The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics

2018 Edition
| Editors: Macmillan Publishers Ltd

Stagnation

  • Josef Steindl
Reference work entry
DOI: https://doi.org/10.1057/978-1-349-95189-5_1661

Abstract

As far as modern experience is concerned, stagnation is linked to the decade of the 1930s when accumulation in the US practically ceased. The concept of stagnation as the inevitable fate of capitalism, however, is as old as classical economics; only its motivation has not always been the same. The source or inspiration of the idea may be traced to various lines of thought. They are, first, historical: it is known that a number of civilizations stagnated, decayed and perished. Some philosophers, among them Oswald Spengler (1923), believed in a general pattern of creative phase followed by decadence in all civilizations. The knowledge that, in the past, civilizations have decayed must have had an influence on speculation about the future of our society. The second source is biological: in analogy to the organic world, societies are seen to age. Growth is followed by stagnation and finally decay. This underlies the term ‘maturity’ (Hansen 1938), used for a society which has reached the end of its growth phase. There are two different interpretations of the process of ageing. One refers to the gradual exhaustion of natural resources. This covers the ideas of the classics who anticipated a scarcity of land in relation to the growing population as well as the modern ideas about the limits of growth determined by the exhaustion of fossile resources of energy or of the healthy environment. The alternative interpretation of ageing is social. With the evolution of capitalism it is seen to pass from its competitive to its monopolistic (and imperialistic) phase. The pioneers of this outlook have been Hilferding (1910) and Luxemburg (1913) with their affirmation of the existence of a new phase of capitalism, characterized by monopoly elements and by imperialism. The elaboration of a theory of stagnation on this basis has been possible only after Kalecki and Keynes had provided the analytical tools in the form of a consistent theory of effective demand.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in to check access.

Bibliography

  1. Baran, P.A. 1957. The political economy of growth. New York: Monthly Review Press.Google Scholar
  2. Baran, P.A., and P.M. Sweezy. 1966. Monopoly capital. New York: Monthly Review Press.Google Scholar
  3. Freeman, C., J. Clark, and L. Soete. 1982. Unemployment and technological innovation: A study of long waves and economic development. London: Frances Pinter.Google Scholar
  4. Grossmann, H. 1929. Das Akkumulations- und Zusammerbruchsgesetz des kapitalistischen Systems. Leipzig: C.L. Hirschfeld.Google Scholar
  5. Hansen, A.H. 1938. Full recovery or stagnation? New York: W.W. Norton.Google Scholar
  6. Hansen, A.H. 1941. Fiscal policy and business cycles. New York: W.W. Norton.Google Scholar
  7. Hilferding, R. 1910. Das Finanzkapital. Vienna: Ignaz Brand & Co. Trans. as Finance Capital, ed. T. Bottomore. London: Routledge, 1981.Google Scholar
  8. Kalecki, M. 1954. Theory of economic dynamics. London: Allen & Unwin; New York: Monthly Review Press, 1965.Google Scholar
  9. Lenin, V.I. 1917. Imperialism: The newest stage of capitalism, 1933. New York: International Publishers Company.Google Scholar
  10. Luxemburg, R. 1913. Die Akkumulation des Kapitals. Berlin: P. Singer. Trans. by A. Schwarzschild as The Accumulation of Capital. London: Routledge & Kegan Paul, 1951.Google Scholar
  11. Meadows, D.H., et al. 1972. The limits to growth. New York: Universe.Google Scholar
  12. Piore, M.J., and C.H.F. Sabel. 1984. The second industrial divide: Possibilities for prosperity. New York: Basic Books.Google Scholar
  13. Sabel, C.H.F. 1982. Work and politics: The division of labour in industry. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  14. Schumpeter, J.A. 1939. Business cycles. New York: McGraw-Hill.Google Scholar
  15. Spengler, O. 1923. Der Untergang des Abendlandes. Munich: C.H. Beck. Trans. as The Decline of the West, 2 vols. New York: Knopf, 1926–8.Google Scholar
  16. Steindl, J. 1952. Maturity and stagnation in american capitalism. Oxford: Basil Blackwell. Reprinted New York: Monthly Review Press, 1976.Google Scholar
  17. Steindl, J. 1979. Stagnation theory and stagnation policy. Cambridge Journal of Economics 3(1): 1–14.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  18. Steindl, J. 1985. Distribution and growth. Political Economy Studies in the Surplus Approach 1(1): 1–14.Google Scholar
  19. Sweezy, P.M. 1942. The theory of capitalist development, 1956. New York: Monthly Review Press.Google Scholar
  20. Sylos-Labini, P. 1956. Oligopolio e progresso tecnico. Milan: Giuffrè. Trans. as Oligopoly and Technical Progress. Cambridge, Mass: Harvard University Press, 1962.Google Scholar

Copyright information

© Macmillan Publishers Ltd. 2018

Authors and Affiliations

  • Josef Steindl
    • 1
  1. 1.