlin’s 1933 approach. History of Political Economy 10: 420–446.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  68. Steiger, O. 1987a. Ex ante and ex post. In The New Palgrave. A dictionary of economics, ed. J. Eatwell, M. Milgate, and P. Newman, vol. 2. London/New York: Macmillan/Stockton Press.Google Scholar
  69. Steiger, O. 1987b. Lindahl, Erik Robert (1891–1960). In The New Palgrave. A dictionary of economics, ed. J. Eatwell, M. Milgate, and P. Newman, vol. 3. London/ New York: Macmillan/Stockton Press.Google Scholar
  70. Steiger, O. 1987c. Monetary equilibrium. In The New Palgrave. A dictionary of economics, ed. J. Eatwell, M. Milgate, and P. Newman, vol. 3. London/ New York: Macmillan/Stockton Press.Google Scholar
  71. Steiger, O. 1991. Comment on Eskil Wadensjö: ‘The Committee of Unemployment and the Stockholm School’. In Jonung (1991).Google Scholar
  72. Steiger, O. 2006a. Lindahl, Erik Robert: Penningpolitikens medel [The means of monetary policy] (1930). In Lexikon der ökonomischen Werke. 650 wegweisende Schriften von der Antike bis ins 20. Jahrhundert, ed. D. Herz and V. Weinberger. Düsseldorf: Verlag Wirtschaft und Finanzen.Google Scholar
  73. Steiger, O. 2006b. Lindahl, Erik Robert: Studies in the theory of money and capital (1939). In Lexikon der ökonomischen Werke. 650 wegweisende Schriften von der Antike bis ins 20. Jahrhundert, ed. D. Herz and V. Weinberger. Düsseldorf: Verlag Wirtschaft und Finanzen.Google Scholar
  74. Steiger, O. 2007. Erik Lindahl och Eurosystemet [Erik Lindahl and the eurosystem]. Ekonomisk Debatt 35 (2): 42–45.Google Scholar
  75. Svennilsson, I. 1938. Ekonomisk planering. Teoretiska studier [Economic planning. Theoretical studies]. Uppsala: Almqvist & Wiksell.Google Scholar
  76. Uhr, C.G. 1960. Economic Doctrines of Knut Wicksell. Berkeley/Los Angeles: University of California Press.Google Scholar
  77. Varian, H.R. 1987. Microeconomics. In The New Palgrave. A dictionary of economics, ed. J. Eatwell, M. Milgate, and P. Newman, vol. 3. London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
  78. Velupillai, K. 1988. Somer Swedish stepping stones to modern macroeconomics. Eastern Economic Journal 14: 87–98.Google Scholar
  79. von Böhm-Bawerk, E.1889. Kapital und Kapitalzins. Zweite Abteilung: Positive Theorie des Kapitales. Jena: G. Fischer; 4th ed, 1921. Trans. as Capital and interest, vols. 2 and 3. South Holland: Libertarian Press, 1959.Google Scholar
  80. von Neumann, J. 1937. Über ein ökonomisches Gleichungssystem und eine Verallgemeinerung des Browerschen Fixpunktsatzes. In Ergebnisse eines mathematischen Kolloquiums 8, ed. K. Menger. Trans. as ‘A model of general equilibrium’, Review of Economic Studies 13 (1945–6), 1–9.Google Scholar
  81. Werin, L. 1991. There were two Stockholm Schools. In Jonung (1991).Google Scholar
  82. Wicksell, K. 1893. Über Wert, Kapital und Rente. Jena: G. Fischer. Trans. as Value, capital and rent, London: Allen & Unwin, 1954.Google Scholar
  83. Wicksell, K. 1896. Finanztheoretische Untersuchungen nebst Darstellung und Kritik des Steuerwesens Schwedens. Jena: G. Fischer, iv–vi, 76–87, 101–59. Trans. as ‘A new principle of just taxation’, in Musgrave and Peacock (1958).Google Scholar
  84. Wicksell, K. 1898. Geldzins und Güterpreise. Eine Studie über die den Tauschwert des Geldes bestimmenden Ursachen. Jena: G. Fischer. Trans. as Interest and prices. A study of the causes regulating the value of money. London: Macmillan, 1936.Google Scholar
  85. Wicksell, K. 1901. Föreläsningar i nationalekonomi. Vol. 1, Stockholm: Fritzes; Lund: Berlingska. Trans. of the 3rd Swedish edn (1928) as Lectures on political economy. volume 1: General theory, London: Routledge & Sons, 1934.Google Scholar
  86. Wicksell, K. 1906. Föreläsningar i nationalekonomi. Vol. 2: Om penningar och kredit. Stockholm: Fritzes; Lund: Berlingska. Quoted from the trans. of the 3rd Swedish edn (1929), Lectures on political economy. volume 2: Money, London: Routledge & Sons, 1935.Google Scholar
  87. Yohe, W.P. 1959. The Wicksellian tradition in Swedish macroeconomic theory. Ann Arbor: University Microfilms.Google Scholar
  88. Yohe, W.P. 1962. A note on some lesser known works of Erik Lindahl. Canadian Journal of Economics and Political Science 28: 274–280.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

Copyright information

© Macmillan Publishers Ltd. 2018

Authors and Affiliations

  • Otto Steiger
    • 1
  1. 1.