The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics

2018 Edition
| Editors: Macmillan Publishers Ltd

Just Price

  • Odd Langholm
Reference work entry
DOI: https://doi.org/10.1057/978-1-349-95189-5_715

Abstract

The idea of the just price is associated primarily with scholastic economics. The schoolmen suggested two ways of estimating the just price, with reference to cost and with reference to the market. The former originated in reply to some of the Church fathers, who claimed that merchants reaped an unjust profit from the toils of others. Alexander of Hales (d. 1240), Peter Olivi (d. 1298), John Duns Scotus (d. 1308) and other schoolmen together compiled a catalogue of cost elements incurred in trade: transport, storage, risk, costly training, professional expertise and diligence, as well as support of the merchant and his family. The cost estimate was confirmed by the schoolmen’s interpretation of the strange formula of exchange appearing in Aristotle’s Nicomachean Ethics. In Book V, on justice, Aristotle presents a cast of characters – a builder, a shoemaker, a farmer, a doctor. ‘As a builder is to a shoemaker, such and such a number of shoes must be to a house’ (1973, 5: ll33a22–3; author’s translation). What could this mean? Albert the Great (d. 1280), the first Latin commentator, and numerous followers, suggested that it might mean equality in proportion to the labour and expenses incurred in the production of the goods offered in exchange. Albert did not merely indicate that economic exchangers deserve cost coverage but that society requires it. If a carpenter (another of Aristotle’s characters) is not paid for a bed as much as it costs him to make it, he will stop making beds – a medieval hint about the law of cost. Scotus says much the same about merchants in general. If no one will be a merchant, the authorities must appoint functionaries and pay them accordingly.

Keywords

Albert the Great Alexander of Hales Aquinas, St. T. Aristotle Duns Scotus, J. Just price Market price Odonis, G. Olivi, P. 

JEL Classifications

B0 
This is a preview of subscription content, log in to check access.

Bibliography

  1. Albert the Great, Saint Albertus Magnus. 1891. Ethica. In Opera Omnia, ed. A. Borgnet, vol. 8. Paris: Louis Vives.Google Scholar
  2. Albert the Great, Saint Albertus Magnus. 1894. Super quartum sententiarum. In Opera Omnia, ed. A. Borgnet, vol. 29. Paris: Louis Vives.Google Scholar
  3. Aquinas, St.T. 1969. Sententia libri ethicorum. In Opera Omnia, ed. R.A. Gauthier, vol. 47. Rome: Leonine Commission.Google Scholar
  4. Aristotle. 1973. Ethica Nicomachea. In Aristoteles Latinus, vol. 26, ed. R.A. Gauthier. Leiden.Google Scholar
  5. Baldwin, J.W. 1959. The medieval theories of the just price. Transactions of the American Philosophical Society, NS 49: 15–92.Google Scholar
  6. de Roover, R. 1958. The concept of the just price. Journal of Economic History 18: 418–434.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  7. Duns Scotus, J. 1894. In Quartum Librum Sententiarum. In Opera Omnia, vol. 18. Paris: Louis Vives.Google Scholar
  8. Langholm, O. 1979. Price and value in the Aristotelian tradition. Oslo: Universitetsforlaget.Google Scholar
  9. Langholm, O. 1992. Economics in the medieval schools. Leiden: Brill.Google Scholar
  10. Langholm, O. 1998. The legacy of scholasticism in economic thought. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

Copyright information

© Macmillan Publishers Ltd. 2018

Authors and Affiliations

  • Odd Langholm
    • 1
  1. 1.