Advertisement

Resource Economics

  • Ngo Van Long
Reference work entry

Abstract

This chapter provides a selective survey of dynamic game models of exploitation of natural resources. It covers both renewable resources and exhaustible resources. In relation to earlier surveys (Long, A survey of dynamic games in economics, World Scientific, Singapore, 2010; Long, Dyn Games Appl 1(1):115–148, 2011), the present work includes many references to new developments that appeared after January 2011 and additional suggestions for future research. Moreover, there is a greater emphasis on intuitive explanation.

Keywords

Exhaustible resources Renewable resources Overexploitation Market structure Dynamic games 

References

  1. Alvarez-Cuadrado F, Long NV (2011) Relative consumption and renewable resource extraction under alternative property rights regimes. Resour Energy Econ 33(4):1028–1053Google Scholar
  2. Amir R (1987) Games of resource extraction: existence of Nash equilibrium. Cowles Foundation Discussion Paper No. 825Google Scholar
  3. Amir R (1989) A Lattice-theoretic approach to a class of dynamic games. Comput Math Appl 17:1345–1349Google Scholar
  4. Bala V, Long NV (2005) International trade and cultural diversity with preference selection. Eur J Polit Econ 21(1):143–162Google Scholar
  5. Basar T, Olsder GJ (1982) Dynamic non-cooperative game theory. Academic, LondonGoogle Scholar
  6. Behringer S, Upmann T (2014) Optimal harvesting of a spatial renewable resource. J Econ Dyn Control 42:105–120Google Scholar
  7. Breton M, Sbragia L, Zaccour G (2010) A dynamic model of international environmental agreements. Environ Resour Econ 45:25–48Google Scholar
  8. Benchekroun H (2008) Comparative dynamics in a productive asset oligopoly. J Econ Theory 138:237–261Google Scholar
  9. Benchekroun H, Halsema A, Withagen C (2009) On non-renewable resource oligopolies: the asymmetric case. J Econ Dyn Control 33(11):1867–1879Google Scholar
  10. Benchekroun H, Halsema A, Withagen C (2010) When additional resource stocks reduce welfare. J Environ Econ Manag 59(1):109–114Google Scholar
  11. Benchekroun H, Gaudet G, Lohoues H (2014) Some effects of asymmetries in a common pool natural resource oligopoly. Strateg Behav Environ 3:213–235Google Scholar
  12. Benchekroun H, Gaudet G (2015) On the effects of mergers on equilibrium outcomes in a common property renewable asset oligopoly. J Econ Dyn Control 52:209–223Google Scholar
  13. Benchekroun H, Long NV (2006) The curse of windfall gains in a non-renewable resource oligopoly. Aust Econ Pap 45(2):99–105Google Scholar
  14. Benchekroun H, Long NV (2016) Status concern and the exploitation of common pool renewable resources. Ecol Econ 125(C):70–82Google Scholar
  15. Benchekroun H, Withagen C (2012) On price-taking behavior in a non-renewable resource Cartel-Fringe game. Games Econ Bahav 76(2):355–374Google Scholar
  16. Benhabib J, Radner R (1992) The joint exploitation of a productive asset: a game-theoretic approach. Econ Theory 2:155–190Google Scholar
  17. Bergstrom T (1982) On capturing oil rents with a national excise tax. Am Econ Rev 72(1):194–201Google Scholar
  18. Bohn H, Deacon RT (2000) Ownership risk, investment, and the use of natural resources. Am Econ Rev 90(3):526–549Google Scholar
  19. Bolle F (1980) The efficient use of a non-renewable common-pool resource is possible but unlikely. Zeitschrift für Nationalökonomie 40:391–397Google Scholar
  20. Brander J, Djajic S (1983) Rent-extracting tariffs and the management of exhaustible resources. Canad J Econ 16:288–298Google Scholar
  21. Breton M, Keoula MY (2012) Farsightedness in a coalitional great fish war. Environ Resour Econ 51(2):297–315Google Scholar
  22. Breton M, Sbragia L, Zaccour G (2010) A dynamic model of international environmental agreements. Environ Resour Econ 45:25–48Google Scholar
  23. Cabo F, Tidball M (2016) Promotion of cooperation when benefits come in the future: a water transfer case. Resour Energy Econ (to appear)Google Scholar
  24. Cabo F, Erdlenbruch K, Tidball M (2014) Dynamic management of water transfer between two interconnected river basins. Resour Energy Econ 37:17–38Google Scholar
  25. Cave J (1987) Long-term competition in a dynamic game: the Cold Fish War. Rand J Econ 18: 596–610Google Scholar
  26. Chiarella C, Kemp MC, Long NV, Okuguchi K (1984) On the economics of international fisheries. Int Econ Rev 25 (1):85–92Google Scholar
  27. Chichilnisky G (1996) An axiomatic approach to sustainable development. Soc Choice Welf 13:231–257Google Scholar
  28. Chou S, Long NV (2009) Optimal tariffs on exhaustible resources in the presence of Cartel behavior. Asia-Pac J Account Econ 16(3):239–254Google Scholar
  29. Chwe M (1994) Farsighted coalitional stability. J Econ Theory 63:299–325Google Scholar
  30. Clark CW (1990) Mathematical bioeconomics. Wiley, New YorkGoogle Scholar
  31. Clark CW, Munro G (1990) The economics of fishing and modern capital theory. J Environ Econ Manag 2:92–106Google Scholar
  32. Clemhout S, Wan H Jr (1985) Dynamic common property resources and environmental problems. J Optim Theory Appl 46:471–481Google Scholar
  33. Clemhout S, Wan H Jr (1991) Environmental problems as a common property resource game. In: Hamalainen RP, Ehtamo HK (eds) Dynamic games and economic analyses. Springer, Berlin, pp 132–154Google Scholar
  34. Clemhout S, Wan H Jr (1995) The non-uniqueness of Markovian strategy equilibrium: the case of continuous time models for non-renewable resources. In: Paper presented at the 5th international symposium on dynamic games and applications, GrimentzGoogle Scholar
  35. Colombo L, Labrecciosa P (2013a) Oligopoly exploitation of a private property productive asset. J Econ Dyn Control 37(4):838–853Google Scholar
  36. Colombo L, Labrecciosa P (2013b) On the convergence to the Cournot equilibrium in a productive asset oligopoly. J Math Econ 49(6):441–445Google Scholar
  37. Colombo L, Labrecciosa P (2015) On the Markovian efficiency of Bertrand and Cournot equilibria. J Econ Theory 155:332–358Google Scholar
  38. Cornes R, Long NV, Shimomura K (2001) Drugs and pests: intertemporal production externalities. Jpn World Econ 13(3):255–278Google Scholar
  39. Couttenier M, Soubeyran R (2014) Drought and civil war in Sub-Saharan Africa. Econ J 124(575):201–244Google Scholar
  40. Couttenier M, Soubeyran R (2015) A survey of causes of civil conflicts: natural factors and economic conditions. Revue d’Economie Politique 125(6):787–810Google Scholar
  41. Crabbé P, Long NV (1993) Entry deterrence and overexploitation of the fishery. J Econ Dyn Control 17(4):679–704Google Scholar
  42. Dasgupta PS, Heal GM (1979) Economic theory and exhaustible resources. Cambridge University Press, CambridgeGoogle Scholar
  43. Dawkins R, Krebs J (1979) Arms races between and within species. Proc R Soc Lond Ser B 10:489–511Google Scholar
  44. de Frutos J, Martín-Herrán G (2015) Does flexibility facilitate sustainability of cooperation over time? A case study from environmental economics. J Optim Theory Appl 165(2):657–677Google Scholar
  45. Deacon R, Bohn H (2000) Ownership risk, investment, and the use of natural resources. Am Econ Rev 90(3):526–549Google Scholar
  46. de Zeeuw A (2008) Dynamic effects on the stability of international environmental agreements. J Environ Econ Manag 55:163–174Google Scholar
  47. Diamantoudi F, Sartzetakis E (2015) International environmental agreements: coordinated action under foresight. Econ Theory 59(3):527–546Google Scholar
  48. Dinar A, Hogarth M (2015) Game theory and water resources: critical review of its contributions, progress, and remaining challenges. Found Trends Microecon 11(1–2):1–139Google Scholar
  49. Dinar A, Zaccour G (2013) Strategic behavior and environmental commons. Environ Develop Econ 18(1):1–5Google Scholar
  50. Dockner E, Long NV (1993) International pollution control: cooperative versus non-cooperative strategies. J Environ Econ Manag 24:13–29Google Scholar
  51. Dockner E, Sorger G (1996) Existence and properties of equilibria for a dynamic game on productive assets. J Econ Theory 71:209–227Google Scholar
  52. Dockner E, Feichtinger G, Mehlmann A (1989) Noncooperative solution for a differential game model of fishery. J Econ Dyn Control 13:11–20Google Scholar
  53. Dockner ESJ, Long NV, Sorger G (2000) Differential games in economics and management science. Cambridge University Press, CambridgeGoogle Scholar
  54. Dutta PK, Sundaram RK (1993a) How different can strategic model be? J Econ Theory 60:42–91Google Scholar
  55. Dutta PK, Sundaram RK (1993b) The tragedies of the commons? Econ Theory 3:413–426Google Scholar
  56. Fesselmeyer E, Santugini M (2013) Strategic exploitation of a common resource under environmental risk. J Econ Dyn Control 37(1):125–136Google Scholar
  57. Food and Agriculture Organization (FAO) (2009) The state of world fisheries and aquaculture 2008. FAO Fisheries and Aquaculture Department, Food and Agriculture Organization of the United Nations, RomeGoogle Scholar
  58. Frey BS, Stutzer A (2007) Economics and psychology. MIT Press, CambridgeGoogle Scholar
  59. Fudenberg D, Levine DK (2006) A dual-self model of impulse control. Am Econ Rev 96: 1449–1476Google Scholar
  60. Fudenberg D, Levine DK (2012) Timing and self control. Econometrica 80(1):1–42Google Scholar
  61. Fudenberg D, Tirole J (1991) Game theory. MIT Press, CambridgeGoogle Scholar
  62. Fujiwara K (2011) Losses from competition in a dynamic game model of renewable resource oligopoly. Resour Energy Econ 33(1):1–11Google Scholar
  63. Fujiwara K, Long NV (2011) Welfare implications of leadership in a resource market under bilateral monopoly. Dyn Games Appl 1(4):479–497Google Scholar
  64. Fujiwara K, Long NV (2012) Optimal tariffs on exhaustible resources: the case of quantity setting. Int Game Theory Rev 14(04):124004-1-21Google Scholar
  65. Gaudet G (2007) Natural resource economics under the rule of hotelling. Canad J Econ 40(4):1033–1059Google Scholar
  66. Gaudet G, Lohoues H (2008) On limits to the use of linear Markov strategies in common property natural resource games. Environ Model Assess 13:567–574Google Scholar
  67. Gaudet G, Long NV (1994) On the effects of the distribution of initial endowments in a non-renewable resource duopoly. J Econ Dyn Control 18:1189–1198Google Scholar
  68. Grafton Q, Kompas T, Long NV (2016) A brave new world? Interaction among Kantians and Nashians, and the dynamic of climate change mitigation. In: Paper presented at the Tinbergen Institute conference on climate change, AmsterdamGoogle Scholar
  69. Greenberg J (1990) The theory of social situations: an alternative game-theoretic approach. Cambridge University Press, CambridgeGoogle Scholar
  70. Gilbert R (1978) Dominant firm pricing policy in a market for an exhaustible resource. Bell J Econ 9(2):385–395Google Scholar
  71. Groot F, Withagen C, de Zeeuw A (2003) Strong time-consistency in a Cartel-versus-Fringe model. J Econ Dyn Control 28:287–306Google Scholar
  72. Hardin G (1968) The tragedy of the commons. Science 162:1240–1248Google Scholar
  73. Haurie M, Tavoni BC, van der Zwaan C (2011) Modelling uncertainty and the climate change: recommendations for robust energy policy. Environ Model Assess 17:1–5Google Scholar
  74. Heal G (2009) The economics of climate change: a post-stern perspective. Clim Change 96: 275–297Google Scholar
  75. Herrmann M, Gaudet G (2009) The economic dynamics of antibiotic efficacy under open access. J Environ Econ Manag 57:334–350Google Scholar
  76. Hoel M (1978) Resource extraction, substitute production, and monopoly. J Econ Theory 19(1): 28–37Google Scholar
  77. Hoel M (2011) The supply side of CO2 with country heterogeneity. Scand J Econ 113(4):846–865Google Scholar
  78. Jørgensen S, Yeung DWK (1996) Stochastic differential game model of common property fishery. J Optim Theory Appl 90(2):381–404Google Scholar
  79. Jørgensen S, Zaccour G (2001) Time consistent side payments in a dynamic game of downstream pollution. J Econ Dyn Control 25:1973–87Google Scholar
  80. Kagan M, van der Ploeg F, Withagen C (2015) Battle for climate and scarcity rents: beyond the linear-quadratic case. Dyn Games Appl 5(4):493–522Google Scholar
  81. Kahneman D, Tversky A (1984) Choices, values and frames. Am Psychol 39:341–350Google Scholar
  82. Kaitala V, Hamalainen RP, Ruusunen J (1985) On the analysis of equilibria and bargaining in a fishery game. In: Feichtinger G (ed) Optimal control theory and economic analysis II. North Holland, Amsterdam, pp 593–606Google Scholar
  83. Karp L (1984) Optimality and consistency in a differential game with non-renewable resources. J Econ Dyn Control 8:73–97Google Scholar
  84. Karp L, Newbery D (1991) Optimal tariff on exhaustible resources. J Int Econ 30:285–99Google Scholar
  85. Karp L, Newbery D (1992) Dynamically consistent oil import tariffs. Canad J Econ 25:1–21Google Scholar
  86. Katayma S, Long NV (2010) A dynamic game of status-seeking with public capital and an exhaustible resource. Opt Control Appl Methods 31:43–53Google Scholar
  87. Katayama S, Long NV, Ohta H (2014) Carbon tax and comparison of trading regimes in fossil fuels. In: Semmler W, Tragler G, Verliov V (eds) Dynamics optimization in environmental economics. Springer, Berlin, pp 287–314Google Scholar
  88. Kemp MC, Long NV (1979) The interaction between resource-poor and resource-rich economies. Aust Econ Pap 18:258–267Google Scholar
  89. Kemp MC, Long NV (1980) Exhaustible resources, optimality, and trade. North Holland, AmsterdamGoogle Scholar
  90. Kemp MC, Long NV (1984) Essays in the economics of exhaustible resources. North Holland, AmsterdamGoogle Scholar
  91. Keutiben O (2014) On capturing foreign oil rents. Resour Energy Econ 36(2):542–555Google Scholar
  92. Khalatbary F (1977) Market imperfections and the optimal rate of depletion of natural resources. Economica 44:409–14Google Scholar
  93. Kolstad CD (1994) Hotelling rents in hotelling space: product differentiation in exhaustible resource markets. J Environ Econ Manag 26:163–180Google Scholar
  94. Krugman P, Obstfeld M, Melitz M (2015) International economics: theory and policy, 10th edn. Pearson, BostonGoogle Scholar
  95. Kwon OS (2006) Partial coordination in the Great Fish War. Environ Resour Econ 33:463–483Google Scholar
  96. Lahiri S, Ono Y (1988) Helping minor firms reduce welfare. Econ J 98:1199–1202Google Scholar
  97. Lambertini L, Mantovani A (2014) Feedback equilibria in a dynamic renewable resource oligopoly: pre-emption, voracity and exhaustion. J Econ Dyn Control 47:115–122Google Scholar
  98. Laurent-Lucchetti J, Santugini M (2012) Ownership risk and the use of common-pool natural resources. J Environ Econ Manag 63:242–259Google Scholar
  99. Levhari D, Mirman L (1980) The great fish war: an example using a dynamic Cournot Nash solution. Bell J Econ 11:322–334Google Scholar
  100. Lewis T, Schmalensee R (1980) On oligopolistic markets for nonrenewable natural resources. Q J Econ 95:471–5Google Scholar
  101. Liski M, Tahvonen O (2004) Can carbon tax eat OPEC’s rents? J Environ Econ Manag 47: 1–12Google Scholar
  102. Long NV (1975) Resource extraction under the uncertainty about possible nationalization. J Econ Theory 10(1):42–53Google Scholar
  103. Long NV (1977) Optimal exploitation and replenishment of a natural resource. Essay 4 in Pitchford JD, Turnovsky SJ (eds) Applications of control theory to economic analysis. North-Holland, Amsterdam, pp 81–106Google Scholar
  104. Long NV (1994) On optimal enclosure and optimal timing of enclosure. Econ Rec 70(221): 141–145Google Scholar
  105. Long NV (2010) A survey of dynamic games in economics. World Scientific, SingaporeGoogle Scholar
  106. Long NV (2011) Dynamic games in the economics of natural resources: a survey. Dyn Games Appl 1(1):115–148Google Scholar
  107. Long NV (2015a) Kant-Nash equilibrium in a dynamic game of climate change mitigations. In: Paper presented at the CESifo area conference on climate and energy, Oct 2015 (CESifo), MunichGoogle Scholar
  108. Long NV (2015b) The green paradox in open economies: lessons from static and dynamic models. Rev Environ Econ Policies 9(2):266–285Google Scholar
  109. Long NV (2016a) Kant-Nash equilibrium in a quantity-setting oligopoly. In: von Mouche P, Quartieri F (eds) Contributions on equilibrium theory for Cournot oligopolies and related games: essays in Honour of Koji Okuguchi. Springer, Berlin, pp 171–192Google Scholar
  110. Long NV (2016b) Mixed-strategy Kant-Nash equilibria in games of voluntary contributions to a public good. In: Buchholz W, Ruebbelke D (eds) The theory of externalities and public goods. SpringerGoogle Scholar
  111. Long NV, McWhinnie S (2012) The tragedy of the commons in a fishery when relative performance matters. Ecol Econ 81:140–154Google Scholar
  112. Long NV, Sorger G (2006) Insecure property rights and growth: the roles of appropriation costs, wealth effects, and heterogeneity. Econ Theory 28(3):513–529Google Scholar
  113. Long NV, Sorger G (2010) A dynamic principal-agent problem as a feedback Stackelberg differential game. Central Eur J Oper Res 18(4):491–509Google Scholar
  114. Long NV, Soubeyran A (2001) Cost manipulation games in oligopoly, with cost of manipulating. Int Econ Rev 42(2):505–533Google Scholar
  115. Long NV, Staehler F (2014) General equilibrium effects of green technological progress. CIRANO working paper 2014s-16. CIRANO, MontrealGoogle Scholar
  116. Long NV, Wang S (2009) Resource grabbing by status-conscious agents. J Dev Econ 89(1):39–50Google Scholar
  117. Long NV, Prieur F, Puzon K, Tidball M (2014) Markov perfect equilibria in differential games with regime switching strategies. CESifo working paper 4662. CESifo Group, MunichGoogle Scholar
  118. Loury GC (1986) A theory of oligopoly: Cournot equilibrium in exhaustible resource market with fixed supplies. Int Econ Rev 27(2):285–301Google Scholar
  119. Martin-Herrán G, Rincón-Zapareto J (2005) Efficient Markov-perfect Nash equilibria: theory and application to dynamic fishery games. J Econ Dyn Control 29:1073–96Google Scholar
  120. Maskin E, Newbery D (1990) Disadvantageous oil tariffs and dynamic consistency. Am Econ Rev 80(1):143–156Google Scholar
  121. McDonald SL (1971) Petroleum conservation in the United States: an economic analysis. Johns Hopkins Press, BaltimoreGoogle Scholar
  122. McMillan J, H-W Sinn (1984) Oligopolistic extraction of a common property resource: dynamic equilibria. In: Kemp MC, Long NV (eds) Essays in the economics of exhaustible resources. North Holland, Amsterdam, pp 199–214Google Scholar
  123. McWhinnie SF (2009) The tragedy of the commons in international fisheries: an empirical investigation. J Environ Econ Manag 57:312–333Google Scholar
  124. Mirman L, Santugini M (2014) Strategic exploitation of a common-property resource under rational learning about its reproduction. Dyn Games Appl 4(1):58–72Google Scholar
  125. Myerson R, Weibull J (2015) Tenable strategy blocks and settled equilibria. Econometrica 83(3):943–976Google Scholar
  126. Ostrom E (1990) Governing the commons: the evolution of institutions for collective actions. Cambridge University Press, CambridgeGoogle Scholar
  127. Ray D, Vohra R (2001) Coalitional power and public goods. J Polit Econ 109(6):1355–1384Google Scholar
  128. Roemer JE (2010) Kantian equilibrium. Scand J Econ 112(1):1–24Google Scholar
  129. Roemer JE (2015) Kantian optimization: a microfoundation for cooperation. J Public Econ 127: 45–57Google Scholar
  130. Rubio SJ (2011) On capturing rent from non-renewable resource international monopoly: prices versus quantities. Dyn Games Appl 1(4):558–580Google Scholar
  131. Rubio SJ, Estriche L (2001) Strategic Pigouvian taxation, stock externalities and polluting non-renewable resources. J Public Econ 79(2):297–313Google Scholar
  132. Russell B (1945) A history of western philosophy. George Allen and Unwin, LondonGoogle Scholar
  133. Salant S (1976) Exhaustible resources and industrial structure: a Nash-Cournot approach to the World oil market. J Polit Econ 84:1079–94Google Scholar
  134. Salant S, Switzer S, Reynolds R (1983) Losses from horizontal merger: the effects of an exogenous change in industry structure on Cournot Nash equilibrium. Q J Econ 98(2):185–199Google Scholar
  135. Salo S, Tahvonen O (2001) Oligopoly equilibria in nonrenewable resource markets. J Econ Dyn Control 25:671–702Google Scholar
  136. Sethi R, Somanathan E (1996) The evolution of social norms in common property resource use. Am Econ Rev 86(4):766–88Google Scholar
  137. Sidgwick H (1874) The method of ethics, 7th edn. 1907. Macmillan, London. Reprinted by the Hackett Publishing Company (1981)Google Scholar
  138. Sinn H-W (1984) Common property resources, storage facilities, and ownership structure: a Cournot model of the oil market. Economica 51:235–52Google Scholar
  139. Smith A (1776) An inquiry into the nature and causes of the wealth of nations. In: Cannan E (ed) The modern library, 1937. Random House, New YorkGoogle Scholar
  140. Smith A (1790) The theory of moral sentiments. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, UK. Republished in the series Cambridge texts in the history of philosophy, 2002. Edited by K. HaakonssenGoogle Scholar
  141. Stiglitz JE (1976) Monopoly power and the rate of extraction of exhaustible resources. Am Econ Rev 66:655–661Google Scholar
  142. Sundaram RK (1989) Perfect equilibria in non-randomized strategies in a class of symmetric games. J Econ Theory 47:153–177Google Scholar
  143. Tahvonen O (1996) Trade with polluting non-renewable resources. J Environ Econ Manag 30:1–17Google Scholar
  144. Tornell A (1997) Economic growth and decline with endogenous property rights. J Econ Growth 2(3):219–257Google Scholar
  145. Tornell A, Lane P (1999) The voracity effect. Am Econ Rev 89:22–46Google Scholar
  146. Ulph A, Folie GM (1980) Exhaustible resources and Cartels: an intertemporal Nash-Cournot model. Canad J Econ 13:645–58Google Scholar
  147. van der Meijden KR, Withagen C (2016) Double limit pricing. In: Paper presented at the 11th Tinbergen Institute conference on climate change, AmsterdamGoogle Scholar
  148. van der Ploeg R (2010) Rapacious resource depletion, excessive investment and insecure property rights. CESifo working paper no 2981, University of MunichGoogle Scholar
  149. Veblen TB (1899) The theory of the Leisure class: an economic study of institutions. Modern Library, New YorkGoogle Scholar
  150. Watkins GC (1977) Conservation and economic efficiency: Alberta oil proration. J Environ Econ Manag 4:40–56Google Scholar
  151. Wirl F (1994) Pigouvian taxation of energy for flow and stock externalities and strategic non-competitive energy pricing. J Environ Econ Manag 26:1–18Google Scholar
  152. World Trade Organization (2010) World trade report, 2010, Washington, DCGoogle Scholar

Copyright information

© Springer International Publishing AG, part of Springer Nature 2018

Authors and Affiliations

  1. 1.McGill UniversityMontrealCanada

Personalised recommendations