The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics

2018 Edition
| Editors: Macmillan Publishers Ltd

Prices of Production

  • G. de Vivo
Reference work entry
DOI: https://doi.org/10.1057/978-1-349-95189-5_1915

Abstract

This expression is used by Marx, mainly in Volume III of Capital, to indicate the exchange values of commodities, when he fully takes into account the inconsistency between the uniformity of the rate of profits and an exchange in proportion to labour embodied. He accordingly tables the famous ‘problem’ of the ‘transformation of the Values of Commodities into Prices of Production’ – i.e., into prices which would include profits at a uniform rate on the whole capital advanced (c + v), and which would therefore differ from relative embodied labours, when commodities differ in the ‘organic composition of capital’ (c/v). The expression ‘prices of production’ (which Marx regards as synonymous with ‘cost-prices’, and with Smith’s ‘natural prices’) starts to be commonly used by Marx only some time after he had actually formulated the ‘transformation problem’, and provided his solution. In Theories of Surplus Value (1862–3), for instance, he would normally still employ its synonym ‘cost-prices’. But ‘prices of production’ is used in the 1893 draft plans for Volume III of Capital (printed in Marx 1862–3, I, pp. 414–16).

This is a preview of subscription content, log in to check access.

Bibliography

  1. De Vivo, G. 1986. Torrens on value and distribution. Contributions to Political Economy 5.Google Scholar
  2. Marx, K. 1862–3. Theories of surplus Value, vols I–III. London: Lawrence & Wishart, 1969–72.Google Scholar
  3. Robbins, L. 1958. Robert Torrens and the evolution of classical economics. London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
  4. Torrens, R. 1815. An essay on the external corn trade; Containing an inquiry into the general principles of that important branch of traffic; an examination of the exceptions to which these principles are liable; and a comparative statement of the effects which restrictions on importation and free intercourse are calculated to produce upon subsistence, agriculture, commerce, and revenue. London: Hatchard.Google Scholar
  5. Torrens, R. 1818. Strictures on Mr Ricardo’s doctrine respecting exchangeable value. Edinburgh Magazine, October. As reprinted in R. Torrens, The economists refuted and other early economic writings, ed. P. Groenewegen. University of Sydney: Reprints of Economic Classics, 1984.Google Scholar

Copyright information

© Macmillan Publishers Ltd. 2018

Authors and Affiliations

  • G. de Vivo
    • 1
  1. 1.