Skip to main content

Stagnation

  • Reference work entry
  • First Online:
The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics
  • 36 Accesses

Abstract

As far as modern experience is concerned, stagnation is linked to the decade of the 1930s when accumulation in the US practically ceased. The concept of stagnation as the inevitable fate of capitalism, however, is as old as classical economics; only its motivation has not always been the same. The source or inspiration of the idea may be traced to various lines of thought. They are, first, historical: it is known that a number of civilizations stagnated, decayed and perished. Some philosophers, among them Oswald Spengler (1923), believed in a general pattern of creative phase followed by decadence in all civilizations. The knowledge that, in the past, civilizations have decayed must have had an influence on speculation about the future of our society. The second source is biological: in analogy to the organic world, societies are seen to age. Growth is followed by stagnation and finally decay. This underlies the term ‘maturity’ (Hansen 1938), used for a society which has reached the end of its growth phase. There are two different interpretations of the process of ageing. One refers to the gradual exhaustion of natural resources. This covers the ideas of the classics who anticipated a scarcity of land in relation to the growing population as well as the modern ideas about the limits of growth determined by the exhaustion of fossile resources of energy or of the healthy environment. The alternative interpretation of ageing is social. With the evolution of capitalism it is seen to pass from its competitive to its monopolistic (and imperialistic) phase. The pioneers of this outlook have been Hilferding (1910) and Luxemburg (1913) with their affirmation of the existence of a new phase of capitalism, characterized by monopoly elements and by imperialism. The elaboration of a theory of stagnation on this basis has been possible only after Kalecki and Keynes had provided the analytical tools in the form of a consistent theory of effective demand.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 6,499.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Hardcover Book
USD 8,499.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Bibliography

  • Baran, P.A. 1957. The political economy of growth. New York: Monthly Review Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Baran, P.A., and P.M. Sweezy. 1966. Monopoly capital. New York: Monthly Review Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Freeman, C., J. Clark, and L. Soete. 1982. Unemployment and technological innovation: A study of long waves and economic development. London: Frances Pinter.

    Google Scholar 

  • Grossmann, H. 1929. Das Akkumulations- und Zusammerbruchsgesetz des kapitalistischen Systems. Leipzig: C.L. Hirschfeld.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hansen, A.H. 1938. Full recovery or stagnation? New York: W.W. Norton.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hansen, A.H. 1941. Fiscal policy and business cycles. New York: W.W. Norton.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hilferding, R. 1910. Das Finanzkapital. Vienna: Ignaz Brand & Co. Trans. as Finance Capital, ed. T. Bottomore. London: Routledge, 1981.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kalecki, M. 1954. Theory of economic dynamics. London: Allen & Unwin; New York: Monthly Review Press, 1965.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lenin, V.I. 1917. Imperialism: The newest stage of capitalism, 1933. New York: International Publishers Company.

    Google Scholar 

  • Luxemburg, R. 1913. Die Akkumulation des Kapitals. Berlin: P. Singer. Trans. by A. Schwarzschild as The Accumulation of Capital. London: Routledge & Kegan Paul, 1951.

    Google Scholar 

  • Meadows, D.H., et al. 1972. The limits to growth. New York: Universe.

    Google Scholar 

  • Piore, M.J., and C.H.F. Sabel. 1984. The second industrial divide: Possibilities for prosperity. New York: Basic Books.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sabel, C.H.F. 1982. Work and politics: The division of labour in industry. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Schumpeter, J.A. 1939. Business cycles. New York: McGraw-Hill.

    Google Scholar 

  • Spengler, O. 1923. Der Untergang des Abendlandes. Munich: C.H. Beck. Trans. as The Decline of the West, 2 vols. New York: Knopf, 1926–8.

    Google Scholar 

  • Steindl, J. 1952. Maturity and stagnation in american capitalism. Oxford: Basil Blackwell. Reprinted New York: Monthly Review Press, 1976.

    Google Scholar 

  • Steindl, J. 1979. Stagnation theory and stagnation policy. Cambridge Journal of Economics 3(1): 1–14.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Steindl, J. 1985. Distribution and growth. Political Economy Studies in the Surplus Approach 1(1): 1–14.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sweezy, P.M. 1942. The theory of capitalist development, 1956. New York: Monthly Review Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sylos-Labini, P. 1956. Oligopolio e progresso tecnico. Milan: Giuffrè. Trans. as Oligopoly and Technical Progress. Cambridge, Mass: Harvard University Press, 1962.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Editor information

Copyright information

© 2018 Macmillan Publishers Ltd.

About this entry

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this entry

Steindl, J. (2018). Stagnation. In: The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics. Palgrave Macmillan, London. https://doi.org/10.1057/978-1-349-95189-5_1661

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics