Background

Two forms of market power along food market chain that have received significant attention are wholesalers’/processors’ buyer power in agricultural procurement and retailers’ seller power in food retailing. These two forms of market power have important implications for agricultural producers and consumers. In agricultural procurement, many US industries, such as livestock, dairy, soybeans, poultry, and seed, have become more and more concentrated in the recent decades. For example, the four-firm concentration ratio (CR4) in beef packing increased from 36% in 1980 to 85% in 2015 (U.S. Department of Agriculture, Grain Inspection Packers and Stockyards Administration 2016), and the national CR4 of fluid milk processing grew from 16% in 1982 to 43% in 2002 (U.S. Department of Agriculture, Economic Research Service 2007). This increasing concentration has made producers, policymakers, and academic researchers to be concerned about the anticompetitive effects of potential buyer power in agricultural procurement on farm price and producer welfare. Academic studies and government reports have focused on concentration and buyer power issues. Buyer power has been analyzed in the markets of many agricultural and food products including wheat (Stiegert and Hamilton 1998), cattle (Azzam and Anderson 1996; McEowen et al. 2002; Ward 2002), hogs (Zheng and Vukina 2009), milk (Alvarez et al. 2000), cocoa (Wilcox and Abbott 2006), tobacco (Raper et al. 2000), and tomatoes (Durham and Sexton 1992; Huang and Sexton 1996).

Another form of market power is seller power in food retailing. In food retail markets, given the increasing concentration, spatial distribution of consumers and stores, and store differentiation, food retailers may be able to use seller market power to influence prices charged to consumers. The national CR4 in food retailing increased from 16.8% in 1992 to 37.3% in 2011, and the average local CR4 in metropolitan areas was 72.3% in 2007 (U.S. Department of Agriculture, Economic Research Service 2007; 2012). Spatial distribution of consumers and retail stores allows a store to have market power over the consumers in vicinity (Benson and Faminow 1985; Walden 1990; Azzam 1999). Differentiated pricing and marketing strategies adopted by retailers may also improve their ability to influence retail prices (Varian 1980; Lal and Rao 1997; Pesendorfer 2002; Sexton et al. 2003; Boatwright et al. 2004; Hosken and Reiffen 2004; Davis 2010; Volpe 2013). Market power and structure issues in agricultural procurement and food retailing in other countries are also examined and discussed in studies such as Declerck et al. (1999) on French beef industry, Farina et al. (2004) on Brazilian supermarket chains, Lloyd et al. (2009) on the UK food sector, and Digal (2010) on the Philippine poultry industry.

In 2010, the Antitrust Division of the US Department of Justice and the US Department of Agriculture held the first-ever joint public workshops on competition issues in the agricultural sector including the two forms of market power: buyer power in agricultural procurement and seller power in food retailing. A report on the workshops issued by the US Department of Justice indicates that “These discussions (from the workshops) confirmed that a healthy agricultural sector requires competition and, consequently, vigorous anti-trust enforcement.” and says the workshops resulted in “an enhanced understanding of agricultural markets” and “a greater appreciation of how anticompetitive practices in these markets can harm producers and consumers.” (U.S. Department of Justice 2012, p. 2).

In the model we develop in this study, when buyer power in agricultural procurement and seller power in food retailing coexist, the welfare gain to farmers or consumers through addressing one form of market power is usually reduced by the other form of market power in the supply chain. This observation suggests that tackling both forms of market power at the same time can be more effective for promoting competition and providing benefits to farmers and consumers. However, how should a policymaker optimally allocate anti-trust efforts between farm and retail markets in order to maximize welfare? When the policy objective is to maximize farmer welfare, should all or most anti-trust efforts be put in addressing market power issues in farm markets? Or a more general question is, for different policy objectives such as to maximize farmer welfare only, consumer welfare only, or total social welfare, should a policymaker adopt different optimal allocations of anti-trust efforts or use the same allocation? What factors and how do they affect the optimal allocation of anti-trust efforts across markets along the supply chain? The answers to these questions would be very helpful for policymakers to take effective actions against anticompetitive behaviors in the agricultural sector and improve the understanding on the optimal allocation of anti-trust efforts along the food market chain.

Some previous research has included market power in two stages, buyer power in agricultural procurement and seller power in finished product sales, in an integrated economic framework (Schroeter 1988; Azzam and Pagoulatos 1990; Alston et al. 1997; Sexton 2000).Footnote 1 But all those studies focus on different issues such as price distortions and impact on research benefits. Another related literature in economics is the one on double marginalization (Spengler 1950; Tirole 1988; Katz 1989), which analyzes sequential oligopoly/seller power (or sequential oligopsony/buyer power) in the upstream and downstream market. The vertical structure examined in this paper along the food market chain is a different one, where there is buyer power in the upstream (agricultural procurement) and seller power in the downstream (food retailing). No published research has examined (1) how a policymaker should optimally allocate anti-trust efforts between farm and retail markets under different policy objectives and (2) what factors and how they affect the optimal allocation of anti-trust efforts across markets along the supply chain.

In this paper, we use a simple framework to show that, even if the policy objective is to maximize farmer welfare only, anti-trust efforts may need to be allocated to both farm and retail markets. More importantly, the same optimal allocation of anti-trust efforts among markets should be used for these three different policy objectives: (i) to maximize farmer welfare, (ii) to maximize consumer welfare, and (iii) to maximize social welfare. The economic intuition is that reducing market power through anti-trust efforts in one market will also benefit the market participants in other markets so that a policymaker always allocates anti-trust efforts to make sure that the marginal gain in welfare due to putting anti-trust efforts in one market is equal to the marginal gain due to putting the efforts in another market, regardless of whether the objective is to maximize the welfare of farmers only, consumers only, or the entire society. Any optimal allocation of anti-trust efforts that maximizes farmer welfare should provide the largest increase in quantity sold by farmers. This means there will also be the largest increase in quantity purchased by consumers, which is associated with the maximum consumer welfare. There are also the largest increases in quantities transacted in all markets along the supply chain, which means deadweight loss is minimized and social welfare is maximized. Our analysis also shows what factors and how they affect the optimal allocation of anti-trust efforts, and provides guidelines to calculate the optimal shares of anti-trust efforts for farm and retail markets.

Methods

In the model, the market chain of an agricultural product consists of three stages: farm, wholesale, and retail markets. Farmers sell a raw agricultural material to wholesalers/processors (hereafter “processors” in the model analysis) in the farm market. Then, processors trade the processed/finished product to food retailers through the wholesale market. Finally, consumers purchase the product from the retailers.

In the farm market, M oligopsony processors procure the raw agricultural material from farmers, where the value of M measures the degree of buyer power in the farm market with smaller values of M indicating stronger buyer power.Footnote 2 Inverse farm supply in a local market is specified as:

$$ {P}_f=a+{bq}_f, $$
(1)

where Pf is the price farmers receive, qf is the quantity supplied in a farm market, b > 0 and subscript “f” denotes the farm market.

In the retail market, N oligopoly food retailers sell the product to consumers. The value of N is a measure of the degree of seller power in the retail market, and smaller values of N represent stronger seller power. The inverse consumer demand function in a local retail market is:

$$ {P}_r=\lambda -\beta {q}_r, $$
(2)

where Pr is the retail price, qr is the quantity demanded in the retail market, and β > 0 and subscript “r” denotes the retail market. Retailers have a constant average and marginal selling cost Cr.

Processors sell the processed product to food retailers in the wholesale market. Various market structure may exist in wholesale markets for agricultural and food products. For a discussion of food wholesale market structure, please see Phlips (1980), Azzam (1999), Schroeter et al. (2000), Richards and Patterson (2003), Sexton et al. (2003), Lloyd et al. (2009), and Draganska et al. (2010). In this paper, we use the case of a competitive wholesale market to facilitate the presentation of results.Footnote 3

Table 1 The impact of various wholesale market structures on farm and retail price and processors’ and retailers’ profit

We follow Zhang and Sexton (2000) to use a fixed-portion production function and assume a constant average and marginal cost. Processors convert the raw agricultural material into the processed product according to a fixed-proportion production function. Through the choice of measurement unit, we can have qw = qf, where qw is the quantity of the wholesale product converted from the raw agricultural material of one farm market, and subscript w denotes the wholesale market. The constant average and marginal wholesaling/processing cost is Cw.Footnote 4

Anti-trust efforts of the government are represented by \( \overline{E} \). The efforts can be allocated between farm and retail markets according to

$$ \overline{E}={E}_f\left(\Delta M\right)+{E}_r\left(\Delta N\right), $$

where Ef(∆M) is the amount of anti-trust efforts allocated to farm markets, which increases the farm market competition level by ∆M, with ∂Ef/∂∆M > 0 and Ef(0) = 0; Er(∆N) is the amount of anti-trust efforts allocated to retail markets, which increases the retail market competition level by ∆N, with ∂Er/∂∆N > 0 and Er(0) = 0.

We first derive the equilibrium prices and quantities of all markets along the food market chain. Then, based on the interaction between buyer power in agricultural procurement and seller power in food retailing, we derive the optimal allocation of anti-trust efforts between farm and retail markets for three policy goals and analyze what factors and how they affect the optimal allocation.

The market equilibrium

In this section, we derive the market equilibrium in each stage of the food market chain. Let us start with the retail market to find the market equilibrium. Given the wholesale price Pw, food retailer n (n = 1, 2, ..., N) sells the optimal quantity qr, n of the finished product to consumers to maximize her profit πn = (Pr − Pw − Cr)qr, n. Having obtained and solved all N first-order conditions simultaneously for the optimal quantities of retailers, the solutions are substituted back into the market-clearing condition (\( \sum \limits_{n=1}^N{q}_{r,n}={q}_r=\left(\lambda -{P}_r\right)/\beta \)) to find the equilibrium price and quantity in a retail market, conditional on the wholesale price Pw:

Pr = [N/(N + 1)](Pw + Cr) + λ/(N + 1) and qr = [N/(N + 1)](λ − Pw − Cr)/β.

Using this conditional retail quantity qr and the wholesale demand qw = qr, we derive the corresponding inverse demand function in the wholesale market as:

$$ {P}_w=\lambda -{C}_r-\left[\beta \left(N+1\right)/N\right]{q}_w. $$

Following the similar method, we also obtain the equilibrium price and quantity in the farm market, conditional on the wholesale price Pw:

Pf = [M/(M + 1)](Pw − Cw) + a/(M + 1) and qf = [M/(M + 1)](Pw − Cw − a)/b and then find the inverse wholesale supply function as Pw = a + Cw + [b(M + 1)/M]qw.

We substitute the (conditional) equilibrium price and quantity of the retail market and the farm market, conditional on the wholesale price, into the wholesale market-clearing condition solve for Pw to obtain the equilibrium wholesale price:

$$ {P}_w=\left[ bN\left(M+1\right)\left(\lambda -{C}_r\right)+\beta M\left(N+1\right)\left(a+{C}_w\right)\right]{\left[ bN\left(M+1\right)+\beta M\left(N+1\right)\right]}^{-1}. $$

The equilibrium wholesale price is increasing in the retail demand factor (λ), the farm production parameter a, average wholesale cost (Cw), and the competition level (N) in retail markets and decreasing in average retail cost (Cr) and the competition level (M) in farm markets. Using this equilibrium wholesale price, we also find the unconditional equilibrium price in retail and farm markets:Footnote 5

$$ {P}_r=\lambda -\beta M N\left(\lambda -{C}_r-{C}_w-a\right)/\left[ bN\left(M+1\right)+\beta M\left(N+1\right)\right] $$

and

$$ {P}_f=a+ bMN\left(\lambda -{C}_r-{C}_w-a\right)/\left[ bN\left(M+1\right)+\beta M\left(N+1\right)\right], $$

and consumer surplus (CS) in the retail market, the farmers’ producer surplus (PS), and total social welfare (SW) along the food market chain:

$$ \mathrm{CS}=\left(1/2\right)\beta {M}^2{N}^2{\left(\lambda -{C}_r-{C}_w-a\right)}^2/{\left[ bN\left(M+1\right)+\beta M\left(N+1\right)\right]}^2, $$
$$ \mathrm{PS}=\left(1/2\right)b{M}^2{N}^2{\left(\lambda -{C}_r-{C}_w-a\right)}^2/{\left[ bN\left(M+1\right)+\beta M\left(N+1\right)\right]}^2, $$

and

$$ \mathrm{SW}=\left[\left(\frac{M}{2}+1\right) bN+\left(\frac{N}{2}+1\right)\beta M\right] MN{\left(\lambda -{C}_r-{C}_w-a\right)}^2/{\left[ bN\left(M+1\right)+\beta M\left(N+1\right)\right]}^2. $$

The equilibrium retail price is increasing in the retail demand factor (λ), the farm production parameter (a), and average wholesale and retail cost (Cw and Cr) and decreasing in the competition level (N) in retail markets and the competition level (M) in farm markets. The equilibrium farm price is increasing in the retail demand factor (λ), the farm production parameter (a), and the competition level (M) in farm markets and the competition level (N) in retail markets and decreasing in the average wholesale and retail cost (Cw and Cr). Regarding the welfare measures, consumer surplus is decreasing in the steepness (b) of farm supply curve, farmers’ producer surplus is decreasing in the steepness (β) of consumer demand curve, all welfare measures are increasing the retail demand factor (λ), and decreasing in the farm production factor (a), wholesale and retail cost, buyer power in farm markets, and seller power in retail markets.

Let δw denotes the processors’ profit margin, which is the difference between the wholesale price Pw and the sum (Pf + Cw) of the farm price and marginal wholesaling cost. Similarly, retailers’ profit margin δr is the difference between the retail price Pr and the sum (Pw + Cr) of the wholesale price and marginal retailing cost. Through the calculation based on the three equilibrium prices, we have the profit margins of processors and retailers in the first scenario as:

$$ {\delta}_w= bN\left(\lambda -{C}_r-{C}_w-a\right)/\left[ bN\left(M+1\right)+\beta M\left(N+1\right)\right] $$
(3)

and

$$ {\delta}_r=\beta M\left(\lambda -{C}_r-{C}_w-a\right)/\left[ bN\left(M+1\right)+\beta M\left(N+1\right)\right]. $$
(4)

Allocation of anti-trust efforts

In this section, we examine the optimal allocation of anti-trust efforts to achieve three specific welfare goals: (i) to maximize farmer welfare, (ii) to maximize consumer welfare, and (iii) to maximize social welfare. First, to maximize farmer welfare, a policymaker’s maximization problem is:

$$ {\displaystyle \begin{array}{l}{\operatorname{Max}}_{E_f,{E}_r}\Delta \mathrm{PS}\\ {}\kern1em \mathrm{s}.\mathrm{t}.{E}_f+{E}_r=\overline{E},\end{array}} $$

where ΔPS is the gain in farmers’ producer surplus due to the anti-trust efforts; Ef and Er are the amount of the anti-trust efforts allocated to the farm and retail market, respectively, and \( \overline{E} \) is the total amount of the available anti-trust efforts. We solve the constraint \( {E}_f+{E}_r={E}_f\left(\Delta M\right)+{E}_r\left(\Delta N\right)=\overline{E} \) for ∆N to obtain

∆N = Φ−1(0),where Φ−1(•) is the inverse function of Φ(•) and\( \Phi \left(\Delta N\right)=\overline{E}-{E}_r\left(\Delta N\right)-{E}_f\left(\Delta M\right) \) with ∂Φ/∂∆M < 0 and \( \mathrm{\partial \Phi }/\partial \overline{E}>0 \).

Using the solution of ∆N and the equilibrium result of farmers’ producer surplus, we find the farmer welfare gain as:

$$ \Delta \mathrm{PS}\approx \left(\mathrm{\partial PS}/\partial M\right)\Delta M+\left(\mathrm{\partial PS}/\partial N\right)\Delta N= bMN\left[b{N}^2\Delta M+\beta {M}^2{\Phi}^{-1}(0)\right]{\left(\lambda -{C}_r-{C}_w-a\right)}^2/{\left[ bN\left(M+1\right)+\beta M\left(N+1\right)\right]}^3. $$

Solving the first-order condition ∂ΔPS/∂ΔM = 0 for ∆M and substituting the solution of ∆M into the anti-trust effort equation yields the optimal allocation of anti-trust efforts as:

$$ {E}_f={E}_f\left[{\Psi}^{-1}(0)\right], $$

where Ψ−1(•) is the inverse function of Ψ(•) and Ψ(∆M) = bN2 + βM2[Φ−1(0)/∂∆M] with Φ−1(0)/∂∆M < 0 and\( {E}_r=\overline{E}-{E}_f\left[{\Psi}^{-1}(0)\right] \).

Similarly, a policymaker’s problem to maximize consumer welfare is:

$$ {\displaystyle \begin{array}{l}{\operatorname{Max}}_{E_f,{E}_r}\Delta CS\\ {}\kern1em \mathrm{s}.\mathrm{t}.{E}_f+{E}_r=\overline{E},\end{array}} $$

where ΔCS is the gain in consumer surplus due to the anti-trust efforts. In order to maximize the total social welfare, a policymaker’s problem becomes:

$$ {\displaystyle \begin{array}{l}{\operatorname{Max}}_{E_f,{E}_r}\Delta \mathrm{SW}\\ {}\kern1em \mathrm{s}.\mathrm{t}.{E}_f+{E}_r=\overline{E},\end{array}} $$

where ΔSW is the gain in social welfare due to the anti-trust efforts. For each of these two additional welfare goals, we also solve the policymaker’s maximization problem to obtain the optimal allocation of anti-trust efforts between the farm and retail market (please see the “Appendix” section for detailed derivation and results).

Results and Discussion

Based on the above analysis, we obtain the effects of the interaction between buyer power in agricultural procurement and seller power in food retailing, and the optimal allocation of anti-trust efforts to maximize welfare. The results are summarized in the following four propositions.

Welfare effects of weakening one form of market power

The results in the first two propositions describe the welfare effects of weakening only one form of market power and how a portion of the benefit is captured by retailers or processors.

Proposition 1 Although farmer welfare and farm price will increase if buyer power in agricultural procurement is weakened, the magnitudes of these increases are reduced by retailers’ seller power. In addition, the anticompetitive effect of retailers’ seller power will be enlarged, i.e., retailers’ profit margin will increase.

When retailers have stronger seller power in retail markets, the farmer welfare and farm price increases due to weakened buyer power in agricultural procurement will be smaller. The increase in retailers’ profit margin will be larger.

Proof Appendix.

The economic intuition of Proposition 1 is as follows: Each processor chooses the optimal amount of the agricultural material to purchase where the marginal revenue (MR) equals the marginal cost. The marginal revenue is increasing in the wholesale price, regardless of the wholesale market structure. Retailers’ seller power causes the wholesale demand to be lower and less elastic through a pivotal shift,Footnote 6 which leads to a lower wholesale price and a lower marginal revenue (MR) for processors. Even when weakened buyer power in agricultural procurement results in a farm price increase, the lower MR for processors due to retailers’ seller power causes processors to compete less aggressively in farm markets than they would when the retail market is competitive and, thus, reduces the amount of farm price increase. Farmer welfare, measured by producer surplus, is increasing in the farm price, ceteris paribus. Thus, when retailers’ seller power reduces the magnitude of farm price increase, it also diminishes the amount of farm welfare gain.

On the other hand, retailers with market power usually pass partially a wholesale price increase/decrease to consumers because they set their marginal revenue, not the retail price, equal their marginal cost. When weakened buyer power in agricultural procurement causes more wholesale supply and, thus, a decrease in the wholesale price, only a portion of this wholesale price decrease is passed to consumers through a retail price decrease. Therefore, retailers’ profit margin, the difference between the wholesale price and the retail price, will increase.

The degree of retailers’ seller power can affect the magnitudes of the effects described above. Stronger seller power in retail markets can cause an even lower wholesale price and MR for processors. Thus, processors compete even less aggressively so that the increases in farmer welfare and farm price are further smaller. Retailers with more seller power pass a smaller portion of a wholesale price decrease to consumers so that their profit margin increase is larger.

Figures 1 and 2 illustrate how the magnitude of farm price increases due to weakened buyer power in agricultural procurement is reduced by retailers’ seller power, and how the anticompetitive effect of retailers’ seller power will be enlarged when buyer power in agricultural procurement is weakened. In the two figures, the parameter values are set as a = 2, b = 1.1, λ = 120, and β = 0.9. Buyer power in agricultural procurement is weakened from M = 2 to M = 3. Figure 1 shows that, compared with the case of perfect competition in retail markets, the magnitude of farm price increases due to weakened buyer power in agricultural procurement is reduced by retailers’ seller power, and the reduction is larger when retailers’ seller power is stronger. Figure 2 illustrates that retailers’ profit margin increases (Δδr > 0) if buyer power in agricultural procurement is weakened, and the profit margin increase is larger when there is a higher degree of retailers’ seller power.

Fig. 1
figure 1

Farm price increase (ΔPf) due to the weakened buyer power in agricultural procurement under various levels of seller power in retail markets. Note: ΔPf is the increase in farm price when processors’ buyer power is weakened from M = 2 to M = 3. The increase (ΔPf) is smaller when retailers have stronger seller power in retail markets. Case 1 is when there is a competitive wholesale market. Case 2 is when there is an oligopoly wholesale market. Case 3 is when there is an oligopsony wholesale market. Farm price increase in case 2 (red line) is larger than that in case 1 (blue line). The relative magnitudes between farm price increase in case 3 and those in cases 1 and 2 depend on various market factors so that all (in)equalities between them are possible

Fig. 2
figure 2

The increase (Δδr) in retailers’ profit margin due to the weakened buyer power in agricultural procurement under various levels of seller power in retail markets. Note: Δδr is the increase in retailers’ profit margin when processors’ buyer power is weakened from M = 2 to M = 3. The increase (Δδr) is larger when retailers have stronger seller power in retail markets. Case 1 is when there is a competitive wholesale market. Case 2 is when there is an oligopoly wholesale market. Case 3 is when there is an oligopsony wholesale market. Retailers’ profit margin increase in case 2 (red line) is larger than that in case 1 (blue line). The relative magnitudes between retailers’ profit margin increase in case 3 and those in cases 1 and 2 depend on various market factors so that all (in)equalities between them are possible

Similarly, we can use the equilibrium retail price and processors’ profit margin to analyze the case in which retailers’ seller power is weakened. Proposition 2 includes the results.

Proposition 2 Although consumer welfare will gain and retail price will decrease if seller power in retail markets is weakened, the magnitude of the consumer welfare gain and retail price decrease is reduced by processors’ buyer power. In addition, the anticompetitive effect of processors’ buyer power will be enlarged, i.e., processors’ profit margin will increase.

When processors have stronger buyer power in agricultural procurement, the consumer welfare gain and retail price decrease due to weakened seller power in retail markets will be smaller. The increase in processors’ profit margin will be larger.

Proof Appendix.

The economic intuition of Proposition 2 is similar to the one of Proposition 1. Figures 3 and 4 show the simulation results for Proposition 2. The parameters used are the same as those in the simulation for Figs. 1 and 2. Seller power in food retailing is weakened from N = 2 to N = 3. The impact of wholesale market structures is also shown in Figs. 3 and 4.

Fig. 3
figure 3

Retail price decrease (ΔPr) due to the weakened seller power in food retailing under various levels of buyer power in farm markets. Note: ΔPr is the decrease in retail price when retailers’ seller power is weakened from N = 2 to N = 3. The magnitude of decrease (|ΔPr|) is smaller when the processors have stronger buyer power in farm markets. Case 1 is when there is a competitive wholesale market. Case 2 is when there is an oligopoly wholesale market. Case 3 is when there is an oligopsony wholesale market. Retail price decrease (|ΔPr|) in case 3 (green line) is larger than that in case 1 (blue line). The relative magnitudes between retail price decrease in case 2 and those in cases 1 and 3 depend on various market factors so that all (in)equalities between them are possible

Fig. 4
figure 4

The increase (Δδw) in processors’ profit margin due to the weakened seller power in retail markets under various levels of buyer power in agricultural procurement. Note: Δδw is the increase in processors’ profit margin when retailers’ seller power is weakened from N = 2 to N = 3. The increase (Δδw) is larger when the processors have stronger buyer power in farm markets. Case 1 is when there is a competitive wholesale market. Case 2 is when there is an oligopoly wholesale market. Case 3 is when there is an oligopsony wholesale market. Processors’ profit margin increase in case 3 (green line) is larger than that in case 1 (blue line). The relative magnitudes between processors’ profit margin increase in case 2 and those in cases 1 and 3 depend on various market factors so that all (in)equalities between them are possible

Optimal allocation of anti-trust efforts

The above two propositions show that addressing only one form of market power may be ineffective because the benefit will be offset by the other form of market power. Dealing with both forms of market power in farm and retail markets means that more of the benefits from reducing market power will be enjoyed by the farmers and consumers.Footnote 7 Thus, we analyze the optimal allocation of anti-trust efforts between farm and retail market that maximizes welfare and find the following results:

Fig. 5
figure 5

Farm price increase (ΔPf) in two scenarios of anti-trust methods under various wholesale market structures. Note: The red lines represent the farm price increase (ΔPf) when only processors’ buyer power is weakened (from M = 2 to M = 3). The blue lines represent the farm price increase (ΔPf) when both processors’ buyer power (from M = 2 to M = 3) and retailers’ seller power are weakened (from N = 2 to N = 3). The farm price increases (blue lines) are larger when the two forms of market power are jointly addressed

Fig. 6
figure 6

Retail price decrease (ΔPr) in two scenarios of anti-trust methods under various wholesale market structures. Note: The red lines represent the retail price decrease (ΔPr) when only retailers’ seller power is weakened (from N = 2 to N = 3). The blue lines represent the retail price decrease (ΔPr) when both retailers’ seller power (from N = 2 to N = 3) and processors’ buyer power (from M = 2 to M = 3) are weakened. The retail price decreases |ΔPr| (blue lines) are larger when the two forms of market power are jointly addressed

Proposition 3 Even if the policy objective is to maximize the welfare of price-takers in one stage of food market chain (e.g., farmers), anti-trust efforts may need to be allocated to both farm and retail markets rather than only the one stage (e.g., farm market). More importantly, the optimal allocations of anti-trust efforts are the same for these three different policy objectives: (i) to maximize farmer welfare, (ii) to maximize consumer welfare, and (iii) to maximize social welfare.

Proof Appendix.

Let us discuss the economic reason for the results in this proposition. Reducing market power through anti-trust efforts in one stage (e.g., retail market) benefits not only the price-takers (e.g., consumers) in this stage but also the market participants (e.g., farmers and processors) in another stage (e.g., farm market). Thus, a policymaker always wants to allocate anti-trust efforts to make sure that the marginal gain in welfare due to putting anti-trust efforts in one market is equal to the marginal gain due to putting efforts in another market, regardless of whether the objective is to maximize welfare of farmers only, consumers only, or the entire society.

Even if the policy objective is to maximize farmer welfare only, for each unit of anti-trust efforts, a policymaker can assign this unit to either the farm market, which will benefit farmers directly, or the retail market, which will benefit farmers indirectly through increased demand for farm product, depending on the relative magnitudes of these two benefits. At the equilibrium, the optimal allocation of anti-trust efforts to maximize farmer welfare may require a positive amount of anti-trust efforts in both farm and retail market, and the marginal gain in the welfare of anti-trust efforts is equal in the two markets.

For the three policy objectives (to maximize farmer welfare, consumer welfare, or social welfare), the optimal allocation of anti-trust efforts results in the largest increase in the quantity of products sold by farmers, or purchased by consumers, or that transacted in all markets. Because the agricultural/food product is produced, processed, and transacted along the supply chain and all stages are connected, an optimal allocation of anti-trust efforts that brings the largest increase in the amount of products sold by farmers will also cause the largest increase in the amount of products purchased by consumers and those transacted in all three (farm, wholesale, retail) markets. Therefore, the optimal allocations of anti-trust efforts are the same for all the three different policy objectives.

We also examine what factors and how they affect the optimal allocation of anti-trust efforts to maximize welfare, and the results are included in the following proposition:

Proposition 4 The results about the optimal shares of anti-trust efforts are:

  1. (i)

    Given the amount of available anti-trust efforts, the optimal share of efforts allocated to farm market is increasing in the steepness of farm supply curve and processors’ buyer power in farm market and decreasing in the steepness of consumer demand and retailers’ seller power in the retail market. The optimal share of efforts allocated to retail market will have the exact opposite directions of changes in response to the changes in these four factors.

  2. (ii)

    If the two effort functions, Ef(∆M) and Er(∆N), have the same form, allocate more (less) than 50% anti-trust efforts to farm market and the remaining effort to retail market if bN2 > βM2 (if bN2 < βM2).

  3. (iii)

    In general, the optimal share of efforts can be calculated using farm supply and consumer demand functions, measures of market power in two markets, and specified anti-trust effort equations. The optimal share of efforts for farm market is represented as \( {E}_f\left[{\Psi}^{-1}(0)\right]/\overline{E} \), and the optimal share for retail market is \( 1-{E}_f\left[{\Psi}^{-1}(0)\right]/\overline{E} \).

Proof Appendix.

In a market with steeper (or inelastic) supply or demand curve and stronger market power, the welfare loss due to market power is larger. Thus, more anti-trust efforts should be allocated in this market than in another market along the supply chain. Therefore, the optimal shares of anti-trust efforts allocated to farm and retail market depend on the relative magnitudes of the four factors, the steepness of farm supply curve, the steepness of consumer demand curve, processors’ buyer power in farm market, and retailers’ seller power in retail market, as indicated in Proposition 4.

Conclusions

Two forms of market power along the food market chain, buyer power in agricultural procurement and seller power in food retailing, have been discussed and examined extensively in the general press and academic research. However, little attention has been paid to the interaction between the two forms of market power and, especially, the optimal allocation of anti-trust efforts among farm and retail markets to maximize welfare. Understanding this issue is essential for taking appropriate and effective measures against anticompetitive behaviors in the agricultural and food sector.

The analysis in this paper shows that the benefit of weakening one form of market power is reduced by another form of market power in the food market chain so that it is necessary to address both forms of market power together. More importantly, to maximize farmer welfare, a policymaker may need to allocate anti-trust efforts to both farm and retail markets. The optimal allocations of anti-trust efforts are actually the same for three different policy objectives (to maximize farmer welfare, maximize consumer welfare, and maximize social welfare). The reason is that all these markets are vertically connected though the movement of one agricultural/food product so that addressing market power to improve welfare in one market will benefit other markets as well.

The optimal share of anti-trust efforts of farm (retail) market is increasing (decreasing) in the steepness of farm supply curve and processors’ buyer power and decreasing (increasing) in the steepness of consumer demand curve and retailers’ seller power. We also provide some guidelines and formula for the design and calculation of optimal allocations of anti-trust efforts among farm and retail markets.

These findings can help improve the understanding on the nature of imperfect competition and optimal allocation of anti-trust efforts along the food market chain. Given that both buyer power in agricultural procurement and seller power in retail markets may exist for many agricultural and food industries, these findings are also useful for designing effective policies to promote competition in the agricultural and food sector.