Skip to main content
Log in

Pollution from consumption and urban unemployment in a dual economy

  • Economic Analysis of Law, Politics, and Regions
  • Published:
Asia-Pacific Journal of Regional Science Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

By incorporating the environmental problems caused by consumption into a theoretical model of rural–urban migration, this study analyzes the effect of a reduction in pollution generation rate and factor accumulation. The environment of each rural and urban area is assumed to deteriorate due to pollution from consumption of the respective inhabitants. For institutional reasons, the urban wage rate is fixed at a higher level than the rural wage rate, and unemployment exists in the urban area. Rural–urban migration occurs because of differences in utility, which is affected by both the environment and expected earning in each area. This study shows that, although reduction in the pollution generation rate improves the environment in both areas, whether it mitigates urban unemployment depends on certain conditions. Regarding the effect of factor accumulation, this study shows that an increase in capital endowment decreases the level of unemployment if and only if the environmental effect outweighs the Rybczynski effect.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. As regards the driver of migration, see Bodvarsson and Van den Berg (2013) and Hatton and Williamson (2005).

  2. We can interpret \(L_{U}\) as labor that is not used in production.

  3. A specific utility function of this type is adopted owing to the reviewer’s comment.

  4. Note that (12) is derived by assuming that each urban worker is employed in turn and earns \(w_{M}\). Alternatively, if we regard that urban employed labor earns \(\bar{w}\) and unemployed labor has no income, the expected utility of an urban worker is the same as (12): The indirect utility function of urban employed labor is \(v(p,\bar{w}) + G(E^{M} )\), whereas that of unemployed labor is \(G(E^{M} )\). Thus, the expected utility of an urban worker becomes \(\frac{{L_{M} }}{{L_{M} + L_{U} }}\left[ {v(p,\bar{w}) + G(E^{M} )} \right] + \frac{{L_{U} }}{{L_{M} + L_{U} }}G(E^{M} ) = v(p,w_{M} ) + G(E^{M} )\). This equation is derived by the assumption that \(u\) is linearly homogeneous.

  5. In equilibrium, \(E^{M} > ( < )E^{A} \Leftrightarrow w_{M} < ( > )w\) holds. Thus, \(w_{M}\) can either be higher or lower than \(w\), even under the assumption that \(\bar{w} > w\).

  6. Note that this study treats demand and consumption as identical.

  7. Essentially, \(\lambda\) depends on the generation rate of pollution by consumption of each good and \(p\). However, the latter is assumed to be constant. Thus, we refer to \(\lambda\) as the pollution generation rate.

  8. Alternatively, we can refer (21) as the aggregated flow of pollution from urban employed workers.

  9. This study refers to \(L_{U} /L_{M}\) as the unemployment ratio.

  10. This can be seen from (34) and (35) in Appendix A.

  11. This result is derived assuming that each urban worker receives \(w_{M}\). Alternatively, if we regard that an urban employed (unemployed) worker earns \(\bar{w}\) (no income), utilities of both employed and unemployed workers also rise by an improvement in the urban environment (as regards the utility functions of this case, see footnote 4).

  12. If magnitude of \(\lambda\) increases, the environmental effect becomes stronger, at least in terms of direct effect.

References

  • Bodvarsson ÖB, Van den Berg H (2013) The economics of immigration: theory and policy. Springer, New York

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Chao CC, Kerkvliet JR, Yu ESH (2000) Environmental preservation, sectoral unemployment, and trade in resources. Rev Dev Econ 4:39–50

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Corden WM, Findlay R (1975) Urban unemployment, intersectoral capital mobility and development policy. Economica 42:59–78

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Daitoh I (2003) Environmental protection and urban unemployment: environmental policy reform in a polluted dualistic economy. Rev Dev Econ 7:496–509

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dustmann C, Okatenko A (2014) Out-migration, wealth constraints, and the quality of local amenities. J Dev Econ 110:52–63

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Harris JR, Todaro MP (1970) Migration, unemployment and development: a two-sector analysis. Am Econ Rev 60:126–142

    Google Scholar 

  • Hatton TJ, Williamson JG (2005) What fundamentals drive world migration? In: Borjas GJ, Crisp J (eds) Poverty, international migration and asylum. Palgrave Macmillan, New York, pp 15–38

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Li X, Xu Y, Wang D (2014) Environment and labor movement of skilled labor and unskilled labor between sectors. Econ Model 38:367–371

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mara D (2004) Domestic wastewater treatment in developing countries. Earthscan, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Nakamura A (2013) Environment, urban unemployment, and tariffs in the Harris–Todaro Model. Rev Dev Econ 17:585–593

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Neary JP (1981) On the Harris–Todaro Model with intersectoral capital mobility. Economica 48:219–234

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • OECD (2012) OECD environmental outlook to 2050. OECD Publishing, Paris

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Pan L, Zhou Y (2013) International factor mobility, environmental pollution and skilled-unskilled wage inequality in developing countries. Econ Model 33:826–831

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tawada M, Nakamura A (2009) Environment and the Harris and Todaro paradoxes. In: Kamihigashi T, Zhao L (eds) International trade and economic dynamics, essays in memory of Koji Shimomura. Springer, Berlin, pp 87–99

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Tawada M, Sun S (2010) Urban pollution, unemployment and national welfare in a dualistic economy. Rev Dev Econ 14:311–322

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Yabuuchi S (2013) Tourism, the environment, and welfare in a dual economy. Asia Pac J Account Econ 20:172–182

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

The author is indebted to two anonymous referees and Professor Makoto Tawada for insightful comments.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Azusa Nakamura.

Appendices

Appendix A: Stability

In the short run, for given \(E^{M}\) and \(E^{A}\), six Eqs. (3), (4), (7), (8), (9), and (16) determine six endogenous variables: \(L_{M}\), \(L_{U}\), \(L_{A}\), \(K_{M}\), \(K_{A}\), and \(w\). Thus, substituting (21) and (25) into (26) and substituting (23) into (28), respectively, the dynamic adjustment process of \(E^{M}\) and \(E^{A}\) can be expressed as

$$\dot{E}^{M} = g(\bar{E} - E^{M} ) - \lambda (\bar{w}L_{M} + rK) \equiv \phi (E^{M} ,E^{A} ),$$
(34)
$$\dot{E}^{A} = g(\bar{E} - E^{A} ) - \lambda wL_{A} \equiv \varPsi (E^{M} ,E^{A} ).$$
(35)

Necessary and sufficient condition for the linear approximation system of (34) and (35) to be globally stable is that the trace of \(S\) (\({\text{tr}} S\)) is negative and the determinant of matrix \(S\) (det \(S\)) is positive, where \(S \equiv \left[ {\begin{array}{*{20}c} {\partial \phi /\partial E^{M} } & {\partial \phi /\partial E^{A} } \\ {\partial \varPsi /\partial E^{M} } & {\partial \varPsi /\partial E^{A} } \\ \end{array} } \right]\).

To investigate the signs of \({\text{tr}} S\) and det \(S\), by differentiating (3), (4), (7), (8), (9), and (16), we obtain

$$\left[ {\begin{array}{*{20}c} {pF_{LL}^{M} } & 0 & 0 & {pF_{LK}^{M} } & 0 & 0 \\ 0 & 0 & {F_{LL}^{A} } & 0 & {F_{LK}^{A} } & { - 1} \\ {pF_{KL}^{M} } & 0 & { - F_{KL}^{A} } & {pF_{KK}^{M} } & { - F_{KK}^{A} } & 0 \\ 1 & 1 & 1 & 0 & 0 & 0 \\ 0 & 0 & 0 & 1 & 1 & 0 \\ B & { - C} & 0 & 0 & 0 & { - v_{w}^{A} } \\ \end{array} } \right]\left[ {\begin{array}{*{20}c} {{\text{d}}L_{M} } \\ {{\text{d}}L_{U} } \\ {{\text{d}}L_{A} } \\ {{\text{d}}K_{M} } \\ {{\text{d}}K_{A} } \\ {{\text{d}}w} \\ \end{array} } \right] = \left[ {\begin{array}{*{20}c} 0 \\ 0 \\ 0 \\ 0 \\ 0 \\ { - G^{M'} } \\ \end{array} } \right]{\text{d}}E^{M} + \left[ {\begin{array}{*{20}c} 0 \\ 0 \\ 0 \\ 0 \\ 0 \\ {G^{A'} } \\ \end{array} } \right]{\text{d}}E^{A} .$$
(36)

Denoting the determinant of square matrix of (36) as \(J\), we have

$$J = p\bar{w}v_{w}^{M} F_{LK}^{M} F_{KL}^{A} L_{A} \left[ {K_{M} /(L_{M} + L_{U} ) - K_{A} /L_{A} } \right]/(L_{M} + L_{U} )K_{A} .$$

Thus, the following relationship holds as regards the sign of \(J\):

$$J > ( < )0 \Leftrightarrow K_{M} /(L_{M} + L_{U} ) > ( < )K_{A} /L_{A} .$$

We are now in a position to examine the signs of \({\text{tr}} S\) and det \(S\). First, we investigate the sign of \({\text{tr}} S\). From (34) and (35), we have

$$\begin{aligned} {\text{tr}} S & = \partial \phi /\partial E^{M} + \partial \varPsi /\partial E^{A} \\ & = - g - \lambda (\bar{w}\partial L_{M} /\partial E^{M} + K\partial r/\partial E^{M} ) - g - \lambda (L_{A} \partial w/\partial E^{A} + w\partial L_{A} /\partial E^{A} ) \\ & = - g - \lambda \bar{w}\partial L_{M} /\partial E^{M} - g - \lambda w\partial L_{A} /\partial E^{A} \\ & = - 2g - \lambda (\bar{w}\partial L_{M} /\partial E^{M} + w\partial L_{A} /\partial E^{A} ) \\ & = - 2g - \lambda J^{*} /J, \\ \end{aligned}$$

where \(J^{*} = p(\bar{w}G^{{M^{\prime}}} F_{LK}^{M} F_{KL}^{A} + wG^{{A^{\prime}}} F_{LL}^{M} F_{KK}^{A} ) > 0\). To derive the last expression, we use \(\partial L_{M} /\partial E^{M} = pG^{{M^{\prime}}} F_{LK}^{M} F_{KL}^{A} /J\) and \(\partial L_{A} /\partial E^{A} = pG^{{A^{\prime}}} F_{LL}^{M} F_{KK}^{A} /J\) from (36). Thus, the following relationship holds.

$${\text{tr}} S < 0 \Leftarrow J > 0 \Leftrightarrow K_{M} /(L_{M} + L_{U} ) > K_{A} /L_{A} .$$
(37)

Next, det \(S\) becomes

$$\begin{aligned} \det S & = (\partial \phi /\partial E^{M} )(\partial \varPsi /\partial E^{A} ) - (\partial \varPsi /\partial E^{M} )(\partial \phi /\partial E^{A} ) \\ & = \left[ { - g - \lambda (\bar{w}\partial L_{M} /\partial E^{M} + K\partial r/\partial E^{M} )} \right]\left[ { - g - \lambda (L_{A} \partial w/\partial E^{A} + w\partial L_{A} /\partial E^{A} )} \right] \\ & \quad - \left[ { - \lambda (L_{A} \partial w/\partial E^{M} + w\partial L_{A} /\partial E^{M} )} \right]\left[ { - \lambda (\bar{w}\partial L_{M} /\partial E^{A} + K\partial r/\partial E^{A} )} \right] \\ & = ( - g - \lambda \bar{w}\partial L_{M} /\partial E^{M} )( - g - \lambda w\partial L_{A} /\partial E^{A} ) - ( - \lambda w\partial L_{A} /\partial E^{M} )( - \lambda \bar{w}\partial L_{M} /\partial E^{A} ) \\ & = g^{2} + \lambda g(\bar{w}\partial L_{M} /\partial E^{M} + w\partial L_{A} /\partial E^{A} ) \\ & = g^{2} + \lambda gJ^{*} /J. \\ \end{aligned}$$

Therefore, the following relationship holds:

$$\det S > 0 \Leftarrow J > 0 \Leftrightarrow K_{M} /(L_{M} + L_{U} ) > K_{A} /L_{A} .$$
(38)

From (37) and (38), if the urban area is more capital abundant than the rural area, that is, \(K_{M} /(L_{M} + L_{U} ) > K_{A} /L_{A}\), then the linear approximation system of (34) and (35) is globally stable.

Appendix B: Environmental effect when capital endowment increases

In the following, we show that \(L_{M}\), \(L_{U}\), and \(K_{M}\) decrease due to the environmental effect of an increase in capital endowment. First, we consider the environmental effect on \(L_{U}\). Because the part in parentheses of the last expression of (33d) becomes \(\begin{aligned} {-}e - G^{{M^{\prime}}} L_{A} d/L_{M} K_{A} & = - G^{{A^{\prime}}} wL_{A} /K_{A} + rG^{{M^{\prime}}} - G^{{M^{\prime}}} L_{A} (\bar{w}L_{M} + rK_{M} )/L_{M} K_{A} \\ & = - G^{{A^{\prime}}} wL_{A} /K_{A} + G^{{M^{\prime}}} \left[ {r(1 - L_{A} K_{M} /L_{M} K_{A} ) - L_{A} \bar{w}/K_{A} } \right] < 0, \\ \end{aligned}\) \(L_{U}\) decreases by the environmental effect.

Next, we investigate the environmental effect on \(K_{M}\). The sum of the environmental effect of \({\text{d}}K_{M} /{\text{d}}K\) and \({\text{d}}K_{A} /{\text{d}}K\) is zero: by adding \(F_{LL}^{M} F_{KK}^{A} ( - J^{*} C + JeK_{A} /L_{A} )\) of (33f) and \(F_{LK}^{M} F_{KL}^{A} \left[ {J^{*} (B + C) + JG^{{M^{\prime}}} d/L_{M} } \right]\) of (33g), it becomes

$$\begin{aligned} F_{LL}^{M} F_{KK}^{A} ( - J^{*} C + JeK_{A} /L_{A} ) + F_{LK}^{M} F_{KL}^{A} \left[ {J^{*} (B + C) + JG^{{M^{\prime}}} d/L_{M} } \right] \\ & = F_{LK}^{M} F_{KL}^{A} \left[ {J^{*} ( - CK_{M} L_{A} /L_{M} K_{A} + B + C) + J(eK_{M} /L_{M} + G^{{M^{\prime}}} d/L_{M} )} \right] \\ & = F_{LK}^{M} F_{KL}^{A} \left\{ {J^{*} \frac{{\bar{w}v_{w}^{M} L_{A} \left[ { - K_{M} /(L_{M} + L_{U} ) + K_{A} /L_{A} } \right]}}{{(L_{M} + L_{U} )K_{A} }} + J(G^{{A^{\prime}}} wK_{M} L_{A} /L_{M} K_{A} + G^{{M^{\prime}}} \bar{w})} \right\} \\ & =\, \frac{{(F_{LK}^{M} F_{KL}^{A} )^{2} p\bar{w}v_{w}^{M} L_{A} }}{{(L_{M} + L_{U} )K_{A} }}\left[ {\frac{{K_{M} }}{{(L_{M} + L_{U} )}} - \frac{{K_{A} }}{{L_{A} }}} \right]\left( { - \bar{w}G^{{M^{\prime}}} - \frac{{G^{{A^{\prime}}} wK_{M} L_{A} }}{{L_{M} K_{A} }} + \frac{{G^{{A^{\prime}}} wK_{M} L_{A} }}{{L_{M} K_{A} }} + \bar{w}G^{{M^{\prime}}} } \right) \\ & = 0, \\ \end{aligned}$$

where to obtain the third expression, we use the definitions for \(B\), \(C\), \(e\), and \(d\), while to obtain the fourth expression, we use the definitions for \(J^{*}\) and \(J\). Thus, remembering that the environmental effect of \({\text{d}}K_{A} /{\text{d}}K\) is positive as expressed in (33g), the environmental effect of \({\text{d}}K_{M} /{\text{d}}K\) becomes negative.

Finally, we consider the environmental effect on \(L_{M}\). From (3), \(L_{M}\) and \(K_{M}\) move in the same direction. Therefore, because \(K_{M}\) decreases due to the environmental effect, \(L_{M}\) also decreases due to the environmental effect.

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Nakamura, A. Pollution from consumption and urban unemployment in a dual economy. Asia-Pac J Reg Sci 2, 211–226 (2018). https://doi.org/10.1007/s41685-018-0071-7

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s41685-018-0071-7

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation