Introduction

Over the past 40 years, financial markets have become increasingly integrated. Market integration began with open markets, in which asset prices were determined globally. The relevant literature emerged in the 1970s, with early theoretical developments in international asset-pricing models. Since then, a growing body of evidence supporting the argument that risk premia are determined globally has accumulated. These days, market integration is often tested using “equality” in risk pricing based on an asset-pricing benchmark or “the law of one price” to avoid arbitrage between variables, such as prices or interest rates. These definitions of financial market integration suggest that integration leads to the conversion of market-specific risk into common risk (Lehkonen 2015). It is strongly argued that an integrated market leads to enhanced economic growth and stability through direct financial channels, such as lower capital costs and increased investment opportunities (Carrieri et al. 2007). Global financial integration has some detractors. One major criticism is that it significantly raises global market volatility during a crisis and causes financial markets to be more vulnerable to global shocks. Since the onset of the global financial crisis (GFC) between 2007 and 2009, periodic local financial crises have occurred worldwide, and market contagion has become one of the most researched topics in the study of financial markets. Gagnon and Karolyi (2006) surveyed the history of financial market contagion and identified volatility spillover as the major driving force behind crisis contagion.

Extant literature has clearly demonstrated that disentangling contagion from market interdependence is crucial for singling out contagion in the event of a financial crisis. Market contagion is measured by a significant increase in the correlation between two markets. One major pitfall in correctly identifying contagion is that it is not simply shown by an increased correlation of performance indicators during a crisis period. The increasing correlation coefficient is somewhat flawed due to the interference of rising volatility, which is commonly associated with periods of financial stress (Forbes and Rigobon 2002). To overcome this, most contagion tests define contagion as “a correlation in excess of that expected via fundamentals” (Bekaert et al. 2005, p.40). However, Bekaert et al. (2005) acknowledged the difficulty in “identifying both the relevant fundamentals and how they are linked to correlation” (p.40).

Thus, contagion tests have been redefined continuously over the years, as the sources of correlation biases or correlation increases due to relevant fundamentals are identified by removing confounding effects.Footnote 1 This process started with Forbes and Rigobon (2002), who noted that cross-market correlation increases during crisis periods due to “common as well as market-specific factors” (p.2225). As the volatility of the target market may change due to common and market-specific factors, many studies use factor decomposition models to identify contagion (Bekaert et al. 2005; Corsetti et al. 2001, 2005; Dungey et al. 2005a, b; Dungey and Martin 2001; Forbes and Rigobon 2002).Footnote 2 Bekeart et al. (2014) defined contagion as “the comovement in excess of that implied by the factor model” (p.2598), which is an improvement on the old definition (Bekaert et al. 2005), as it is not limited to correlation increase as a contagion measurement.

To investigate the comovement defined by Bekeart et al. (2014) more precisely, this study linked the latent factor model (LFM) and the single equation error correction model (SEECM). The LFM assumes market-specific and common systematic volatilities to describe market returns under market integration. The SEECM describes the dynamic process of market returns to equilibrium from a state of disequilibrium due to a shock, assuming that two market return time series exhibit a linear equilibrium relationship that determines short- and long-term behavior (Banerjee et al. 1990, 1993; Davidson et al. 1978). By linking the two models via first-order autoregressive (AR[1]) errors, this study described stressful market situations more precisely. The major strength of linking the two models is the ability to establish the null market integration hypothesis (MIH) for tranquil periods and analyze the contagion structurally via a causal relation between two markets for crisis periods. This reveals that the short-term relationship, that is, the common-factor loading, is the main backbone of the linked model and is entirely embedded in the long-term relationship and correlatedness between two markets. These findings allow for an accurate and concise definition of contagion: contagion is defined as an occurrence of breaks in the long-term relationship or correlatedness between two markets mainly caused by breaks in the short-term relationship. This definition is reasonable, as contagion would be in effect when the short-term effect of a shock is not properly controlled at the beginning of the crisis period and continues to cause breaks in the long-term relationship or correlatedness between two markets. From the market behavior perspective, long-term relationships or correlatedness may be considered comovements, while short-term effects may be considered the market speed ratio (MSR) of two market movements under integration, which depends on liquidity and possibility of downside risk (Eq. 7).

This approach leads to the consideration of various situations as potential alternatives when a shock hits a source market (Table 1). The originality of this approach is the application of the Bayesian method to those situations in order to identify contagion. This study used the Bayesian method to analytically detect comovement in excess of that expected from fundamentals, identifying it as contagion. When comovement (long-term relationship or correlatedness) between the target and source markets is broken, the cause is determined by calculating posterior probabilities. If the cause is a short-term (MSR) break, the contagion is formally addressed.

Identifying contagion based on comovement involves two critical issues (Dungey and Renault 2018): (1) how correlation is related to common and market-specific factors during tranquil and crisis periods (Bekaert et al. 2005; Corsetti et al. 2005; Dungey and Martin 2007; Dungey et al. 2010, 2011; Forbes and Rigobon 2002) and (2) how all time-varying components of return volatilities are related to structural breaks during crisis times (Aït-Sahalia et al. 2015; Bae et al. 2003; Baur and Schulze 2005; Boyson et al. 2010; Bussetti and Harvey 2011; Favero and Giavazzi 2002; Rodriguez 2007). The present approach completely resolves these two critical issues, as demonstrated below.

The empirical part of this study involves applying the Bayesian approach to address the financial market contagion between the U.S. and other countries under market integration during the GFC between 2007 and 2009. This study evaluated the contagion effects of the U.S. stock market during the GFC using 22 developed equity markets. The results revealed that some countries suffered from financial contagion from the U.S. market crash, while others managed to escape contagion. Some key contagion parameters, such as short- and long-term effects, correlatedness between source and target markets, and contagion odds, must be monitored during a financial stress. An increase in short- and long-term effects or correlatedness suggests potential contagion. These contagion parameters could help policymakers and investors develop alternative and practical guidelines against contagion.

Identifying contagion is vital not only in financial markets but also in macroeconomic dynamics. Kalemli-Ozcan et al. (2013) and Beck (2021) demonstrated the necessity of identifying contagion to establish the link between financial integration and business cycle synchronization in European Union countries. The present approach to identify contagion is promising in its application to analyzing contagion phenomena in various macroeconomic and financial market variables across international markets.

The remainder of this paper is organized as follows. First, the market model and market integration hypothesis are discussed. Next, contagion dynamics and the Bayesian testing procedure are described. Following this, the major findings for the 2008 US market crisis are presented. Finally, concluding remarks are provided.

Methods

Market modeling under integration

Linking the latent factor and single equation error correction models

The latent factor model Eq. 10 (LFM, Appendix 1) was linked to the single equation error correction model Eq. 11 (SEECM, Appendix 2) to model the market dynamics between two markets under integration. This linking process yields a proper model for identifying contagion using a Bayesian approach. To link the two models, we introduced AR(1) errors \(u_{x,t}\) and \(u_{y,t}\) for the LFM, as in Eq. 1. AR(1) errors are useful for describing market behavior during periods of financial stress via the parameter \({\upeta }\). For instance, providing more (or less) information to the market can make \({\upeta }\) close to zero (or close to 1), which indicates iid \(u\). Phillips et al. (2011) investigated the near-explosive process with the AR(1) parameter \({\upeta }\) close to 1 during a crisis period.

Proposition 1

Suppose that we employ an AR(1) model for the idiosyncratic factors \(u_{x,t}\) and \(u_{y,t}\) in Eq.  10 :

$$u_{x,t} = \eta_{x} u_{x,t - 1} + a_{u,t} \quad u_{y,t} = \eta_{y} u_{y,t - 1} + b_{u,t}$$
(1)

where \(E\left( {a_{u,t} W_{t} } \right) = 0, E\left( {a_{u,t} u_{x,t - 1} } \right) = 0, E\left( {b_{u,t} W_{t} } \right) = 0, E\left( {b_{u,t} u_{y,t - 1} } \right) = 0\), \(E\left( {a_{u,t} b_{u,t} } \right) = 0\), \(a_{u,t} \sim iid \left( {0,1} \right), and b_{u,t} \sim iid \left( {0,1} \right).\) This links the LFM to the SEECM as follows:

$$\Delta Y_{t} = \frac{{\theta_{y} }}{{\theta_{x} }}\Delta X_{t} - \left( {1 - \eta_{y} } \right)\left( {Y_{t - 1} - \frac{{\theta_{y} \left( {1 - \eta_{x} } \right)}}{{\theta_{x} \left( {1 - \eta_{y} } \right)}}X_{t - 1} } \right) + \varepsilon_{Lt}$$
(2)

where \(\varepsilon_{Lt} = \delta_{y} b_{u,t} - \frac{{\theta_{y} }}{{\theta_{x} }}\delta_{x} a_{u,t} + (\eta_{x } - \eta_{y } )\theta_{y} W_{t - 1}\) with iid over t, \(0 < \eta_{y} < 1\), and \(Var(\varepsilon_{Lt } ) = \delta_{y}^{2} + \left( {\frac{{\theta_{y} }}{{\theta_{x} }}\delta_{x} } \right)^{2} + \left( {\eta_{x} - \eta_{y} } \right)^{2} \theta_{y}^{2} .\)

Proof of Proposition 1 is provided in Appendix 3.

Remark 1

Composition of the linked model. Using Proposition 1, we obtain the following:

$$\begin{aligned} \Delta Y_{t} & = \frac{{\theta_{y} }}{{\theta_{x} }}\Delta X_{t} - \left( {1 - \eta_{y} } \right)\left( {Y_{t - 1} - \frac{{\theta_{y} \left( {1 - \eta_{x} } \right)}}{{\theta_{x} \left( {1 - \eta_{y} } \right)}}X_{t - 1} } \right) + \varepsilon_{Lt} \\ & = \beta_{L0} \Delta X_{t} + \beta_{L1} \left( {Y_{t - 1} - \gamma_{L} X_{t - 1} } \right) + \varepsilon_{1t} = \beta_{L0} \Delta X_{t} + \beta_{L1} Y_{t - 1} + \beta_{L2} X_{t - 1} + \varepsilon_{Lt} . \\ \end{aligned}$$
(3)

where \(\beta_{L0} = \frac{{\theta_{y} }}{{\theta_{x} }}\), \(\gamma_{L} = \frac{{\theta_{y} \left( {1 - \eta_{x} } \right)}}{{\theta_{x} \left( {1 - \eta_{y} } \right)}}\), and \(\beta_{L2} = \frac{{\theta_{y} \left( {1 - \eta_{x} } \right)}}{{\theta_{x} }}\) correspond to the short-term effect, long-term effect, and correlatedness of the linked model, respectively.Footnote 3 Thus, the factors that might cause the time-varying comovement (or long-term effect and correlatedness of Eq. 3) during a crisis include the common factors \(W_{t}\) via \(\theta_{x}\) and \(\theta_{y}\) and market-specific factors \(u_{x,t}\) and \(u_{y,t}\) via \(\eta_{x}\) and \(\eta_{y}\). \(\beta_{L0} = \frac{{\theta_{y} }}{{\theta_{x} }}\) is entirely embedded in \(\gamma_{L}\), \(\beta_{L2}\) and \(\varepsilon_{Lt}\) in Eq. 2. This feature not only plays a key role in formally defining contagion but also resolves various critical issues in identifying contagion, as described below.

Remark 2

Risk parameters. The variances of the idiosyncratic factors of X and Y are \({\text{Var}}\left( {\delta_{x} u_{x,t} } \right) = {\updelta }_{{\text{x}}}^{2} { }/\left( {1 - \eta_{x}^{2} } \right)\) and \({\text{ Var}}\left( {\delta_{y} u_{y,t} } \right) = {\updelta }_{{\text{y}}}^{2} /\left( {1 - \eta_{y}^{2} } \right)\) using Eq. 1, respectively. Thus, market-specific volatility becomes high as \(\eta_{x}\) and \(\eta_{y}\) are close to 1 or \(|{\updelta }_{{\text{x}}} |\) and \(\left| {{\updelta }_{{\text{y}}} } \right|\) are large. According to Proposition 1

\(Var(\varepsilon_{Lt } ) = \delta_{y}^{2} + \left( {\frac{{\theta_{y} }}{{\theta_{x} }}\delta_{x} } \right)^{2} + \left( {\eta_{x} - \eta_{y} } \right)^{2} \theta_{y}^{2}\);

therefore, volatility of \(\Delta Y_{t}\) of the target marketFootnote 4 depends on common and market-specific factors based on their parameters. Volatility increases not only when \({\updelta }_{{\text{y}}}\) becomes large but also when \(\theta_{y}\),\(\updelta _{{\text{x}}}\), and \(\left( {\eta_{x} - \eta_{y} } \right)^{2}\) are large. Target market volatility may be decreased by reducing \(\frac{{\theta_{y} }}{{\theta_{x} }}\) and \(\left( {\eta_{x} - \eta_{y} } \right)^{2} \theta_{y}^{2}\) during the financial stress period.

Remark 3

Causality issue. During periods of financial stress with an increased possibility of downside risk, investors tend to exhibit more risk-adverse behavior due to imperfect information. Historically, fears have prompted investors to display herding behavior in the market, which increases the AR(1) parameters \(\eta_{x} \; and\; \eta_{y}\) to close to 1, making them different (Phillips et al. 2011). Different AR(1) parameters (\(\eta_{x} \ne \eta_{y}\)) make \(\varepsilon_{Lt}\) of Eq. 2 depend on \({\text{W}}_{{{\text{t}} - 1}}\), suggesting endogeneity, which usually leads to causality in both directions (from X to Y and from Y to X; Dungey et al. 2005b). This could explain the various breakages in parameters during a crisis.

The market integration hypothesis

The market integration hypothesis (MIH) refers to a tranquil period situation in which market returns X and Y share a common factor with the respective level of risk, and hence, their normal comovement is expected. As Proposition 1 describes the general market dynamics between X and Y, the tranquil period may be based as a null hypothesis against the crisis period.

Proposition 2

Assume the following null MIH:

$$MIH{:}\; \eta_{x} = \eta_{y} = \eta_{0} \;for\;some\;0 < \eta_{0} < 1,\;\frac{{\theta_{y} }}{{\theta_{x} }} \ne 1,\;and\; \theta_{x} \theta_{y} \ne 0$$
(4)

Then, under the null MIH , Eq.  2 can be rewritten as follows:

$$\Delta Y_{t} = \frac{{\theta_{y} }}{{\theta_{x} }}\Delta X_{t} - \left( {1 - \eta_{0} } \right)\left( {Y_{t - 1} - \frac{{\theta_{y} }}{{\theta_{x} }}X_{t - 1} } \right) + \varepsilon_{Mt}$$
(5)

where \(\varepsilon_{Mt} = \delta_{y} b_{u,t} - \frac{{\theta_{y} }}{{\theta_{x} }}\delta_{x} a_{u,t}\) is an iid error with \(E\left( {\varepsilon_{Mt} } \right) = 0\) and finite variance of \(Var(\varepsilon_{Mt } ) = \delta_{y}^{2} + \left( {\frac{{\theta_{y} }}{{\theta_{x} }}\delta_{x} } \right)^{2}\) .

Proof of Proposition 2, Eq. 5 easily follows by applying Eq. 4 to Eq. 2.

Remark 4

Basic linear relationship under MIH. Using Proposition 2, we obtain the following:

$$\begin{aligned} \Delta Y_{t} & = \frac{{\theta_{y} }}{{\theta_{x} }}\Delta X_{t} - \left( {1 - \eta_{0} } \right)\left( {Y_{t - 1} - \frac{{\theta_{y} }}{{\theta_{x} }}X_{t - 1} } \right) + \varepsilon_{Mt} \\ & = \beta_{M0} \Delta X_{t} + \beta_{M1} \left( {Y_{t - 1} - \gamma_{M} X_{t - 1} } \right) + \varepsilon_{Mt} = \beta_{M0} \Delta X_{t} + \beta_{M1} Y_{t - 1} + \beta_{M2} X_{t - 1} + \varepsilon_{Mt} \\ \end{aligned}$$
(6)

where \(\beta_{M0} = \frac{{\theta_{y} }}{{\theta_{x} }}\), \({\upgamma }_{{\text{M}}} = \frac{{\theta_{y} }}{{\theta_{x} }}\), and \({\upbeta }_{{{\text{M}}2}} = \frac{{\theta_{y} \left( {1 - \eta_{0} } \right)}}{{\theta_{x} }}\) correspond to the short-term effect, long-term effect, and correlatedness for the MIH, respectively, and \(\left( {Y_{t - 1} - \frac{{\theta_{y} }}{{\theta_{x} }}X_{t - 1} } \right) = 0\) when X and Y are in equilibrium. Equation 6 subsequently implies a basic linear relationshipFootnote 5\(Y_{t } = \frac{{\theta_{y} }}{{\theta_{x} }}X_{t}\) \(Y_{t } = \frac{{\theta_{y} }}{{\theta_{x} }}X_{t}\) and the corresponding market speed ratio (MSR) between two markets during a tranquil period; that is,

$$\Delta Y_{t} /\Delta X_{t} = \frac{{\theta_{y} }}{{\theta_{x} }}.$$
(7)

In fact, the MSR equals the short-term effect and holds for general market situations (refer to footnote 5).

Remark 5

Practical meaning of MIH. The null MIH above implies a situation in which two markets are midway between the two extremes of perfect integration into one market and two completely independent markets (Appendix 4). This implies that market-specific volatility is the same in markets X and Y (\({\upeta }_{{\text{x}}} = {\upeta }_{{\text{y}}} = {\upeta }_{0} )\), and that they share a common factor \(\left( {{\uptheta }_{{\text{x}}} {\uptheta }_{{\text{y}}} \ne 0} \right)\) with different levels of systematic risk \(\left( {\frac{{{\uptheta }_{{\text{y}}} }}{{{\uptheta }_{{\text{x}}} }} \ne 1} \right)\). This notion is consistent with the financial market theory, which indicates that only global systematic risks are priced in two fully integrated markets and that integration leads to the conversion of a market-specific risk of each market into a common risk. This implies that local market-specific risks are fully diversified for integrated markets (Lehkonen 2015). In this sense, the MIH achieves two fully integrated markets without any endogeneity problem by allowing \(\eta_{x} = \eta_{y}\) in Eq. 1. The parametric condition \(0 < \eta_{x} = \eta_{y} = \eta_{0} < 1\) is essential for the convergence to the equilibrium in Eq. 6 (\(- 1 < \beta_{M1} = - \left( {1 - \eta_{0} } \right){ } < 0\)).

Remark 6

Contagion and the MSR. It is reasonable to discuss market contagion by testing the MIH as a proper null hypothesis. Testing MIH against a crisis enables the detection of comovement change and breaks in long-term effect or correlatedness in excess of those implied by the MIH. As the MSR, being equal to the short-term effect, is actually the relative adjustment speed of market movements to new information from the source market, the MSR is a function of liquidity and possibility of downside risk. Therefore, if the MSR fails to decrease or slow down properly during a stress period, an increase in the comovement (long-term effect or correlatedness) would be unavoidable in excess of that implied by the MIH. Thus, the MSR slowdown during crises is a critical issue in market contagion, as discussed below.

Resolving the two critical issues

The present linked model resolved the two critical issues for identifying contagion based on comovements discussed in the Introduction: (1) how correlation is related to common and market-specific factors during tranquil and crisis periods and (2) how all time-varying components of return volatilities are related to structural breaks in crisis times. Regarding the first issue, Eq. 3 illustrates that correlatedness \(\left( {{\upbeta }_{{{\text{L}}2}} = \frac{{{\uptheta }_{{\text{y}}} \left( {1 - {\upeta }_{{\text{x}}} } \right)}}{{{\uptheta }_{{\text{x}}} }}{ }} \right)\) is related to a common factor via \(\frac{{{\uptheta }_{{\text{y}}} }}{{{\uptheta }_{{\text{x}}} }}\) and to the market-specific factor of X through \(\left( {1 - {\upeta }_{{\text{x}}} } \right)\) under general situations. Under MIH \({ }\left( {{\upeta }_{y} = \eta_{x} = \eta_{0} } \right)\), these factors are reduced to correlatedness \({\upbeta }_{{{\text{M}}2}} = \frac{{{\uptheta }_{{\text{y}}} \left( {1 - {\upeta }_{0} } \right)}}{{{\uptheta }_{{\text{x}}} }}\) in Eq. 6. During a financial crisis period, \({\upeta }_{y} \ne \eta_{x}\) brings about endogeneity and changes in \(\left( {\frac{{\uptheta _{{\text{y}}} }}{{\uptheta _{{\text{x}}} }},\upeta _{{\text{x}}} ,\upeta _{{\text{y}}} } \right)\), which, in turn, results in increases in correlatedness and long-term effects.

Regarding the second issue, the present linked model defines volatility spillover clearly and simply by considering systematic (common) and market-specific volatility. As \(\frac{{\theta_{y} }}{{\theta_{x} }}\) is related to systematic volatility and \(\upeta _{{\text{x}}}\) and \(\upeta _{{\text{y}}}\) are related to market-specific volatility, volatility spillover occurs due to changes in \(\left( {\frac{{\uptheta _{{\text{y}}} }}{{\uptheta _{{\text{x}}} }},\upeta _{{\text{x}}} ,\upeta _{{\text{y}}} } \right)\) caused by a shock. These volatility changes cause direct changes in the short-term effect \(\left( {{\upbeta }_{{{\text{L}}0}} = \frac{{{\uptheta }_{{\text{y}}} }}{{{\uptheta }_{{\text{x}}} }},\;{\text{MSR}}} \right)\), long-term effect \(\left( {{\upgamma }_{{\text{L}}} = \frac{{{\uptheta }_{{\text{y}}} \left( {1 - {\upeta }_{{\text{x}}} } \right)}}{{{\uptheta }_{{\text{x}}} \left( {1 - {\upeta }_{{\text{y}}} } \right)}}} \right)\), correlatedness \(\left( {\upbeta _{{{\text{L}}2}} = \frac{{\uptheta _{{\text{y}}} \left( {1 -\upeta _{{\text{x}}} } \right)}}{{\uptheta _{{\text{x}}} }}} \right),\) or convergence speed to equilibrium \((\beta_{L1} = - \left( {1 - \eta_{y} } \right)\)). When the MIH is rejected or \(\left( {\frac{{\theta_{y} }}{{\theta_{x} }}, \eta_{0} , \eta_{0} } \right)\) under the MIH changes to \(\left( {\frac{{\theta_{y}^{{\prime}} }}{{\theta_{x}^{{\prime}} }}, \eta_{x}^{{\prime}} , \eta_{y}^{{\prime}} } \right)\), the error volatility under the MIH changes from \({\text{Var}}({\upvarepsilon }_{{\text{Mt }}} ) = \delta_{y}^{2} + \left( {\frac{{{\uptheta }_{{\text{y}}} }}{{{\uptheta }_{{\text{x}}} }}\delta_{x} } \right)^{2}\) to:

$${\text{Var}}({\upvarepsilon }_{{\text{Lt }}} ) = \delta_{y}^{2} + \left( {\frac{{\theta_{y}^{{\prime}} }}{{\theta_{x}^{{\prime}} }}\delta_{x} } \right)^{2} + \left( { \eta_{x}^{{\prime}} - \eta_{y}^{{\prime}} } \right)^{2} \theta_{y}^{{\prime} 2} .$$
(8)

Thus, Eq. 8 defines the volatility spillover related to systematic (\(\frac{{\theta_{y}^{{\prime}} }}{{\theta_{x}^{{\prime}} }})\) and market-specific element (\(\eta_{x}^{{\prime}}\),\(\eta_{y}^{{\prime}}\)). This explains how all time-varying components of return volatilities are related to structural breaks during crises.

Literature often treats volatility spillover as the tail dependence of market returns. Rodriguez (2007) noted that structural breaks in tail dependence are an actual dimension of contagion effects and tested them using copulas. Bussetti and Harvey (2011) used time-varying copulas to test financial contagion through tail events. Using coexceedance measures or quantiles, a number of studies have detected contagion using the tail (Bae et al. 2003; Baur and Schulze 2005; Boyson et al. 2010). Aït-Sahalia et al. (2015) measured contagion effects via the extreme tail events of mutually exciting jumps. Recently, Dungey and Renault (2018) applied a GARCH (Generalized Autoregressive Conditional Heteroskedasticity) common feature approach to identify contagion.

A simple illustrative market episode based on this discussion is provided in Appendix 5.

Defining and testing contagion

Defining contagion and testing breaks

A shock that occurs in source market X may cause a break in the established relationship with target market Y during tranquil periods, resulting in contagion. Three types of breaks in market relationships were considered: a break in a short-term relationship, or short-term break (SB), a break in a long-term relationship, or a long-term break (LB), and a break in correlatedness, or a correlatedness break (CRB). Contagion is expected to occur when a shock causes a break in the underlying relationship pertaining to \(\beta_{L0}\) (short-term), \({\upgamma }_{{\text{L}}}\) (long-term), and \(\beta_{L2}\) (correlatedness) in Eq. 3. As the long-term relationship \(\gamma_{L} = \frac{{\theta_{y} \left( {1 - \eta_{x} } \right)}}{{\theta_{x} \left( {1 - \eta_{y} } \right)}}\) and correlatedness \(\beta_{L2} = \frac{{\theta_{y} \left( {1 - \eta_{x} } \right)}}{{\theta_{x} }}\) contain the short-term effect \(\beta_{L0} = \frac{{\theta_{y} }}{{\theta_{x} }}\), the short-term effect, which is the MSR, can be used to create the following formal definition of contagion.

Definition

Contagion is declared if a long-term break (a break in \(\gamma_{L} = \frac{{\theta_{y} \left( {1 - \eta_{x} } \right)}}{{\theta_{x} \left( {1 - \eta_{y} } \right)}}\)) or a correlatedness break (a break in \(\beta_{L2} = \frac{{\theta_{y} \left( {1 - \eta_{x} } \right)}}{{\theta_{x} }}\)) is mainly caused by a short-term break (a break in \(\beta_{L0} = \frac{{\theta_{y} }}{{\theta_{x} }}\)).

This definition implies that contagion is declared when the short-term effect (the MSR) of a shock is not properly controlled in a target market at the beginning of the crisis period and continues to cause breaks in the long-term relationship or correlatedness between two markets.Footnote 6

To derive the contagion test, first this study tested whether a shock causes a break in the established linear relationship under the MIH described in Remark 4. Therefore, whether a given period experiences breaks in the relationships pertaining to \(\beta_{M0}\) (short-term effect or MSR), \({\upgamma }_{{\text{M}}}\) (long-term effect), and \(\beta_{M2}\) (correlatedness) in Eq. 6 was tested. To test the null MIH for a given period, the following hypotheses were proposed:

$$H_{0} { }:{ }\beta_{{{\text{L}}0}} = \beta_{{{\text{M}}0}} ,{ }\beta_{{{\text{L}}1}} = \beta_{{{\text{M}}1}} ,{ }\beta_{{{\text{L}}2}} = \beta_{{{\text{M}}2}} \;\left( {\beta_{{{\text{L}}0}} = \beta_{{{\text{M}}0}} ,{ }\gamma_{L} = \gamma_{{\text{M}}} ,{ }\beta_{{{\text{L}}2}} = \beta_{{{\text{M}}2}} ,{\text{ equivalently}}} \right)$$

\(H_{a}\): At least one of the following holds true:

$$\beta_{{{\text{L}}0}} \ne \beta_{{{\text{M}}0}} ,{ }\beta_{{{\text{L}}1}} \ne \beta_{{{\text{M}}1}} ,{ }\beta_{{{\text{L}}2}} \ne { }\beta_{{{\text{M}}2}} { }\left( {\beta_{{{\text{L}}0}} \ne \beta_{{{\text{M}}0}} ,{ }\gamma_{L} \ne \gamma_{{\text{M}}} ,{ }\beta_{{{\text{L}}2}} \ne \beta_{{{\text{M}}2}} ,{\text{ equivalently}}} \right)$$

The null hypothesis \(H_{0}\) illustrates that \(\beta_{M0}\), \(\gamma_{M}\), and \(\beta_{M2}\) are fixed with iid error \({\upvarepsilon }_{{{\text{Mt}}}}\), as noted in Eq. 6. In other words, for a given period, markets X and Y maintain \(\beta_{L0 } = \beta_{{{\text{M}}0}}\), \(\gamma_{L} = \gamma_{{\text{M}}}\), and \(\beta_{L2} = \beta_{{{\text{M}}2}}\) under the MIH. If \(H_{0}\) is rejected, then the MIH fails to hold. In this case, the markets fail to maintain their underlying relationship and experience breaks in the short- or long-term relationship or correlatedness.

We developed a test adopting quantile regression and a Z-test to evaluate such breaks (see Baur 2013 for a more detailed discussion on the advantages of quantile regression). This test is based on the idea that a random fluctuation of the slope estimates around a constant value (with only the intercept parameters systematically increasing as a function of quantile \(\vartheta\)) provides evidence for the iid error of the classical linear regression under the null MIH specified by Eq. 6. If some of the slope coefficients change as a function of quantile \(0 \le \vartheta \le 1,\) it is detected via the Z-test, which is designed to assess the magnitude of the estimated changes in slope for a given quantile. To implement the test, quantile regression parameters were estimated across the entire range of conditional quantiles of \(\Delta Y_{t}\) given \(\Delta X_{t}\). \((\beta_{{{\text{L}}0}} ,\gamma_{{\text{L}}} ,\beta_{{{\text{L}}2}} )\) was estimated using quantile regression across fixed \(N\) quantiles. Let \(\left( {\hat{\beta }_{{{\text{L}}0j}} ,\hat{\gamma }_{{{\text{L}}j}} ,\hat{\beta }_{{{\text{L}}2j}} } \right)\) be the slope estimates of \(\left( {\beta_{{{\text{L}}0j}} ,\gamma_{{{\text{L}}j}} ,\beta_{{{\text{L}}2j}} } \right)\) from the \(\frac{j}{N + 1}{\text{th}}\) quantile regression for \(j = 1, \ldots ,N\). Using the Proposition 3 in the Appendix 6, the Z-test can be derived as follows. Let \(P_{i}\) be \(\left( {\hat{\varphi }_{i1} , \ldots ,\hat{\varphi }_{iN} } \right)\), where \(\hat{\upvarphi }_{ij} \left( {i = 1,2,3, j = 1,\ldots,N} \right)\) is the ith slope estimate for one of the three slope estimates (\(\hat{\beta }_{{{\text{L}}0{\text{j}}}}\), \(\hat{\gamma }_{{{\text{L}}j}} , \hat{\beta }_{{{\text{L}}2j}}\)) from the \(\frac{j}{N + 1}{\text{th}}\) quantile regression. Let \(P_{ i, - k}\) represent a vector constructed by excluding the kth element from \(P_{i} = \left( {\hat{\varphi }_{i1} , \ldots ,\hat{\varphi }_{iN} } \right)\). For instance, \(P_{i, - 1} = \left( {\hat{\varphi }_{i2} , \ldots ,\hat{\varphi }_{i,N} } \right)\) and \(P_{i, - N} = \left( {\hat{\varphi }_{i1} , \ldots ,\hat{\varphi }_{i,N - 1} } \right)\). Then,Footnote 7

$${ }Z_{i, k} = \frac{{ \hat{\varphi }_{ik} - m_{k} }}{{s_{k} }}\;{\text{is N}}\left( {0,{1}} \right){\text{ asymptotically}}$$
(9)

with mean \(m_{k}\) and standard deviation \({\text{s}}_{{\text{k}}}\) from \(P_{i, - k}\). This Z-test can be employed to test the following hypotheses.

\(H_{0}^{SB}\)

There is no short-term (MSR) break between X and Y in the \(\frac{k}{N + 1}{\text{th}}\) quantile

(or \(\hat{\beta }_{{{\text{L}}0k}}\) originates from the same normal distribution as the others in \(P_{1}\) under \({ }H_{0}\)).

\(H_{1}^{SB}\)

There is a short-term (MSR) break between X and Y in the \(\frac{k}{N + 1}{\text{th}}\) quantile

(or \(\hat{\beta }_{{{\text{L}}0k}}\) does not originate from the same normal distribution as the others in \(P_{1}\) under \({ }H_{{\text{a}}}\)).

\(H_{0}^{LB}\)

There is no long-term break between X and Y in the \(\frac{k}{N + 1}{\text{th}}\) quantile

(or \(\hat{\gamma }_{{{\text{L}}k}}\) originates from the same normal distribution as the others in \(P_{2}\) under \({ }H_{0}\)).

\(H_{1}^{LB}\)

There is a long-term break between X and Y in the \(\frac{k}{N + 1}{\text{th}}\) quantile

(or \(\hat{\gamma }_{{{\text{L}}k}}\) does not originate from the same normal distribution as the others in \(P_{2}\) under \({ }H_{{\text{a}}}\)).

\(H_{0}^{CRB}\)

There is no correlatedness break between X and Y in the \(\frac{k}{N + 1}{\text{th}}\) quantile

(or \(\hat{\beta }_{{{\text{L}}2k}}\) originates from the same normal distribution as the others in \(P_{3}\) under \({ }H_{0}\)).

\(H_{1}^{CRB}\)

There is a correlatedness break between X and Y in the \(\frac{k}{N + 1}{\text{th}}\) quantile

(or \(\hat{\beta }_{{{\text{L}}2k}}\) does not originate from the same normal distribution as the others in \(P_{3}\) under \({ }H_{{\text{a}}}\)).

The basic structure of testing the hypotheses of our main concern in Fig. 1 shows that a long-term break (\(H_{1}^{LB}\)) or a correlatedness break (\(H_{1}^{CRB}\)) is caused by a short-term break (\(H_{1}^{SB}\)).

Fig. 1
figure 1

Basic causal structure of testing contagion

As a break in the established relationship is expected to occur at low quantiles corresponding to crisis periods, the contagion test can use the slope estimates at low quantiles, namely, \({ }\hat{\beta }_{{{\text{L}}01}} , \hat{\gamma }_{{{\text{L}}1}} ,\) or \(\hat{\beta }_{{{\text{L}}21}}\). The selection of the low quantile may be justified by the fact that during a crisis period, when \(\Delta X_{t}\) decreases, \(\Delta Y_{t }\) tends to decrease more significantly than usual. Hence, a significant change is expected to occur in \(\frac{{{\uptheta }_{{\text{y}}} }}{{{\uptheta }_{{\text{x}}} }}\) at low quantile (recall \(\Delta Y_{t} /\Delta X_{t} = \frac{{\theta_{y} }}{{\theta_{x} }}\) under the MIH based on Eq. 7) or a structural break in (left) tail dependence, which is an actual dimension of the contagion effects (Bussetti and Harvey 2011; Rodriguez 2007). In summary, quantile regression is employed to handle contagion as a left-tail event. By rejecting \(H_{0}^{SB}\), \(H_{0}^{LB}\), and \(H_{0}^{CRB}\) using \(\hat{\beta }_{{{\text{L}}01}} , \hat{\gamma }_{{{\text{L}}1}} ,\) and \(\hat{\beta }_{{{\text{L}}21}}\), respectively, breaks can be identified in the short-term relationship, long-term relationship, and correlatedness during crisis periods, respectively.

Contagion dynamics against the MIH

Based on the null MIH and Eq. 6, various kinds of situations can occur when a shock hits market X. Changes in \(\left( {\frac{{\theta_{y} }}{{\theta_{x} }}, \eta_{x} , \eta_{y} } \right)\) and volatility spillover based on Eq. 8 caused by a shock create structure breaks in short- or long-term effect or correlatedness (\(\beta_{L0}\),\({\upgamma }_{{\text{L}}}\), \(\beta_{L2}\)). There are eight possible cases of breaks in short- or long-term effect or correlatedness (\(\beta_{L0}\), \({\upgamma }_{{\text{L}}}\), \(\beta_{L2} )\) resulting from the changes in \(\left( {\frac{{\theta_{y} }}{{\theta_{x} }}, \eta_{x} , \eta_{y} } \right)\). Table 1 summarizes the eight possible situations (S1–S8) with causality relations between \(\left( {\frac{{\theta_{y} }}{{\theta_{x} }}, \eta_{x} , \eta_{y} } \right)\) and (\(\beta_{L0}\), \({\upgamma }_{{\text{L}}}\), \(\beta_{L2} )\) when a shock hits market X. Appendix 7 verifies the causality relationships between the eight situations in Table 1. The last column of Table 1 addresses the contagion check. “No” and “Contained”Footnote 8 indicate avoidance of contagion. “Additional check required” indicates that a further check is needed to determine contagion.

Table 1 Contagion dynamics table

Remark 7

Handling the contagion test via classification. As noted in Table 1, there is a one-to-one relationship between causal volatility and structural breaks for S-1 to S-4 (i.e., it contains no UND), while there is no such one-to-one relationship for S-5 to S-8 (i.e., it contains UNDs).Footnote 9 S-1 covers a normal MIH or a “fully integrated market.” S-2 and S-3 handle the contagion bias from correlatedness break (CRB) or long-term break (LB), which were addressed by Forbes and Rigobon (2002). S-4 handles bias from a short-term break (SB), which is related to Favero and Giavazzi (2002), who employed a nonlinearity technique to detect a short-term effect in its opposite direction to observe “flight to quality” (p.241). S-5 contains contagion by exclusively keeping \(\frac{{{\uptheta }_{{\text{y}}} }}{{{\uptheta }_{{\text{x}}} }} \left( {MSR} \right);\) hence, it might be considered to handle contagion bias from a long-term break (LB) and correlatedness break (CRB) simultaneously. S-5 is unlikely to occur in reality, as LB and CRB occur simultaneously with no short-term break (NSB). S-6, S-7, and S-8 are concerned with the possible bias from the SB, as noted in S-4. In these cases, further checks are necessary to identify contagion, as SB, CRB, SB, and LB occur simultaneously.

Remark 8

S2–S5 in an economic or financial context. According to Forbes and Rigobon (2002), CRB may be explained by aggregate or global shocks that simultaneously affect the fundamentals of several economies. For instance, a rise in the international interest rate, a contraction in the supply of international capital, or a decline in demand for international capital could simultaneously slow down economic growth in a number of countries. LB may be explained by how a shock to one country could affect the fundamentals in other countries. This case could work through a number of real linkages, such as trade or policy coordination. Trade could link economies, as a devaluation in one country would increase the competitiveness of that country’s goods, potentially decreasing the competitiveness of other countries. This could have a direct effect on a country’s sales and output and, if the loss in competitiveness is severe enough, increase expectations of exchange rate devaluation and/or lead to an attack on the country’s currency. In these cases, well-defined types of LB or CRB are handled, making it less difficult to handle contagion.

Remark 9

S6–S8 in an economic or financial context. These cases refer to any increased market comovement that cannot be explained by the S2–S5 cases. Masson (1998) presented a theory of multiple equilibria, which shows that a crisis in one country can be used as a sunspot for another. The shift from a good to a bad equilibrium is driven by a change in investor expectations rather than real linkages. Theories explaining contagion are based on multiple equilibria, capital market liquidity, investor psychology, and political economy. Valdés (2000) developed a model based on capital market liquidity and argued that a crisis in one country can cause a liquidity shock to market participants. This could force portfolio recomposition and drive a sell-off of certain asset classes, which would lower asset prices in countries not affected by the initial crisis. Mullainathan (2002) focused on investor psychology and argued that investors recall past events imperfectly. A crisis in one country could trigger memories of past crises, which would cause investors to recompute their priors regarding variables such as debt default and assign a higher probability to a bad state. The resulting downward comovement in prices would occur because memories rather than fundamentals are correlated. Drazen (2000) proposed that political economy can drive price comovements, such as during the European devaluations of 1993. For instance, if political pressure drives central bank presidents to maintain an existing exchange rate regime, when one country abandons its regime, the political costs of other countries would be reduced, changing their regime. This effect could generate bunching in the timing of the economic policy shifts. In these cases, relatively more complicated types of LB or CRB are handled; hence, it would be rather difficult to handle contagion.

Identifying contagion using a Bayesian approach

The change in the short-term effect \(\beta_{L0} = \frac{{\theta_{y} }}{{\theta_{x} }}\) (or the MSR) is further checked to determine whether it is the main force behind a break in the long-term effect or correlatedness (LB or CRB). The Bayesian approach was used to calculate the related posterior probabilities. Following the definition of contagion, its occurrence can be investigated by calculating the posterior probabilities of P \(\left( {SB{|}LB} \right) or P\left( {SB{|}CRB} \right).\) The posterior probability of P \(\left( {SB{|}LB} \right)\) (\({\text{P}}\left( {SB{|}CRB} \right)\)) is interpreted as the probability that LB (CRB) is caused by SB when LB (CRB) is given or as the ratio of SB to LB (CRB). For S-1, S-2, S-3, and S-5, P \(\left( {SB{|}LB} \right) = P\left( {SB{|}CRB} \right) = 0\), as they belong to NSB. For S-4, P \(\left( {SB{|}LB} \right) = P\left( {SB{|}CRB} \right) = 0,\) as it belongs to the NLB and NCRB simultaneously. Thus, either no or contained contagion was reported for S-1 to S-5.

For S-6, \({\text{P}}\left( {\text{SB|CRB}} \right) > 0\) must be calculated, which belongs to SB and CRB. As the correlatedness \(\beta_{L2} = \frac{{\theta_{y} \left( {1 - \eta_{x} } \right)}}{{\theta_{x} }}\) consists of independent multiplication components of \(\frac{{\theta_{y} }}{{\theta_{x} }}\) and \(\left( {1 - {\upeta }_{{\text{x}}} } \right)\), an additional check is necessary to decide whether CRB is mainly due to the change in \(\frac{{\theta_{y} }}{{\theta_{x} }}\) or in \(\left( {1 - {\upeta }_{{\text{x}}} } \right)\). The posterior probability CRB caused by changes in \(\frac{{\theta_{y} }}{{\theta_{x} }}\) (or SB) is calculated as \({\text{P}}\left( {SB{|}CRB} \right) = \frac{{P\left( {SB} \right)P\left( {CRB{|}SB} \right)}}{{P\left( {CRB} \right)}}\). For S-7, \({\text{P}}\left( {\text{SB|LB}} \right) > 0\) must be calculated, which belongs to SB and LB. As the long-term effect \(\gamma_{{\text{L}}} = \frac{{\theta_{y} \left( {1 - \eta_{x} } \right)}}{{\theta_{x} \left( {1 - \eta_{y} } \right)}}\) consists of independent multiplication components of \(\frac{{\theta_{y} }}{{\theta_{x} }}\) and \(\frac{{\left( {1 - \eta_{x} } \right)}}{{\left( {1 - \eta_{y} } \right)}}\), an additional check is required to determine whether LB is mainly due to the change in \(\frac{{\theta_{y} }}{{\theta_{x} }}\) or in \(\frac{{\left( {1 - \eta_{x} } \right)}}{{\left( {1 - \eta_{y} } \right)}}\). The posterior probability that LB is caused by changes in \(\frac{{\theta_{y} }}{{\theta_{x} }}\) (or SB) is calculated as \({\text{P}}\left( {SB{|}LB} \right) = \frac{{P\left( {SB} \right)P\left( {LB{|}SB} \right)}}{{P\left( {LB} \right)}}\). For S-8, it must be further verified that LB or CRB is due to the change in \(\frac{{\theta_{y} }}{{\theta_{x} }}\) (or SB) by calculating the posterior probabilities of P \(\left( {SB{|}LB} \right) {\text{and}} P\left( {SB{|}CRB} \right)\).

The present contagion test procedure is summarized as follows:

  1. (i)

    Assume Eq. 3 for target market Y and source market X,

    $$\begin{aligned} \Delta Y_{t} & = \frac{{\theta_{y} }}{{\theta_{x} }}\Delta X_{t} - \left( {1 - \eta_{y} } \right)\left( {Y_{t - 1} - \frac{{\theta_{y} \left( {1 - \eta_{x} } \right)}}{{\theta_{x} \left( {1 - \eta_{y} } \right)}}X_{t - 1} } \right) + \varepsilon_{Lt} \\ & = \beta_{L0} \Delta X_{t} + \beta_{L1} \left( {Y_{t - 1} - \gamma_{L} X_{t - 1} } \right) + \varepsilon_{1t} = \beta_{L0} \Delta X_{t} + \beta_{L1} Y_{t - 1} + \beta_{L2} X_{t - 1} + \varepsilon_{Lt} \\ \end{aligned}$$
  2. (ii)

    Establish null hypotheses for coefficients in the \(\frac{k}{N + 1}{\text{th}}\) quantile that correspond to the crisis period across fixed N quantiles: \(H_{0}^{SB} \;{\text{versus}}\; H_{1}^{SB}\)(short-term break), \(H_{0}^{LB} \;{\text{versus}}\;H_{1}^{LB}\)(long-term break), and \(H_{0}^{CRB} \;{\text{versus}}\; H_{1}^{CRB}\) (correlatedness break).

  3. (iii)

    Apply the Z-test given by Eq. 9 with selected \(k\) for \({ }(\beta_{{{\text{L}}0}} ,\gamma_{{\text{L}}} ,\beta_{{{\text{L}}2}} )\).

  4. (iv)

    Using the test results from step (iii) and Table 1, complete the Bayesian test by calculating the posterior probabilities of P(SBLB) and P(SBCRB). If the posterior probability is greater than a specified value \(\theta_{0}\), contagion is declared.

To calculate the posterior probabilities of \(P\left( {SB{|}LB} \right) and P\left( {SB{|}CRB} \right),{ }\) the p values from step (iii) of the contagion test process were used to estimate the related probabilities. Recalling that the p value is the probability under \({\text{H}}_{0}\), to obtain a result equal to or greater than what was observed, p values from testing \(H_{0}^{SB} , H_{0}^{LB}\) and \(H_{0}^{CRB}\) were used as estimates of \(P\left( {SB} \right), P\left( {{\text{L}}B} \right), {\text{and}} P\left( {{\text{CR}}B} \right)\), respectively. In addition, \({\hat{\text{P}}}\left( {{\text{L}}B{|}SB} \right)\) and \({\hat{\text{P}}}\left( {{\text{CR}}B{|}SB} \right)\) could be estimated from the given testing results (Appendix 8, Eqs. 12 and 13).

Empirical results and discussion

Dynamic analysis of the GFC among developed markets

This study examined the dynamic transmission of the GFC to 22 developed equity markets between 2007 and 2009 using the analytical Bayesian approach developed above.

Data

Data from the Thompson Reuters DataStream were used, which provided equity market indices for most countries. Using the U.S. financial market as the origin of the GFC, 22 developed markets were examined (see Appendix 9 for equity market indices by country and DataStream code). These countries were selected based on the developed market lists provided by Dow Jones, the FTSE Group, MSCI, Russell, and S&P. These data providers classify the market status of countries as “developed” or “emerging” based on their economic size, wealth, and the quality, depth, and breadth of their markets. This study selected countries included in all the developed market lists provided by these data providers.Footnote 10 The data consisted of the daily prices of the aggregate stock indices. This study used a 2-day moving average return to overcome the issue posed by geographical time differences in the analysis of the U.S. financial contagion to other countries (Forbes and Rigobon 2002). The sample period, spanning approximately 6 years, from January 2004 to October 2009, focused on the GFC (2007–2009). The crisis began in the U.S. subprime mortgage market in 2007 and led to sharp declines in equity markets worldwide, affecting both developed and emerging markets (Aloui et al. 2011; Dungey and Gajurel 2014; Frank and Hesse 2009; Horta et al. 2010; Hwang et al. 2013; Kenourgios et al. 2011; Samarakoon 2011). As the purpose of this study was to examine the spread of the U.S. financial crisis to developed countries during the GFC, this study did not consider data from November 2009 onwards, when Greece revealed that its budget deficit was more than twice the value it previously disclosed, which signaled the beginning of the European sovereign debt crisis. Including data from November 2009 onward may lead to unexpected results owing to the effect of the European sovereign debt crisis. Thus, the sample period was ended in October 2009 to alleviate the possible noise from other financial market crises. Following the crisis related to the bankruptcy of WorldCom in June 2002, no significant financial crisis was reported until the beginning of the subprime crisis in the U.S. Therefore, this sample period, which began in January 2004 and continued through October 2009, covered an extended period of tranquility followed by the GFC. The sample included 1522 daily observations. According to Brière et al. (2012), it is difficult to identify precise dates that correspond to a crisis, and previous studies on financial contagion during the GFC have used slightly different crisis periods. To identify the crisis period, this study selected observation dates included within most crisis periods considered in previous studies on the GFC. This study assumed that the crisis period began on August 1, 2007 and continued until March 31, 2009. Table 2 reports the summary statistics of the aggregate stock market indices’ daily returns for developed markets during the crisis and tranquil periods. Compared with the tranquil period, the crisis period had smaller mean returns (− 0.0015 vs. 0.0010) and greater variation (0.0225 vs. 0.0099).

Table 2 Descriptive statistics of aggregate stock market indices

Country-wise contagion analysis of the GFC spread

To explore the dynamic spread of the GFC from U.S. aggregate equity market returns to developed equity market returns, this study utilized the daily returns reported by the DataStream equity index for each country. Each country’s equity market index returns were treated as the outcome variable and U.S. equity market returns as a predictor in the SEECM in Eq. 4.Footnote 11 To implement the test procedure, it was observed that the crisis period belonged to the 5th quantile (Appendix 10); hence, \(k = 1, N = 19\) in the test procedure.

Next, the SEECM was estimated at 5% increments, from the 5th to 95th quantiles, via quantile regression for 22 developed markets. Given the estimates of the quantile regression parameters across the entire range of quantiles of each country’s equity market returns, this study tested whether the crisis period at the 5th quantile experiences short-term (MSR, \(\beta_{L0} ),\) long-term (\({\upgamma }_{L}\)), or correlatedness (\(\beta_{L2} )\) breaks from the aggregate U.S. equity market owing to excess and significant shocks. Table 3 reports the Z-test statistics with the corresponding p values in parentheses for \(\hat{\beta }_{L0}\), \(\hat{\gamma }_{L}\), and \(\hat{\beta }_{L2}\) for the 22 developed countries. Their standard errors were computed using the Markov chain marginal bootstrap resampling method, which is robust to data that are not iid (He and Hu 2002). This study posited hypotheses \(H_{0}^{SB}\) versus \(H_{1}^{SB}\) to test \(\beta_{L0}\), \(H_{0}^{LB}\) versus \(H_{1}^{LB}\) to test \({\upgamma }_{L}\), and \(H_{0}^{CRB}\) versus \(H_{1}^{CRB}\) to test \(\beta_{L2}\) with \(k = 1\) and \(N = 19\).

Table 3 Results of testing breaks in market structure and aggregate equity contagion

According to the S-classifications in Table 1, Figs. 2, 3, 4, 5, 6, 7 and 8 present plots of \(\hat{\beta }_{L0}\), \(\hat{\gamma }_{L}\), and \(\hat{\beta }_{{{\text{L}}2}} { }\) across the entire range of quantiles for the markets. The U.S. equity market returns had positive short- and long-term effects on the selected developed market returns (\(\hat{\beta }_{L0} > 0, \hat{\gamma }_{L} > 0\)) and converge to equilibrium (\(- 1 < \hat{\beta }_{{{\text{L}}1}} < 0\)). Blue, red, and green lines indicate \(\hat{\beta }_{L0}\) (short-term, MSR), \(\hat{\gamma }_{{\text{L}}}\)(long term), and \(\hat{\beta }_{{{\text{L}}2}}\)(correlatedness), respectively. Before discussing the test results by country, it should be mentioned that \(\eta_{x} = \eta_{y} = \eta_{0}\) under MIH holds for a specific value of \(\eta_{0}\) (say, \(\eta_{j0} )\) for the jth pair of a selected country and the U.S. market. Each market had a unique factor common with the U.S. market; hence, the market-specific risk of the U.S. market \(\left( {\eta_{x} } \right)\) showed a different value depending on the selected market, namely, \(\eta_{x} = \eta_{y} = \eta_{j0}\) under the MIH for the jth pair of a selected country and the U.S. market.

Fig. 2
figure 2

Estimated parameters by quantile for S-1 markets (no break)

Fig. 3
figure 3

Estimated parameters by quantile for S-2 markets (CRB)

Fig. 4
figure 4

Estimated parameters by quantile for S-3 markets (LB)

Fig. 5
figure 5

Estimated parameters by quantile for S-4 markets (SB)

Fig. 6
figure 6

Estimated parameters by quantile for S-6 markets (SB and CRB)

Fig. 7
figure 7

Estimated parameters by quantile for S-7 markets (SB and LB)

Fig. 8
figure 8

Estimated parameters by quantile for S-8 countries (all breaks)

S-1 markets Austria, Finland, Singapore, and Switzerland maintained established short-and long-term relationships and correlatedness with the U.S. market. According to the S-1 classification rule in Table 1, no contagion was reported. Figure 2 might serve as an example of markets escaping contagion. Overall, it shows that at the 5th quantile, the long-term effect (red lines), correlatedness (green lines), and short-term effect (blue lines) tended to show a decrease, that is, slowdown in comovement and MSR at the 5th quantile.

S-2 markets The equity market returns for Germany and Sweden can be categorized as S-2. These markets suffered from a correlatedness break without short- or long-term breaks during crisis periods. According to the S-2 classification rule in Table 1, firms escape contagion by effectively containing volatility spillovers. Figure 3shows that at the 5th quantile, the long-term (red lines) and short-term effects (blue lines) tended to decrease (i.e., slowdown in comovement and MSR).

S-3 markets The test results for Canada, Israel, and Norway showed no breaks in the short-term and correlatedness and break in the long-term. According to the S-3 classification rule in Table 1, they escaped contagion by keeping the short-term effect unchanged. As shown in Fig. 4, the long-term effect for these markets at the 5th quantile increases compared with the other periods. Other than Israel, Fig. 4 shows that at the 5th quantile correlatedness (green lines) and short-term effect (blue lines) tended to show decreases (slowdown in comovement and MSR). For Israel, the short-term effects and correlatedness were as low as 0.4–0.5, although they suffer from a small increase.

S-4 markets The equity market in Japan was classified as S-4, as it suffered from a short-term break without long-term and correlatedness breaks. As shown in Fig. 5, the shock appeared to increase the short-term effect. According to the S-4 classification rule in Table 1, Japan escapes contagion by maintaining a longer-term equilibrating mechanism. In Japan, the short-term effect (MSR) was as low as 0.3, although it suffers from a small increase.

For the S-6, S-7, and S-8 cases below, the posterior probabilities were estimated to determine contagion, as described in Appendix 8. To obtain the posterior probability, this study estimated the related probabilities using the p values given in Table 3. For instance, Hong Kong had a posterior probability of

$${\hat{\text{P}}}_{0} \left( {SB{|}CRB} \right) = \frac{{{\hat{\text{P}}}\left( {SB} \right){\hat{\text{P}}}\left( {CRB{|}SB} \right)}}{{{\hat{\text{P}}}\left( {CRB} \right)}} = \frac{{0.0297 \times \frac{7}{13}}}{0.0344} = 0.4649,$$

where \({\hat{\text{P}}}\left( {SB} \right)\) and \({\hat{\text{P}}}\left( {{\text{CR}}B} \right)\) were p values for testing short-term and correlatedness break, respectively, in Table 3, and \({\hat{\text{P}}}\left( {CRB{|}SB} \right) = 7/13\) was estimated from Table 3 (i.e., given the 13 SB markets, seven countries show CRB). Thus, the posterior probability that CRB was caused by SB in Hong Kong was estimated as \({\hat{\text{P}}}\left( {SB{|}CRB} \right) =\) \({\text{min}}\left( {\frac{{0.0297 \times \frac{7}{13}}}{0.0344},1} \right) = 0.4649\) using Eq. 13 of Appendix 8.

S-6 markets The Hong Kong and Irish markets were classified as S-6. The shock affected the short-term effect and correlatedness, while the long-term effect during the crisis period was maintained. According to the classification rule of S-6 and Eq. 13, the posterior probabilities that CRB was caused by SB for Hong Kong and Ireland were estimated as follows:

$${\text{Hong Kong:}}\;{\hat{\text{P}}}\left( {SB{|}CRB} \right) = {\text{min}}\left( {\frac{{0.0297 \times \frac{7}{13}}}{0.0344},1} \right) = 0.4649$$
$${\text{Ireland:}}\;{\hat{\text{P}}}\left( {SB{|}CRB} \right) = {\text{min }}\left( {\frac{{0.0011 \times \frac{7}{13}}}{0.0001}, 1} \right) = 1$$

For the Hong Kong market, the posterior probability that CRB was caused by SB was relatively low (less than 0.5), indicating that CRB was mainly caused by a change in the market-specific volatility of X (\(\eta_{x}\)). On the other hand, the Irish market revealed \({\hat{\text{P}}}\left( {SB{|}IB} \right)\) = 1; in other words, the CRB was caused by SB. Therefore, according to the S-6 classification rule in Table 1, the Hong Kong market appears to have barely escaped contagion by properly containing the break in the short-term effect, while the Irish market appears to have failed to escape contagion. Notice from Fig. 6that the short-term effect (MSR) and correlatedness (comovement) increased at the 5th quantile; however, Hong Kong had less correlatedness increase than Ireland. Clarke and Hardiman (2012) reported that a number of Irish financial institutions faced imminent collapse during the GFC, and the Irish government instigated a €63 billion bank bailout.

S-7 markets The markets in Australia, Belgium, Italy, the Netherlands, and the UK were categorized as S-7. They suffered from short- and long-term breaks but maintained correlatedness with the U.S. market during the crisis period. Using the S-7 classification rule of Table 1 and Eq. 12 of Appendix 8, the posterior probabilities that LB was caused by SB for these countries were calculated as follows:

Australia: \({\hat{\text{P}}}\left( {SB{|}LB} \right) = {\text{min}}\left( {\frac{{0.0059 \times \frac{10}{{13}}}}{0.0159},1} \right) = 0.2854\).

Belgium: \({\hat{\text{P}}}\left( {SB{|}LB} \right) = {\text{min}}\left( {\frac{{0.0116 \times \frac{10}{{13}}}}{0.0075}, 1} \right) = 1\).

Italy: \({\hat{\text{P}}}\left( {SB{|}LB} \right) = {\text{min}}\left( {\frac{{0.0206 \times \frac{10}{{13}}}}{0.0346},1} \right) = 0.4580\).

Netherlands: \({\hat{\text{P}}}\left( {SB{|}LB} \right) = {\text{min}}\left( {\frac{{0.0010 \times \frac{10}{{13}}}}{0.0014},1} \right) = 0.5495\).

UK: \({\hat{\text{P}}}\left( {SB{|}LB} \right) = {\text{min}}\left( {\frac{{0.0001 \times \frac{10}{{13}}}}{0.0411},1} \right) = 0.0019\).

\({\hat{\text{P}}}\left( {LB{|}SB} \right) = 10/13\) was calculated using Table 3. Indeed, ten countries showed LB, given the 13 SB markets. From the posterior probabilities above, the LB of markets in Belgium and the Netherlands were mainly caused by SB; hence, they appear to have suffered from contagion (\({\hat{\text{P}}}\left( {SB{|}LB} \right) > 0.5\)). According to the S-7 classification rule in Table 1, Australia, Italy, and the UK escaped contagion by containing a break in the short-term effect. Notice from Fig. 7that both the long-term (comovement) and short-term effects (MSR) increased at the 5th quantile for Belgium and the Netherlands.

The National Bank of Belgium (2017) reported that the 2008–2009 Belgian financial crisis was caused by two of Belgian’s largest banks, Fortis and Dexia, and was exacerbated by the GFC. Masselink and van den Noord (2009) also stated that the negative effects of the financial crisis became more apparent and economic growth came to a grinding halt in the Netherlands in the second quarter of 2008. Such a large contraction was driven not only by the strong fall in world trade but also by negative developments in domestic demand associated with an adverse wealth shock. Specifically, typical Dutch strengths, such as the country’s funded pension system and strong position in world trade, turned out to be vulnerabilities in the wake of the crisis and negatively impacted consumption and investment. This appears to have noticeably increased the long-term effect at 5th quantile for the Netherlands.

S-8 markets Denmark, France, New Zealand, Portugal, and Spain appear to have suffered from all types of breaks (SB, LB, and CRB) during the crisis period. These results correspond to those for S-8. As seen in Fig. 8, the shock directly increased the short- and long-term effects and correlatedness between markets during the crisis period; hence, the posterior probabilities were calculated for these markets using the classification rule of S-8. \({\hat{\text{P}}}\left( {SB{|}LB} \right)\) and \({\hat{\text{P}}}\left( {SB{|}CRB} \right)\) for these countries were calculated using Eqs. 12 and 13 presented in Appendix 8, as follows:

Denmark:

$${\hat{\text{P}}}\left( {SB{|}LB} \right) = {\text{min}}\left( {\frac{{0.0001 \times \frac{10}{{13}}}}{0.0001},1} \right) = 0.7692,\;{\hat{\text{P}}}\left( {SB{|}CRB} \right) = {\text{min}}\left( {\frac{{0.0001 \times \frac{7}{13}}}{0.0333},1} \right) = 0.0016$$

France:

$${\hat{\text{P}}}\left( {SB{|}LB} \right) = {\text{min}}\left( {\frac{{0.0002 \times \frac{10}{{13}}}}{0.0119}, 1} \right) = 0.0129,\;{\hat{\text{P}}}\left( {SB{|}CRB} \right) = {\text{min}}\left( {\frac{{0.0002 \times \frac{7}{13}}}{0.0489},1} \right) = 0.0022$$

New Zealand:

$${\hat{\text{P}}}\left( {SB{|}LB} \right) = {\text{min}}\left( {\frac{{0.0058 \times \frac{10}{{13}}}}{0.0114},1} \right) = 0.3914,\;{\hat{\text{P}}}\left( {SB{|}CRB} \right) = {\text{min}}\left( {\frac{{0.0058 \times \frac{7}{13}}}{0.0001},1} \right) = 1$$

Portugal:

$${\hat{\text{P}}}\left( {SB{|}LB} \right) = {\text{min}}\left( {\frac{{0.0001 \times \frac{10}{{13}}}}{0.0012},1} \right) = 0.0641,\;{\hat{\text{P}}}\left( {SB{|}CRB} \right) = {\text{min}}\left( {\frac{{0.0001 \times \frac{7}{13}}}{0.0001},1} \right) = 0.5385$$

Spain:

$${\hat{\text{P}}}\left( {SB{|}LB} \right) = {\text{min}}\left( {\frac{{0.0012 \times \frac{10}{{13}}}}{0.0001},1} \right) = 1,\;{\hat{\text{P}}}\left( {SB{|}CRB} \right) = {\text{min}}\left( {\frac{{0.0012 \times \frac{7}{13}}}{0.0008},1} \right) = 0.8077$$

Based on the posterior probabilities above, the LB or CRB of markets in Denmark, New Zealand, Portugal, and Spain were mainly caused by SB; hence, they appear to have suffer from contagion (\({\hat{\text{P}}}\left( {SB{|}LB} \right) > 0.5\) or \({\hat{\text{P}}}\left( {SB{|}CRB} \right) > 0.5\)). By contrast, France was found to have escaped contagion by properly containing a break in the long-term effect. Notice a sudden long-term effect decrease for France and increases in all three parameters for the other countries at the 5th quantile (see Fig. 8). Note that the short-term effect was MSR and the long-term effect or correlatedness was comovement.

GFC contagion was reported in Denmark, New Zealand, Portugal, and Spain. The financial crisis in Denmark started in the summer of 2008 with the collapse of the Roskilde Bank, and Denmark experienced a systemic financial crisis in the banking sector until 2010 (Kickert 2013). Several studies have reported significant effects of the GFC on the New Zealand economy (Murphy 2011; Spencer 2012). It has also been reported that the international recession hit Portugal in 2008, and eventually, the country was unable to repay or refine its government debt without the assistance of third parties (Pereira and Wemans 2012). The Great Spanish Depression began in 2008, and Spain was unable to bail out its financial sector; therefore, it had to apply for a €100 billion rescue package under the European Stability Mechanism. Of all European countries, Spain was affected the worst by the GFC (Worldview Report 2009). Although the French financial system also suffered contagion effects from the GFC, it recovered resiliently owing to regulations limiting banks’ debt exposure (Xiao 2009).

These empirical results can be compared with those of Bekeart et al. (2014), in which GFC transmission to 415 country-industry equity portfolios was examined using a factor model. The empirical results of equity market contagion for some countries in Bekeart et al. (2014) reported similar findings as the present results. In sum, the empirical contagion studies of developed markets during crisis presented here indicated that long-term effect, correlatedness, and short-term effect should be decreased to properly contain contagion. During a financial crisis, comovement and MSR determine the behavior of stock returns and residual series. MSR is closely related to liquidity and the possibility of downside risks.

Other contagion cases in the literatures

The literature contains contagion case studies outside those in developed countries. By employing the volatility impulse response function (VIRF) approach, Jin and An (2016) addressed the extent to which the effects of contagion occurred between the BRIC (Brazil, Russia, India, China) and the U.S. stock markets and demonstrated how the BRIC stock markets were influenced in the context of the 2007–2009 GFC. Their discussion on the extent and influence of contagion could be made more precise by finding the corresponding S-classification category, as presented in Table 3. Dimitriou et al. (2013) examined the U.S. and BRIC markets and found that decoupling was indicated in the early stages of the crisis; however, linkages reemerged after the collapse of Lehman Brothers. Their findings suggested that BRIC might belong to S-4 of Table 1 (SB, NLB, NCRB) and escape contagion. Luchtenberg and Vu (2015) demonstrated that economic fundamentals, such as trade structure, interest rates, inflation rates, industrial production, regional effects, and investors’ risk aversion, contributed to international contagion, including emerging markets. Such economic fundamentals were included in the common factor \(W_{t}\) or the market-specific factor \(u_{x, t}\) in the present LFM.

Chiang et al. (2007) used the dynamic conditional correlation (DCC) model developed by Engle (2002) to examine the Asian crisis and found that in the early stage of contagion, there was a negative correlation, which was followed by herding behavior that dominated the latter stages of the crisis. A negative correlation at the early stage of contagion indicated NSB, and herding behavior in the later stages of the crisis indicated possible LB or CRB.

Investigating the entire group of emerging markets via the present approach is beyond the scope of this study, as it requires a technically more cautious approach than the developed markets of this study, necessitating regressions at different quantiles from the 5th quantile for each country.

Summary and policy implications

Figure 9 summarizes the test results presented in Table 3. It shows four S-1, five S-7, and five S-8 markets but no S-5 market. The low frequency of S-5 is consistent with Remark 7: long-term and correlatedness breaks hardly occur without a short-term break.

Fig. 9
figure 9

Classifications of the test results from Table 3. This figure shows the number of developed markets in the S class. The figures in parenthesis denote the number of markets that have suffered contagion

More detailed probabilistic contagion assessments are possible by counting the relative frequencies of contagion in each scenario presented in Fig. 9. The contagion odds for markets that experienced SB, LB, or CRB were calculated by estimating the cardinality in relation to each case. For instance, the contagion odds for markets that experienced SB (or SB exclusively) equaled the number of markets with contagion in SB (or SB exclusively) divided by the total number of markets in SB (or SB exclusively). Table 4 reports the contagion odds for the developed markets in various scenarios.

Table 4 The contagion odds

The contagion odds in each cell served as the conditional probability of contagion given market experience. Examining the odds for markets that experience SB, LB, CRB, and their combinations exclusively, indicated within parentheses, revealed that (1) a developed market escaped contagion unless it suffered from SB and LB, SB and CRB, and SB, LB, and CRB exclusively, and (2) a single exclusive break did not cause any contagion regardless of SB, LB, or CRB. These empirical results, presented in Table 4, provided useful implications for policies against market contagion.

When a source market is hit by a significant shock, policymakers of a target market should carefully monitor the short-term effect (\(\hat{\beta }_{{{\text{L}}0}}\), MSR) between their market and source market. Monitoring could be done by checking changes in the target market’s relative speed to the source market in the model. When the short-term effect appears to break (probably increase), it must be recognized as a warning sign that contagion is highly possible. Decision-makers should observe the long-term effect (\(\hat{\gamma }_{L}\)) and correlatedness (\(\hat{\beta }_{L2}\)), classify them into one of the S-types, and establish an economic policy that checks the short-term effect (MSR). As a short-term effect \(\left( {\frac{{{\uptheta }_{{\text{y}}} }}{{{\uptheta }_{{\text{x}}} }}, MSR} \right)\) is determined by the common factor \({\text{W}}_{{\text{t}}}\) in Eq. 11, the target market can escape contagion by implementing a proper economic plan that influences MSR directly via \({\uptheta }_{{\text{y}}}\), such as adjusting liquidity or providing more information. Target market Y in S-4, S-6, and S-7 appears to contain breaks in short-term effect properly via \({\uptheta }_{{\text{y}}}\) when it escapes contagion with no break in the long-term effect or correlatedness. Finally, S-8 for some target market Y may occasionally be interpreted as a successful recovery from contagion, in which market Y successfully establishes a new sound relationship with market X by restructuring all ties to market X (or via SB, LB, and CRB; see the test results for France S-8).

Conclusions

The literature indicates that contagion tests suffer from various biases, such as the “interdependence, not contagion issue” noted by Forbes and Rigobon (2002, p.2251). Numerous studies have been performed to remove confounding effects or contagion biases from comovement in excess. Solutions have been developed using various models. This study structurally resolved these difficulties by linking LFM and SEECM and applying the Bayesian approach, which determines the identification of the breaks in long-term relationship or correlatedness (or comovement). In addition, the present contagion test defined contagion as a long-term or correlatedness break (or comovement break) mainly caused by a short-term break (or MSR change). Furthermore, this test is easy to implement.

Employing the Bayesian approach, this study successfully addressed various episodes of market contagion. The results revealed the key contagion parameters to be monitored in time-varying situations: contagion odds, short-term effects, long-term effects, and correlatedness. Figures 2, 3, 4, 5, 6, 7 and 8 strongly suggest that the significant increases in these parameters should be handled with caution. The results presented in Fig. 9 and Table 4 help predict contagion odds in time varying situations. In addition, these results should allow policymakers to develop alternative economic safeguards against contagion via MSR, which depends on liquidity or the possibility of downside risk. Future studies should apply this approach to emerging markets, including the BRIC, during the GFC.