The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics

2018 Edition
| Editors: Macmillan Publishers Ltd

Returns to Schooling

  • David Card
Reference work entry
DOI: https://doi.org/10.1057/978-1-349-95189-5_2574

Abstract

The returns to schooling represent the incremental increase in earnings associated with an increase in schooling. Under assumptions first spelled out by Jacob Mincer in 1958, each additional year of schooling will lead to a percentage gain in earnings that is equal to the interest rate. More recent research has treated the return to schooling as a causal parameter that can vary across people, and by the level of education.

Keywords

Ability bias Control functions Degree effects Equalizing differences Human capital earnings function Instrumental variables Mincer, J. Publication bias Returns to schooling Self-selection bias Treatment effect Wage differentials 
This is a preview of subscription content, log in to check access

Bibliography

  1. Altonji, J.J. 1993. The demand for and return to education when education outcomes are uncertain. Journal of Labor Economics 11: 48–83.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  2. Angrist, J.D., and A.B.. Krueger. 1991. Does compulsory school attendance affect schooling and earnings? Quarterly Journal of Economics 106: 979–1014.Google Scholar
  3. Arcidiacono, P. 2004. Ability sorting and the returns to college major. Journal of Econometrics 121: 343–375.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  4. Ashenfelter, O., and A.B.. Krueger. 1994. Estimates of the economic return to schooling from a new sample of twins. American Economic Review 84: 1157–1173.Google Scholar
  5. Ashenfelter, O., and C. Rouse. 1998. Income, schooling, and ability: Evidence from a new sample of twins. Quarterly Journal of Economics 113: 869–895.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  6. Ashenfelter, O., C. Harmon, and H. Oosterbeek. 1999. A review of estimates of the schooling/earnings relationship, with tests for publication bias. Labour Economics 6: 453–470.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  7. Becker, G.S. 1962. Investment in human capital: A theoretical analysis. Journal of Political Economy 70: 9–49.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  8. Becker, G.S. 1964. Human capital: A theoretical and empirical analysis, with special reference to education. New York: Columbia University Press.Google Scholar
  9. Becker, G.S. 1967. Human capital and the personal distribution of income. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.Google Scholar
  10. Blundell, R., Dearden, L. and Sianesi, B. 2004. Evaluating the impact of education on earnings in the U.K.: Models, methods, and results from the NCDS. Working Paper No. 03/20. Institute for Fiscal Studies.Google Scholar
  11. Bonjour, D., L. Cherkas, J. Haskel, D. Hawkes, and T. Spector. 2003. Returns to education: Evidence from UK twins. American Economic Review 93: 1799–1812.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  12. Bound, J., and G. Solon. 1999. Double trouble: On the value of twins-based estimation of the returns to education. Economics of Education Review 18: 169–182.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  13. Butcher, K.F., and A. Case. 1994. The effect of sibling composition on women’s education and earnings. Quarterly Journal of Economics 109: 531–563.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  14. Card, D. 1995a. Earnings, schooling, and ability revisited. In Research in labor economics, ed. S. Polachek, vol. 14. Greenwich: JAI Press.Google Scholar
  15. Card, D. 1995b. Using geographic variation in college proximity to estimate the return to schooling. In Aspects of labour market behaviour: Essays in honour of John Vanderkamp, ed. L.N. Christofides, E.K. Grant, and R. Swidinsky. Toronto: University of Toronto Press.Google Scholar
  16. Card, D. 1999. The causal effect of education on earnings. In Handbook of labor economics, ed. O. Ashenfelter and D. Card, vol. 3A. Amsterdam: North-Holland.Google Scholar
  17. Card, D. 2001. Estimating the return to schooling: Progress on some persistent econometric problems. Econometrica 69: 1127–1160.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  18. Card, D., and T. Lemieux. 2001. Can falling supply explain the rising return to college for younger men? A cohort-based analysis. Quarterly Journal of Economics 116: 705–746.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  19. Chamberlain, G., and Z. Griliches. 1975. Unobservables with a variance–covariance structure: Ability, schooling, and the economic success of brothers. International Economic Review 16: 422–449.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  20. Conneely, K. and Uusitalo, R. 1997. Estimating heterogeneous treatment effects in the Becker schooling model. Discussion Paper, Industrial Relations Section, Princeton University.Google Scholar
  21. Cunha, F. and Heckman, J.J. 2006. Identifying and estimating the distributions of ex post and ex ante returns to schooling: A survey of recent developments. Working Paper, University of Chicago.Google Scholar
  22. Duflo, E. 2001. Schooling and labor market consequences of school construction in Indonesia: Evidence from an unusual policy experiment. American Economic Review 91: 795–813.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  23. Eckstein, Z., and K.I. Wolpin. 1999. Why youths drop out of high school: The impact of preferences, opportunities and abilities. Econometrica 67: 1295–1339.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  24. Fortin, N. 2006. Higher education policies and the college premium: Cross-state evidence from the 1990s. American Economic Review 96: 959–987.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  25. Freeman, R.B. 1976. The over-educated American. New York: Academic Press.Google Scholar
  26. Garen, J. 1984. The returns to schooling: A selectivity bias approach with a continuous choice variable. Econometrica 52: 1199–1218.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  27. Gorseline, D.E. 1932. The effect of schooling upon income. Bloomington: University of Indiana Press.Google Scholar
  28. Gosling, A., and T. Lemieux. 2003. Labor market reforms and changes in wage inequality in the United Kingdom and the United States. In Seeking a premier economy: The economic effects of British economic reforms, 1980–2000, ed. D. Card, R. Blundell, and R.B. Freeman. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
  29. Griliches, Z. 1977. Estimating the returns to schooling: Some econometric problems. Econometrica 45: 1–22.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  30. Harmon, C., and I. Walker. 1995. Estimates of the economic return to schooling for the United Kingdom. American Economic Review 85: 1278–1286.Google Scholar
  31. Harmon, C., I. Walker, and N. Westergaard-Nielson. 2001. Introduction. In Education and earnings in Europe, ed. C. Harmon, I. Walker, and N. Westergaard-Nielson. Aldershot: Edward Elgar.Google Scholar
  32. Harmon, C., I. Walker, and N. Westergaard-Nielson. 2003a. The returns to education: Microeconomics. Journal of Economic Surveys 17: 115–156.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  33. Harmon, C., H. Oosterbeek, and I. Walker. 2003b. The returns to education: Microeconomics. Journal of Economic Surveys 17: 115–156.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  34. Heckman, J.J. 1978. Dummy endogenous variables in a simultaneous equation system. Econometrica 46: 931–959.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  35. Heckman, J.J., and X. Li. 2004. Selection bias, comparative advantage, and heterogeneous returns to education: Evidence from China in 2000. Pacific Economic Review 9: 155–171.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  36. Hungerford, T., and G. Solon. 1987. Sheepskin effects in the return to education. Review of Economics and Statistics 69: 175–177.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  37. Kane, T.J. and Rouse, C.E. 1993. Labor market returns to two- and four-year colleges: Is a credit a credit and do degrees matter? Working Paper No. 4268. Cambridge: NBER.Google Scholar
  38. Katz, L.F., and K.M. Murphy. 1992. Changes in relative wages, 1963–1987: Supply and demand factors. Quarterly Journal of Economics 107: 35–78.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  39. Keane, M.P., and K.I. Wolpin. 1997. The career decisions of young men. Journal of Political Economy 105: 473–521.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  40. Keane, M.P., and K.I. Wolpin. 2001. The effect of parental transfers and borrowing constraints on educational attainment. International Economic Review 42: 1051–1103.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  41. Krueger, A.B.., and M. Lindahl. 2001. Education for growth: Why and for whom? Journal of Economic Literature 39: 1101–1136.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  42. Lemieux, T. 2006. The ‘Mincer equation’ thirty years after Schooling, experience, and earnings. In Jacob Mincer: A pioneer of modern labor economics, ed. S. Grossbard-Shechtman. Heidelberg: Springer.Google Scholar
  43. Meghir, C., and M. Palme. 2005. Educational reform, ability and parental background. American Economic Review 95: 414–424.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  44. Miller, P.W., C. Mulvey, and N. Martin. 1995. What do twins studies reveal about the economic returns to education? A comparison of Australian and US findings. American Economic Review 85: 586–599.Google Scholar
  45. Mincer, J. 1958. Investment in human capital and personal income distribution. Journal of Political Economy 66: 281–302.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  46. Mincer, J. 1974. Schooling, experience, and earnings. New York: NBER (distributed by Columbia University Press).Google Scholar
  47. Mincer, J. 1997. Changes in wage inequality, 1970–1990. Research in Labor Economics 16: 1–18.Google Scholar
  48. Murphy, K.M., and F. Welch. 1990. Empirical age–earnings profiles. Journal of Labor Economics 8: 202–229.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  49. Oreopoulos, P. 2006. Estimating average and local average treatment effects of education when compulsory schooling laws really matter. American Economic Review 96: 152–175.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  50. Park, J.H. 1994. Returns to schooling: A peculiar deviation from linearity. Working Paper No. 335. Industrial Relations Section, Princeton University.Google Scholar
  51. Psacharopoulos, G. 1994. Returns to investment in education: A global update. World Development 22: 1325–1343.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  52. Psacharopoulos, G., and H.A. Patrinos. 2004. Returns to investment in education: A further update. Education Economics 12: 111–134.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  53. Rau-Binder, T. 2006. Semiparametric estimation of microeconometric models with endogenous regressors and sorting. Manuscript, Department of Economics, University of California Berkeley.Google Scholar
  54. Roy, A.D. 1951. Some thoughts on the distribution of earnings. Oxford Economic Papers 3: 135–146.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  55. Solon, G. 1999. Intergenerational mobility in the labor market. In Handbook of labor economics, ed. O.C. Ashenfelter, D. Card, and R. Layard, vol. 3A. Amsterdam: North-Holland.Google Scholar
  56. Walsh, J.R. 1935. Capital concept applied to man. Quarterly Journal of Economics 49: 255–285.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  57. Willis, R. 1986. Wage determination: A survey and reinterpretation of human capital earnings functions. In Handbook of labor economics, ed. O. Ashenfelter and R. Layard, vol. 1. Amsterdam: North-Holland.Google Scholar
  58. Willis, R., and S. Rosen. 1979. Education and self-selection. Journal of Political Economy 87: S7–S36.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

Copyright information

© Macmillan Publishers Ltd. 2018

Authors and Affiliations

  • David Card
    • 1
  1. 1.