The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics

2018 Edition
| Editors: Macmillan Publishers Ltd

Division of Labour

  • Peter Groenewegen
Reference work entry
DOI: https://doi.org/10.1057/978-1-349-95189-5_675

Abstract

Division of labour has been a very important topic for economic writings from the earliest times, and was treated in great detail by major economists, including especially Adam Smith and Alfred Marshall. This article surveys the development of ‘division of labour’ from its beginnings in the writings of Greek philosophers through the centuries and up to the 21st century. It therefore also reflects on its offshoots: international division of labour, sexual division of labour and its contemporary revival as an essential adjunct to the theory of economic growth, labour productivity, inter-firm cooperation, and its modern limits in coordination and communication costs.

Keywords

Agricultural productivity Aristotle Austrian capital theory Babbage, C. Beccaria, C. B. Bagehot, W. British Association Capital accumulation Capitalism Carl, E. L. Carlyle, T. Clustering Communication and coordination costs Comte, A. Concentration d’Alembert, C. Dexterity Diderot, D. Division of labour Durkheim, E. Economies of scale Engels, F. Engineering Equilibrium analysis Ferguson, A. Firm, theory of Foreign direct investment Hegel, G. W. F. Hodgskin, T. Housework Human capital Hutcheson, F. IbnKhaldun Increasing returns Industrial organization Industrial psychology Industrial revolution Inequality Inter-firm cooperation International division of labour Kaldor, N. Labour productivity Mandeville, B. Manufacturing Manufacturing division of labour Marshall, A. Marshall, M. P. McCulloch, J. R. New classical microeconomics New growth economics Nicholson, J. S. Petty, W. Plato Productivity growth Putting-out system Quesnay, F. Rae, J. (1796–1872) Robbins, L. C. Ruskin, J. Segmented labour markets Senior, N. Sexual division of labour Sidgwick, H. Social division of labour Specialization Spencer, H. Taussig, F. W. Technical change Torrens, R. Tucker, J. Turgot, A. R. J. Ure, A. Verdoorn’s Law Women’s work Xenophon Young, A. A. 

JEL Classifications

B1 
This is a preview of subscription content, log in to check access.

Bibliography

  1. Amsden, A.H. 1985. The division of labour is limited by the rate of growth of the market; The Taiwan machine tool industry in the 1970s. Cambridge Journal of Economics 9: 271–284.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  2. Anonymous. 1701. Considerations on the East-India trade. In A select collection of early English tracts on commerce, ed. J. R. McCulloch. London, 1856; Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1954.Google Scholar
  3. Babbage, C. 1832. On the economy of machinery and manufactures. London. Fourth enlarged edition of 1835; New York: Augustus M. Kelley, 1963.Google Scholar
  4. Becattini, G. 1990. The Marshallian industrial district as a socio-economic notion. In Industrial districts and inter-firm co-operation in Italy, eds. F. Pyke, G. Becattini, and W. Sengenberger. Geneva: International Institute of Labour Studies.Google Scholar
  5. Becattini, G. 2001. The caterpillar and the butterfly. Florence: Felice de Monier.Google Scholar
  6. Beccaria, C. 1771. Elementi di economiapublica. In Opere, ed. S. Romagnoli. Florence: Sansoni, 1958.Google Scholar
  7. Becker, G.S. 1985. Human capital, effort, and the sexual division of labour. Journal of Labour Economics 3 (1): S33–S58.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  8. Becker, G.S., and K.M. Murphy. 1992. The division of labour, coordination costs, and knowledge. Quarterly Journal of Economics 107: 1137–1160.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  9. Bonar, J. 1893. Philosophy and political economy, 3rd ed. London: Allen and Unwin, 1967.Google Scholar
  10. Braverman, H. 1974. Labour and monopoly capital: The degradation of work in the twentieth century. New York: Monthly Review Press.Google Scholar
  11. Camacho, A. 1996. Division of labour, variability, coordination and the theory of the firm and markets. Dordrecht: Kluwer.Google Scholar
  12. Campbell, R. 1747. The London tradesman. London.Google Scholar
  13. Cannan, E. 1929. Review of economic theory. London: P.S. King & Son.Google Scholar
  14. Carlyle, T. 1843. Past and present. London: Chapman & Hall. Another ed. London: G. Routledge & Sons, 1893.Google Scholar
  15. Cigno, A. 1991. Economics of the family. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
  16. Corsi, M. 1984. Ilsistema di fabbrica e la divisione del lavoro, ilpensiero di Charles Babbage. Quaderni di storiadell’economiapolitica 3: 111–123.Google Scholar
  17. Dosi, G. 1988. Sources, procedures, and micro-economic effects of innovation. Journal of Economic Literature 26: 1120–1171.Google Scholar
  18. Engels, F. 1884. Origin of the family, private property and the state. In MarxEngels selected works, vol. 2. Moscow: Progress Publishers.Google Scholar
  19. Fawcett, H. 1863. Manual of political economy. London and Cambridge: Macmillan & Co.Google Scholar
  20. Ferguson, A. 1767. An essay on the history of civil society. Edinburgh.Google Scholar
  21. Fröbel, F., J. Heinrichs, and O. Kreye. 1980. The new international division of labour. Trans. P. Burgess. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
  22. Gershuny, J. 1983. Social innovation and division of labour. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
  23. Gioja, M. 1815. Nuoveprospettodellescienzeeconomiche. Milan: G. Pirotta.Google Scholar
  24. Goodman, E., and J. Pamford, eds. 1989. Small firms and industrial districts in Italy. London: Routledge.Google Scholar
  25. Gouverneur, J. 1978. Contemporary capitalism and marxist economics. Trans. R. le Farnu. Oxford: Robertson, 1983.Google Scholar
  26. Groenewegen, P. 1977. Adam Smith and the division of labour: A bi-centenary estimate. Australian Economic Papers 16: 161–174.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  27. Harris, J. 1757. An essay upon money and coins. Part I. London: G. Hawkins.Google Scholar
  28. Hegel, G.W.F. 1821. Philosophy of right. Trans. T.M. Knox. Oxford: Clarendon Press, 1982.Google Scholar
  29. Hicks, J.R. 1965. Capital and growth. Oxford: Clarendon Press.Google Scholar
  30. Himmelweit, S., and S. Mohun. 1977. Domestic labour and capital. Cambridge Journal of Economics 1: 15–31.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  31. Hobsbawm, E. 2000. The new century. London: Abacus.Google Scholar
  32. Hodgskin, T. 1827. Popular political economy. London/New York: C. Tait/A.M. Kelley, 1966.Google Scholar
  33. Hutcheson, F. 1755. A system of moral philosophy. Glasgow.Google Scholar
  34. Hutchison, T.W. 1988. Before Adam Smith: The emergence of political economy 1662–1776. Oxford: Basil Blackwell.Google Scholar
  35. Kaldor, N. 1966. Causes of the slow rate of economic growth in the United Kingdom. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
  36. Kaldor, N. 1967. Strategic factors in economic development. Ithaca: State School of Industrial and Labour Relations, Cornell University.Google Scholar
  37. Kaldor, N. 1972. The irrelevance of equilibrium economics. Economic Journal 82: 1237–1255.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  38. Kaldor, N. 1975. What is wrong with economic theory? Quarterly Journal of Economics 89: 347–357.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  39. Kames, H.H. 1774. Sketches of the history of man. Edinburgh/London: W. Creech/W. Strahan and T. Cadell.Google Scholar
  40. Lindsay, P. 1733. The interest of Scotland considered. Edinburgh: R. Fleming & Co.Google Scholar
  41. McCulloch, J.R. 1825. Principles of political economy. London: Murray, 1870.Google Scholar
  42. McCulloch, J.R. 1850. Introduction and notes to Adam Smith. In An inquiry into the nature and causes of the wealth of nations, 4th ed. Edinburgh/London: A. & C. Black/Longman.Google Scholar
  43. Mandeville, B. 1729. The fable of the bees. London: A. Roberts.Google Scholar
  44. Marglin, S. 1974. What do bosses do? The origins and functions of hierarchy in capitalist production. Review of Radical Political Economics 6: 60–112.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  45. Marshall, A. 1890. Principles of economics, 8th ed. London: Macmillan & Co., 1920.Google Scholar
  46. Marshall, A. 1919. Industry and trade, 4th ed. London: Macmillan & Co., 1923.Google Scholar
  47. Marshall, A., and M.P. Marshall. 1879. The economics of industry. London: Macmillan and Company.Google Scholar
  48. Marx, K. 1844. Economic and philosophic manuscripts. Moscow: Foreign Languages Publishing House, 1959.Google Scholar
  49. Marx, K. 1867. Capital, vol. 1. Moscow: Foreign Languages Publishing House, 1959.Google Scholar
  50. Marx, K., and F. Engels. 18456. The German ideology. Moscow: Progress Publishers, 1964.Google Scholar
  51. Meek, R.L., and A.S. Skinner. 1973. The development of Adam Smith’s ideas on the division of labour. Economic Journal 83: 1094–1116.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  52. Mill, J.S. 1821. Elements of political economy. In The selected economic writings of James Mill, 3rd ed, ed. D.N. Winch. Edinburgh: Oliver & Boyd for the Scottish Economic Society, 1966.Google Scholar
  53. Mill, J.S. 1848. Principles of political economy. In The collected works of John Stuart Mill, vols. 2 and 3, ed. J.M. Robson. Toronto: Toronto University Press, 1965.Google Scholar
  54. Nicholson, J.S. 1893. Principles of political economy, 2nd ed. London: A. & C. Black.Google Scholar
  55. Perelman, M. 1984. Classical political economy: primitive accumulation and the social division of labour. London: Rowman & Allenheld.Google Scholar
  56. Pernin, J.L. 1993. La cooperation entre firmes: uneapproche par l’économie des conventions. Economie appliqué 46: 105–126.Google Scholar
  57. Petty, W. 1671. Political arithmetick. In Economic writings of Sir William Petty, ed. C.H. Hull. New York: A.M. Kelley, 1963.Google Scholar
  58. Petty, W. 1683. Another essay on political arithmetick concerning the growth of the city of London. In Economic writings of Sir William Petty, ed. C.H. Hull. New York: A.M. Kelley, 1963.Google Scholar
  59. Plato. 380 bc. The republic. Harmondsworth: Penguin Classics, 1955.Google Scholar
  60. Posner, R.A. 1992. Sex and reason. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
  61. Quesnay, F. 1765. Natural right. Extracts. Trans. R.L. Meek. The economics of physiocracy. London: Allen &Unwin, 1962.Google Scholar
  62. Rae, J. 1834. Statement of some new principles on the subject of political economy.New York: A.M. Kelley, 1964.Google Scholar
  63. Robbins, L. 1932. An essay on the nature and significance of economic science. London: Macmillan, 1935.Google Scholar
  64. Romer, P.M. 1987. New theories of economic growth: Growth based on increasing returns due to specialization. American Economic Review 77: 56–62.Google Scholar
  65. Rosenberg, N. 1976. Marx as a student of technology. Monthly Review 28: 56–77. In Inside the black box: Technology and economics, ed. N. Rosenberg. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1982.Google Scholar
  66. Rowthorn, R.E. 1975. A reply to Lord Kaldor’s comment. Economic Journal 85: 897–901.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  67. Ruskin, J. 1851–1853. The stones of Venice.In The complete works of John Ruskin, eds. E.T. Cook and A. Wedderburn. London: George Allen, 1904.Google Scholar
  68. Salz, A. 1934. Specialisation. In International encyclopaedia of the social sciences, vol. 13, ed. E.R.A. Seligman. New York: Macmillan Company, 1948.Google Scholar
  69. Scazzieri, R. 1981. Efficienza, produttività e livelli di attitività. Bologna: Il Mulino.Google Scholar
  70. Schiller, F. 1793. On the aesthetic education of man. Trans. R. Snell. New York: Ungar, 1980.Google Scholar
  71. Schumpeter, J.A. 1954. History of economic analysis. London: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
  72. Senior, N. 1836. An outline of the science of political economy. London: George Allen & Unwin, 1938, 1951.Google Scholar
  73. Sidgwick, H. 1883. Principles of political economy, 2nd ed. London: Macmillan & Co.Google Scholar
  74. Smith, A. 1776. An inquiry into the nature and causes of the wealth of nations, ed. R.H. Campbell and A.S. Skinner. Oxford: Clarendon Press, 1976.Google Scholar
  75. Stewart, D. 1858. In Collected works of Sir Dugald Stewart, ed. Sir William Hamilton. Edinburgh.Google Scholar
  76. Sun, G.Z. 2005. Readings in the economics of the division of labour. Singapore: World Scientific Publishing Company.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  77. Taussig, F.W. 1911. Principles of economics, 3rd ed. New York: Macmillan, 1936.Google Scholar
  78. Thirlwall, A.P. 1983. A plain man’s guide to Kaldor’s growth law. Journal of Post Keynesian Economics 5: 345–358.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  79. Torrens, R. 1808. The economists refuted. Sydney: Department of Economics, University of Sydney, Reprints of Economic Classics, 1984.Google Scholar
  80. Tucker, J. 1755. The elements of commerce and the theory of taxes. London.Google Scholar
  81. Tucker, J. 1774. Four tracts on political and economic subjects, 2nd ed. Gloucester: R. Raikes.Google Scholar
  82. Turgot, A.R.J. 1751. Lettre à Madame de Graffignysur les letters d’un Péruvienne. In Oeuvres de Turgot et documents le concernant, vol. 1, ed. G. Schcllc. Paris: F. Alcan, 1913.Google Scholar
  83. Turgot, A.R.J. 1766. Reflections on the production and distribution of wealth. In The economics of A.R.J. Turgot, ed. P.D. Groenewegen. The Hague: Nijhoff, 1977.Google Scholar
  84. Ure, A. 1835. The philosophy of manufactures. London: C. Knight/Frank Cass, 1967.Google Scholar
  85. Verdoorn, P.J. 1949. Fattori che regolano lo sviluppo della produttività del lavoro. L’industria 1: 45–53.Google Scholar
  86. West, E.G. 1964. Adam Smith’s two views on the division of labour. Economica 31: 23–32.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  87. Yang, X.-K., and Y.-K. Ng. 1993. Specialisation and economic integration: A new classical micro-economic framework. New York: Elsevier Science.Google Scholar
  88. Young, A. 1928. Increasing returns and economic progress. Economic Journal 38: 327–342.Google Scholar

Copyright information

© Macmillan Publishers Ltd. 2018

Authors and Affiliations

  • Peter Groenewegen
    • 1
  1. 1.