Encyclopedia of the Sciences of Learning

2012 Edition
| Editors: Norbert M. Seel

Imitation and Social Learning

  • Karl H. Schlag
Reference work entry
DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/978-1-4419-1428-6_1452

Synonyms

Definition

Imitation is the act of copying the behavior of someone observed. It is the most common learning rule and, as behavior, can be observed among animals (Galef and Laland 2005) as well as among humans (Apesteguia et al. 2007; Horner and Whiten 2005). Not to imitate means to experiment or innovate, to try something new instead of choosing one of the behaviors that has been observed.

To learn means to acquire knowledge or understanding. Social learning is about learning within a social group as opposed to individual learning where only the learning of a single person is considered. Concern is for how individuals within the group learn, and hence how the whole group learns. Social learning does not require that individuals within the group actively change their understanding about the environment. To exhibit learning as a group, it is already sufficient that more within the group adapt a superior action.

Theoretical Background

I...

This is a preview of subscription content, log in to check access.

References

  1. Alos-Ferrer, C., & Schlag, K. H. (2009). Imitation and social learning. In P. Anand, P. Pattanaik, & C. Puppe (Eds.), The handbook of rational and social choice. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
  2. Apesteguia, J., Huck, S., & Oechssler, J. (2007). Imitation – theory and experimental evidence. Journal of Economic Theory, 136, 217–235.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  3. Bjornerstedt, J., & Schlag, K. H. (1996). On the evolution of imitative behavior. Discussion Paper No. B.378, Sonderforschungsbereich 303, University of Bonn.Google Scholar
  4. Galef, B. G., Jr., & Laland, K. N. (2005). Social learning in animals: Empirical studies and theoretical models. Bioscience, 55(6), 489–499.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  5. Hofbauer, J., & Schlag, K. H. (2000). Sophisticated imitation in cyclic games. Journal of Evolutionary Economics, 10(5), 523–543.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  6. Horner, V., & Whiten, A. (2005). Causal knowledge and imitation/emulation switching in chimpanzees (Pan troglodytes) and children (Homo sapiens). Animal Cognition, 8, 164–181.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  7. Kendal, J. R., Rendell, L., Pike, T. W., & Laland, K. N. (2009). Nine-spined sticklebacks deploy a hill-climbing social learning strategy. Behavioral Ecology, 20(2), 238–244.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  8. Pike, T. W., Kendal, J. R., Rendell, L. E., & Laland, K. N. (2010). Learning by proportional observation in a species of fish. Behavioral Ecology, 21(3), 570–575.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  9. Schlag, K. H. (1996). Imitate best vs. Imitate best average. Mimeo, University of Bonn. http://homepage.univie.ac.at/karl.schlag/research/imitation/IDIO9.pdf.
  10. Schlag, K. H. (1998). Why imitate, and if so, how? A boundedly rational approach to multi-armed bandits. Journal of Economic Theory, 78(1), 130–156.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  11. Simon, H. A. (1955). A behavioral model of rational choice. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 69(1), 99–118.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  12. Weibull, J. (1995). Evolutionary game theory. Cambridge: MIT Press.Google Scholar

Copyright information

© Springer Science+Business Media, LLC 2012

Authors and Affiliations

  1. 1.Department of EconomicsUniversity of ViennaViennaAustria