Skip to main content

Game Theory as a Foundation of Evolutionary Psychology

  • Living reference work entry
  • First Online:
Encyclopedia of Evolutionary Psychological Science

Synonyms

Behavioral game theory; Decision theory; Evolutionary game theory; Experimental economics; Mathematical biology

Definition

Game theory is the mathematical analysis of interdependent systems composed of fitness- or utility-maximizing “actors” (e.g., humans, animals, genes, or viruses) whose success depends on the strategies of others.

Introduction

Game theory is a useful tool for understanding interdependent systems. It is a mathematical description of how individuals should behave in contexts in which the outcomes of their actions depend on the behavior of other individuals. Game theory has been applied to topics as varied as climate change negotiations (Helm et al. 2012), the evolution of cooperation (Nowak 2006b), and viral population dynamics (Turner and Chao 1999). Game theory makes sense of different “strategies” and “payoffs” by using the mathematical logic of each individual agent’s perspective. Game theory was first used to model rational, conscious actions by humans...

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Institutional subscriptions

References

  • Allais, M. (1953). Fondements d’une théorie positive des choix comportant un risque et critique des postulats et axiomes de l’école américaine (Vol. 144). Paris: Imprimerie Nationale.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bednar, J., & Page, S. (2007). Can game (s) theory explain culture? The emergence of cultural behavior within multiple games. Rationality and Society, 19(1), 65–97.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bohl, K., Hummert, S., Werner, S., Basanta, D., Deutsch, A., Schuster, S., et al. (2014). Evolutionary game theory: Molecules as players. Molecular BioSystems, 10(12), 3066–3074.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bolton, G. E., Katok, E., & Zwick, R. (1998). Dictator game giving: Rules of fairness versus acts of kindness. International Journal of Game Theory, 27(2), 269–299.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Burt, A., & Trivers, R. (2006). Genes in conflict: The biology of selfish genetic elements. Cambridge: Belknap Press of Harvard University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Buss, L. W. (1999). Slime molds, ascidians, and the utility of evolutionary theory. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences of the United States of America, 96(16), 8801–8803. https://doi.org/10.1073/pnas.96.16.8801.

    Article  PubMed  PubMed Central  Google Scholar 

  • Conroy-Beam, D., Goetz, C. D., & Buss, D. M. (2015). Chapter one-why do humans form long-term Mateships? An evolutionary game-theoretic model. Advances in Experimental Social Psychology, 51, 1–39.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dall, S. R. X., Houston, A. I., & McNamara, J. M. (2004). The behavioural ecology of personality: Consistent individual differences from an adaptive perspective. Ecology Letters, 7(8), 734–739.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fisher, R. A. (1958). The general theory of natural selection. New York: Dover.

    Google Scholar 

  • Foster, J. A., & Neufeld, K.-A. M. (2013). Gut–brain axis: How the microbiome influences anxiety and depression. Trends in Neurosciences, 36(5), 305–312.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gintis, H. (2009). The bounds of reason: Game theory and the unification of the behavioral sciences. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Haig, D. (1999). What is a marmoset? American Journal of Primatology, 49(4), 285–296.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Haig, D. (2002). Genomic imprinting and kinship. New Brunswick: Rutgers University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Haig, D. (2011). Genomic imprinting and the evolutionary psychology of human kinship. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences, 108(Supplement 2), 10878–10885.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Haig, D. (2012). The strategic gene. Biology and Philosophy, 27(4), 461–479. https://doi.org/10.1007/s10539-012-9315-5.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hamilton, W. J. (1967). Extraordinary sex ratios. Science, 156, 477–488.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Helm, D., Hepburn, C., & Ruta, G. (2012). Trade, climate change, and the political game theory of border carbon adjustments. Oxford Review of Economic Policy, 28(2), 368–394.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hutchinson, G. E. (1965). The ecological theater and the evolutionary play. New Haven: Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kramer, P., & Bressan, P. (2015). Humans as superorganisms how microbes, viruses, imprinted genes, and other selfish entities shape our behavior. Perspectives on Psychological Science, 10(4), 464–481.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Küpper, C., Stocks, M., Risse, J. E., dos Remedios, N., Farrell, L. L., McRae, S. B., et al. (2015). A supergene determines highly divergent male reproductive morphs in the ruff. Nature Genetics, 48(1), 79–83.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Maynard Smith, J. (1982). Evolution and the theory of games. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Maynard Smith, J., & Price, G. R. (1973). Lhe logic of animal conflict. Nature, 246, 15.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McNamara, J. M., Barta, Z., Fromhage, L., & Houston, A. I. (2008). The coevolution of choosiness and cooperation. Nature, 451(7175), 189–192.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nash, J. (1951). Non-cooperative games. Annals of Mathematics, 54(2), 286–295.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nettle, D. (2006). The evolution of personality variation in humans and other animals. American Psychologist, 61(6), 622.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nowak, M. A. (2006a). Evolutionary dynamics: Exploring the building blocks of life. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nowak, M. A. (2006b). Five rules for the evolution of cooperation. Science, 314(5805), 1560–1563.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pareto, V. (1896–97). Cours D’Economie Politique. In Bousquet, G. H. and G. Busino eds., Oevres Completes de Vilfredo Pareto, 1. Geneva: Librairie Droz, 1964.

    Google Scholar 

  • Perez, J. D., Rubinstein, N. D., & Dulac, C. (2016). New perspectives on genomic imprinting, an essential and multifaceted mode of epigenetic control in the developing and adult brain. Annual Review of Neuroscience, 39, 347–384.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ridley, M. (1994). The red queen: Sex and the evolution of human nature. London: Penguin.

    Google Scholar 

  • Russell, B. (1992). The basic writings of Bertrand Russell, 1903–1959. Psychology Press, London: Routledge Classics.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sigmund, K. (1993). Games of life: Explorations in ecology, evolution, and behaviour. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Traulsen, A., & Reed, F. A. (2012). From genes to games: Cooperation and cyclic dominance in meiotic drive. Journal of Theoretical Biology, 299, 120–125.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Turner, P. E., & Chao, L. (1999). Prisoner’s dilemma in an RNA virus. Nature, 398(6726), 441–443.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Vincent, T. L., & Brown, J. S. (2005). Evolutionary game theory, natural selection, and Darwinian dynamics. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • von Neumann, J. (1928). Zur Theorie der Gesellschaftsspiele. Mathematische annalen, 100(1), 295–320.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • von Neumann, J., & Morgenstern, O. (1944). Theory of games and economic behavior (Vol. 60). Princeton: Princeton university press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Webster, J. P., Kaushik, M., Bristow, G. C., & McConkey, G. A. (2013). Toxoplasma gondii infection, from predation to schizophrenia: Can animal behaviour help us understand human behaviour? Journal of Experimental Biology, 216(1), 99–112.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wilson, E. O. (1975). Sociobiology: The new synthesis. Cambridge, MA: Belknap Press of Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wilson, D. S. (1998). Game theory and human behavior. In L. A. Dugatkin & H. K. Reeve (Eds.), Game theory and animal behavior (pp. 261–282). New York: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Dakota E. McCoy .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Section Editor information

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2018 Springer International Publishing AG, part of Springer Nature

About this entry

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this entry

McCoy, D.E. (2018). Game Theory as a Foundation of Evolutionary Psychology. In: Shackelford, T., Weekes-Shackelford, V. (eds) Encyclopedia of Evolutionary Psychological Science. Springer, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-16999-6_3577-1

Download citation

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-16999-6_3577-1

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Publisher Name: Springer, Cham

  • Print ISBN: 978-3-319-16999-6

  • Online ISBN: 978-3-319-16999-6

  • eBook Packages: Springer Reference Behavioral Science and PsychologyReference Module Humanities and Social SciencesReference Module Business, Economics and Social Sciences

Publish with us

Policies and ethics