Skip to main content

Hold-Up

  • Reference work entry
  • First Online:
The Palgrave Encyclopedia of Strategic Management

Abstract

A hold-up occurs when one transactor takes advantage of another’s lack of comparably valued alternatives to insist on more favourable terms of trade. Opportunities for hold-ups commonly arise where transactions require relationship-specific investments. The potential for a hold-up reduces the efficiency of exchange by causing underinvestment or because efforts to appropriate and protect quasi-rents through bargaining and other rent seeking activities dissipate gains from trade. Avoiding or reducing the potential for hold-up is an often-cited motive for contracting and vertical integration.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 1,099.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Hardcover Book
USD 1,699.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

References

  • Casadesus-Masanell, R., and D.F. Spulber. 2000. The fable of fisher body. Journal of Law and Economics 43: 67–104.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Coase, R.H. 2000. The acquisition of fisher body by general motors. Journal of Law and Economics 43: 5–31.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Coase, R.H. 2006. The conduct of economics: The example of fisher body and general motors. Journal of Economics and Management Strategy 15: 255–278.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cutler, D.M., and L.H. Summers. 1988. The costs of conflict resolution and financial distress: Evidence from the Texaco–Penzoillitigation. RAND Journal of Economics 19: 157–172.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Freeland, R.F. 2000. Creating hold-up through vertical integration: Fisher body revisited. Journal of Law and Economics 43: 33–66.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gallick, E.C. 1996. Exclusive dealing and vertical integration: The efficiency of contracts in the tuna industry. In Case studies in contracting and organization, ed. S.E. Masten. New York: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gibbons, R. 2005. Four formal(izable) theories of the firm? Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 58: 200–245.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Goetz, C.J., and R.E. Scott. 1983. The mitigation principle: Toward a general theory of contractual obligation. Virginia Law Review 69: 967–1024.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Goldberg, V.P. 1976. Regulation and administered contracts. Bell Journal of Economics 7: 426–448.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Goldberg, V.P. 1985. Price adjustment in long-term contracts. Wisconsin Law Review 527–543.

    Google Scholar 

  • Grossman, S., and O. Hart. 1986. The costs and benefits of ownership: A theory of lateral and vertical integration. Journal of Political Economy 94: 691–719.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hart, O., and J. Moore. 1990. Property rights and the nature of the firm. Journal of Political Economy 98: 1119–1158.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Joskow, P. 1985. Vertical integration and long-term contracts: The case of coal burning electric generating plants. Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization 1: 33–80.

    Google Scholar 

  • Joskow, P. 1987. Contract duration and relationship-specific investments: Empirical evidence from coal markets. American Economic Review 77: 168–185.

    Google Scholar 

  • Klein, B. 1988. Vertical integration as organizational ownership: The fisher body–general Motors relationship revisited. Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization 4: 199–213.

    Google Scholar 

  • Klein, B. 1996. Why hold-ups occur: The self-enforcing range of contractual relationships. Economic Inquiry 34: 444–463.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Klein, B. 2000. Fisher–general motors and the nature of the firm. Journal of Law and Economics 43: 105–141.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Klein, B. 2007. The economic lessons of fisher body–general motors. International Journal of the Economics of Business 14: 1–36.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Klein, B., R. Crawford, and A. Alchian. 1978. Vertical integration, appropriable rents and the competitive contracting process. Journal of Law and Economics 21: 297–326.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Koss, P. 1999. Self-enforcing transactions: Reciprocal exposure in fisheries. Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization 15: 737–749.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lafontaine, F., and M. Slade. 2007. Vertical integration and firm boundaries: The evidence. Journal of Economic Literature 45: 629–685.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Masten, S.E. 1988. A legal basis for the firm. Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization 4: 181–198.

    Google Scholar 

  • Masten, S.E. 2000. Transaction-cost economics and the organization of agricultural transactions. In Advances in applied microeconomics: Industrial organization, ed. Baye Michael. New York: Elsevier Science.

    Google Scholar 

  • Masten, S.E., J.W. Meehan, and E.A. Snyder. 1991. The costs of organization. Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization 7: 1–25.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Monteverde, K., and D.J. Teece. 1982a. Switching costs and vertical integration in the automobile industry. Bell Journal of Economics 13: 206–213.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Monteverde, K., and D.J. Teece. 1982b. Appropriable rents and quasi-vertical integration. Journal of Law and Economics 25: 321–328.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pirrong, S.C. 1993. Contracting practices in bulk shipping markets: A transaction cost perspective. Journal of Law and Economics 36: 937–976.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shelanski, H., and P. Klein. 1995. Empirical research in transaction-cost economics: A review and assessment. Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization 11: 335–361.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stremitzer, A. 2010. Standard breach remedies, quality thresholds, and cooperative investments. Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization. doi:10.1093/jleo/ewq007.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Whinston, M. 2003. On the transaction cost determinants of vertical integration. Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization 19: 1–23.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wickelgren, A.L. 2007. The limitations of buyer-option contracts in solving the hold-up problem. Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization 23: 127–140.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Williamson, O.E. 1971. The vertical integration of production: Market failure considerations. American Economic Review 61: 112–123.

    Google Scholar 

  • Williamson, O.E. 1975. Markets and hierarchies: Analysis and antitrust implications. New York: Free Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Williamson, O.E. 1985. The economic institutions of capitalism. New York: Free Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Williamson, O.E. 1991. Comparative economic organization: The analysis of discrete structural alternatives. Administrative Science Quarterly 36: 269–296.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Scott E. Masten .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Copyright information

© 2018 Macmillan Publishers Ltd., part of Springer Nature

About this entry

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this entry

Masten, S.E. (2018). Hold-Up. In: Augier, M., Teece, D.J. (eds) The Palgrave Encyclopedia of Strategic Management. Palgrave Macmillan, London. https://doi.org/10.1057/978-1-137-00772-8_579

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics