The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics

2018 Edition
| Editors: Macmillan Publishers Ltd

Microfoundations

  • Maarten C. W. Janssen
Reference work entry
DOI: https://doi.org/10.1057/978-1-349-95189-5_2707

Abstract

The microfoundations literature has attempted to bridge the gap between microeconomic and macroeconomic models. Many models in this literature have used the theoretical construct of a representative agent. Economy-wide outcomes are thereby presented as if they were the result of the optimizing behaviour of one individual. Emergent properties at the macro level are by construction precluded from the analysis. Other literatures exist where emergent properties are taken to be at the heart of the quest for microfoundations.

Keywords

Aggregation (theory) Austrian economics Behavioural macroeconomics Bounded rationality Classical economics Coordination failure Effective demand Efficiency wages Evolution Expectations Fairness Fixprice models Frictions Game theory General equilibrium Hayek, F. von Imperfect competition Involuntary unemployment IS–LM Keynesianism Labour supply Learning Lucas, R Market clearing Menu cost Methodological individualism Microfoundations Multiplier Neoclassical synthesis New Classical economics New Keynesian macroeconomics Other-regarding preferences Overlapping generations model of general equilibrium Phillips curve Post-Keynesian economics Residential segregation Rational behaviour Rational expectations Real business cycles Reciprocity Representative agents Spontaneous order Sticky prices Strategic complementarities Technology shocks Vienna Circle 

JEL Classification

D0 E0 
This is a preview of subscription content, log in to check access.

Bibliography

  1. Agassi, J. 1960. Methodological individualism. British Journal of Sociology 11: 144–170.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  2. Agassi, J. 1975. Institutional individualism. British Journal of Sociology 26: 144–155.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  3. Arrow, K., and G. Debreu. 1954. Existence of an equilibrium for a competitive economy. Econometrica 22: 265–290.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  4. Barro, R., and H. Grossman. 1971. A general disequilibrium model of income and employment. American Economic Review 61: 82–93.Google Scholar
  5. Benassy, J.-P. 1975. Neo-Keynesian disequilibrium theory in a monetary economy. Review of Economic Studies 42: 502–523.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  6. Bernheim, D. 1984. Rationalizable strategic behavior. Econometrica 52: 1007–1028.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  7. Blanchard, O., and N. Kiyotaki. 1987. Monopolistic competition and the effects on aggregate demand. American Economic Review 77: 647–666.Google Scholar
  8. Bray, M., and N. Savin. 1986. Rational expectations equilibria, learning and model specification. Econometrica 54: 1129–1160.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  9. Brodbeck, M. 1958. Methodological individualisms: Definition and reduction. Philosophy of Science 25: 1–22.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  10. Bryant, J. 1983. A rational expectations Keynes type model. Quarterly Journal of Economics 98: 525–529.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  11. Clower, R. 1965. The Keynesian counterrevolution: A theoretical appraisal. In The theory of interest rates, ed. F. Hahn and F. Brechling. London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
  12. Cooper, R., and A. John. 1988. Coordinating coordination failures in Keynesian models. Quarterly Journal of Economics 103: 441–463.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  13. d’Aspremont, C., R. Dos Santos Ferreira, and L. Gérard-Varet. 1990. On monopolistic competition and involuntary unemployment. Quarterly Journal of Economics 105: 895–919.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  14. Drèze, J. 1975. Existence of an equilibrium with price rigidity and quantity rationing. International Economic Review 16: 301–320.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  15. Fehr, E., and A. Falk. 1999. Wage rigidity in a competitive incomplete contract labour market. Journal of Political Economy 107: 106–134.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  16. Friedman, M. 1968. The role of monetary policy. American Economic Review 58: 1–17.Google Scholar
  17. Frydman, R., and E. Phelps (eds.). 1983. Individual forecasting and aggregate outcomes. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
  18. Geanakoplos, J., and H. Polemarchakis. 1986. Walrasian indeterminacy and Keynesian macroeconomics. Review of Economic Studies 53: 755–779.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  19. Guesnerie, R. 1992. An exploration of the eductive justifications of the rational expectations hypothesis. American Economic Review 82: 1254–1278.Google Scholar
  20. Hart, O. 1982. A model of imperfect competition with Keynesian features. Quarterly Journal of Economics 97: 109–138.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  21. Hayek, F. 1948. Individualism and economic order. Chicago: Chicago University Press.Google Scholar
  22. Hicks, J. 1937. Mr. Keynes and the classics: A suggested interpretation. Econometrica 5: 147–159.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  23. Horwitz, S. 2000. Microfoundations and macroeconomics: An Austrian perspective. London: Routledge.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  24. Janssen, M. 1993. Microfoundations: A critical inquiry. London: Routledge.Google Scholar
  25. Kandori, M., G. Mailath, and R. Rob. 1993. Learning, mutation and long-run equilibria in games. Econometrica 61: 29–56.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  26. Kirman, A. 1989. The intrinsic limits of modern economic theory: The emperor has no clothes. Economic Journal 99(supplement), 126–139.Google Scholar
  27. Kirman, A. 1992. Whom or what does the representative individual represent? Journal of Economic Perspectives 6(2): 117–136.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  28. Kiyotaki, N. 1988. Multiple expectational equilibria under monopolistic competition. Quarterly Journal of Economics 103: 695–713.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  29. Kydland, F., and E. Prescott. 1982. Time to build and aggregate fluctuations. Econometrica 50: 1345–1370.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  30. Leijonhufvud, A. 1968. On Keynesian economics and the economics of Keynes. New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
  31. Lindbeck, A., and D. Snower. 1987. Efficiency wages versus insiders and outsiders. European Economic Review 31: 407–416.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  32. Lucas, R. 1972. Expectations and the neutrality of money. Journal of Economic Theory 4: 103–124.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  33. Lucas, R. 1978. Unemployment policy. American Economic Review 68: 353–357.Google Scholar
  34. Lucas, R. 1987. Models of business cycles. Oxford: Basil Blackwell.Google Scholar
  35. Lucas, R., and L. Rapping. 1969. Real wages, employment and inflation. Journal of Political Economy 77: 721–754.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  36. Mankiw, N. 1985. Small menu cost and large business cycles: A macroeconomic model of monopoly. Quarterly Journal of Economics 100: 529–537.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  37. Muth, J. 1961. Rational expectations and the theory of price movements. Econometrica 29: 315–335.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  38. Nelson, A. 1984. Some issues surrounding the reduction from macroeconomics to microeconomics. Philosophy of Science 51: 573–594.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  39. Pearce, D. 1984. Rationalizable strategic behavior and the problem of perfection. Econometrica 52: 1029–1050.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  40. Phelps, E. (ed.). 1970. Microeconomic foundations of unemployment and inflation theory. London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
  41. Roberts, J. 1987. An equilibrium model with involuntary unemployment at flexible competitive prices and wages. American Economic Review 57: 856–874.Google Scholar
  42. Schelling, T. 1978. Micromotives and macrobehavior. New York: Norton.Google Scholar
  43. Weintraub, E. 1979. Microfoundations. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  44. Yellen, J. 1984. Efficiency-wage models of unemployment. American Economic Review 74: 200–205.Google Scholar
  45. Young, H. 1993. The evolution of conventions. Econometrica 61: 57–84.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

Copyright information

© Macmillan Publishers Ltd. 2018

Authors and Affiliations

  • Maarten C. W. Janssen
    • 1
  1. 1.